{"title":"Cost-Benefit Analysis: Why Relative Economic Position Does Not Matter","authors":"T. Kniesner, W. Viscusi","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.305180","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"The current debate over cost-benefit concerns in agencies' evaluations of government regulations is not so much whether to consider costs and benefits at all but rather what belongs in the estimated costs and benefits themselves. Overlaid is the long-standing concern that the distribution of costs and benefits needs some consideration in policy evaluations. In a recent article in the University of Chicago Law Review, Robert Frank and Cass Sunstein proposed a relatively simple method for adding distributional concerns to policy evaluation that enlarges the typically constructed estimates of the individual's willingness to pay for safer jobs or safer products. One might pay more for safety if it were the result of a government regulation that mandated greater safety across-the-board. The reason, Frank and Sunstein argue, for enlarging current estimates is that someone who takes a safer job or buys a safer product gives up wages or pays a higher price, which then moves him or her down in the ladder of income left over to buy other things. Alternatively, a worker who is given a safer job via a government regulation has no relative income consequences because all affected workers have lower pay. We show that when considering the core of the Frank and Sunstein proposal carefully one concludes that current regulatory evaluations should be left alone because there is no reason to believe that relative positional effects are important either to personal decisions in general or to currently constructed cost-benefit calculations of government regulations in particular. One of the practical problems with trying to consider relative position of income and consumption when estimating willingness to pay is that there is no unique way to ascertain from a statistical model the person's actual social reference group. A researcher must specify ex ante a reference group and then net out the behavioral effects of a possibly incorrectly attributed reference group's behavior on the individual. There is no well-established result from survey data for a typical person's economic reference group. Moreover, the econometric literature generally finds that reference group or social interaction effects are small and easily ignored, perhaps because the relative positional effects of workplace or product safety offset possible reference group effects on residual income (income net of the implicit cost of the extra product or job safety). It is also the case that Frank and Sunstein's recommended increase in the value of willingness to pay for safety used in current regulatory evaluations is already considered. Regulatory evaluations often include a pessimistic and an optimistic value of likely benefits, and Frank and Sunstein's suggested revised value of willingness to pay is still below the optimistic case that carefully formulated cost-benefit studies use. It is easy to show that almost doubling the estimated value of a statistical life would have an inconsequential effect on the economic desirability of a broad set of regulatory policies. Finally, we argue that the most important refinements one could make in the area of regulatory evaluation would be for agencies involved to adhere more to the framework of what is generally considered a carefully done cost-benefit study, and for agencies to make greater actual use of appropriately done cost-benefit studies when recommending regulations.","PeriodicalId":448271,"journal":{"name":"Employment & Labor Law Abstracts eJournal","volume":"100 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2002-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"9","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Employment & Labor Law Abstracts eJournal","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.305180","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 9
Abstract
The current debate over cost-benefit concerns in agencies' evaluations of government regulations is not so much whether to consider costs and benefits at all but rather what belongs in the estimated costs and benefits themselves. Overlaid is the long-standing concern that the distribution of costs and benefits needs some consideration in policy evaluations. In a recent article in the University of Chicago Law Review, Robert Frank and Cass Sunstein proposed a relatively simple method for adding distributional concerns to policy evaluation that enlarges the typically constructed estimates of the individual's willingness to pay for safer jobs or safer products. One might pay more for safety if it were the result of a government regulation that mandated greater safety across-the-board. The reason, Frank and Sunstein argue, for enlarging current estimates is that someone who takes a safer job or buys a safer product gives up wages or pays a higher price, which then moves him or her down in the ladder of income left over to buy other things. Alternatively, a worker who is given a safer job via a government regulation has no relative income consequences because all affected workers have lower pay. We show that when considering the core of the Frank and Sunstein proposal carefully one concludes that current regulatory evaluations should be left alone because there is no reason to believe that relative positional effects are important either to personal decisions in general or to currently constructed cost-benefit calculations of government regulations in particular. One of the practical problems with trying to consider relative position of income and consumption when estimating willingness to pay is that there is no unique way to ascertain from a statistical model the person's actual social reference group. A researcher must specify ex ante a reference group and then net out the behavioral effects of a possibly incorrectly attributed reference group's behavior on the individual. There is no well-established result from survey data for a typical person's economic reference group. Moreover, the econometric literature generally finds that reference group or social interaction effects are small and easily ignored, perhaps because the relative positional effects of workplace or product safety offset possible reference group effects on residual income (income net of the implicit cost of the extra product or job safety). It is also the case that Frank and Sunstein's recommended increase in the value of willingness to pay for safety used in current regulatory evaluations is already considered. Regulatory evaluations often include a pessimistic and an optimistic value of likely benefits, and Frank and Sunstein's suggested revised value of willingness to pay is still below the optimistic case that carefully formulated cost-benefit studies use. It is easy to show that almost doubling the estimated value of a statistical life would have an inconsequential effect on the economic desirability of a broad set of regulatory policies. Finally, we argue that the most important refinements one could make in the area of regulatory evaluation would be for agencies involved to adhere more to the framework of what is generally considered a carefully done cost-benefit study, and for agencies to make greater actual use of appropriately done cost-benefit studies when recommending regulations.
目前关于各机构在评估政府法规时所考虑的成本效益问题的争论,与其说是要不要考虑成本和效益,不如说是成本和效益本身应该包含什么。长期存在的一个问题是,在政策评价中需要对成本和收益的分配进行一些考虑。在《芝加哥大学法律评论》(University of Chicago Law Review)最近发表的一篇文章中,罗伯特•弗兰克(Robert Frank)和卡斯•桑斯坦(Cass Sunstein)提出了一种相对简单的方法,将分配问题添加到政策评估中,从而扩大了对个人愿意为更安全的工作或更安全的产品买单的典型构建估计。如果这是政府规定全面提高安全性的结果,人们可能会为安全付出更多的钱。弗兰克和桑斯坦认为,扩大当前估计的原因是,从事一份更安全的工作或购买更安全产品的人放弃了工资或支付了更高的价格,这使得他或她在剩余收入阶梯上的地位下降,从而购买了其他东西。另一种情况是,一个工人通过政府规定获得了一份更安全的工作,他的相对收入不会受到影响,因为所有受影响的工人的工资都较低。我们表明,当仔细考虑弗兰克和桑斯坦提案的核心时,我们得出的结论是,当前的监管评估应该被单独考虑,因为没有理由相信相对位置效应对一般的个人决策或目前构建的政府监管的成本效益计算是重要的。在估计支付意愿时,试图考虑收入和消费的相对地位,其中一个实际问题是,没有一种独特的方法可以从统计模型中确定一个人的实际社会参照群体。研究人员必须事先指定参照组,然后排除可能被错误归因于参照组的行为对个体的行为影响。对于一个典型的人的经济参照组,调查数据并没有一个完善的结果。此外,计量经济学文献普遍发现,参考群体或社会互动效应很小,很容易被忽略,这可能是因为工作场所或产品安全的相对位置效应抵消了可能的参考群体对剩余收入的影响(收入减去额外产品或工作安全的隐性成本)。此外,弗兰克和桑斯坦提出的在当前监管评估中增加安全性支付意愿的建议也已被考虑在内。监管评估通常包括可能收益的悲观值和乐观值,弗兰克和桑斯坦建议的支付意愿修正值仍然低于仔细制定成本收益研究使用的乐观情况。很容易证明,将统计寿命的估计价值几乎翻倍,将对一系列广泛监管政策的经济可取性产生无关紧要的影响。最后,我们认为,在监管评估领域可以做出的最重要的改进是,相关机构更多地遵守通常被认为是精心完成的成本效益研究的框架,以及机构在推荐法规时更多地实际使用适当完成的成本效益研究。