Efficient Confidentiality for Privacy, Security, and Confidential Business Information

Peter P. Swire
{"title":"Efficient Confidentiality for Privacy, Security, and Confidential Business Information","authors":"Peter P. Swire","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.383180","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"This Article addresses my observation, based on my experience in government service, that those trained in economics are much less likely to consider privacy protection important than those trained in other disciplines. The core economist intuition comes from the basic model of a competitive market, where a market is considered more efficient the closer it comes to perfect information. Full information allows the efficient matching of buyers and sellers. Limits on information, such as privacy rules, raise the costs of exchange and may even promote fraud by concealing negative information. This Article addresses that economists' intuition in a number of ways. As the Article was prepared for a symposium on the future of financial services, Part I highlights the substantial history of confidentiality in banking. Many economists believe that persistent features of markets are likely adaptive and efficient. The history of confidentiality thus raises a rebuttable presumption that confidentiality has important efficiency characteristics. Part II places the privacy debate into settings where economists are likely to have positive intuitions that confidentiality is efficient. First, consider in the security context whether it is efficient to disclose the combination to a bank safe or other security information. Second, consider whether it is efficient for a bank to disclose confidential business information about a corporate borrower to that company's competitors. Third, consider, given the risk of identity theft, whether it is efficient for a bank to reveal a customer's online password or other information that acts as a key to the customer's account. The likely efficiency of keeping this key security information confidential thus can strengthen the intuition that confidentiality may also be efficient when it comes to sensitive personal information, or the \"keys to the heart.\" The Article next suggests reasons why economists have tended to undervalue the harms from unwanted disclosures of information. Economists, who themselves may on average care little about privacy, may have mis-gauged the tastes of other people. The Article explains significant externalities that may lead to inefficiently high use of telemarketing and other business activities that rely on information sharing. The technique of cost/benefit analysis likely tends to emphasize the costs of privacy protections, which are more easily monetizable, instead of the benefits. Certain sorts of harms, including long-run societal harms from lack of privacy, have also likely not received full weight. Fourth, a Ponemon Institute study provides new evidence about revealed behavior, and not simply about poll responses, when it comes to financial services and privacy. The most significant finding is that customers that trusted their financial institution on privacy were substantially more likely to engage in online banking. Additional research would be helpful, but this data supports the possibility that individuals will participate more in some financial services where confidentiality is provided. The Article also places the economic efficiency analysis into broader debates about the desirability of privacy protection. Many non-economist scholars, and the legal system, have stressed the violations of rights that occur when important data about individuals is disclosed without their agreement. Economic analysis gives no independent weight to the violation of rights. Economists have thus systematically given less weight than those trained in other academic disciplines to many of the strongest arguments for privacy protection.","PeriodicalId":124672,"journal":{"name":"Brookings-Wharton Papers on Financial Services","volume":"68 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2003-05-26","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"25","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Brookings-Wharton Papers on Financial Services","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.383180","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 25

Abstract

This Article addresses my observation, based on my experience in government service, that those trained in economics are much less likely to consider privacy protection important than those trained in other disciplines. The core economist intuition comes from the basic model of a competitive market, where a market is considered more efficient the closer it comes to perfect information. Full information allows the efficient matching of buyers and sellers. Limits on information, such as privacy rules, raise the costs of exchange and may even promote fraud by concealing negative information. This Article addresses that economists' intuition in a number of ways. As the Article was prepared for a symposium on the future of financial services, Part I highlights the substantial history of confidentiality in banking. Many economists believe that persistent features of markets are likely adaptive and efficient. The history of confidentiality thus raises a rebuttable presumption that confidentiality has important efficiency characteristics. Part II places the privacy debate into settings where economists are likely to have positive intuitions that confidentiality is efficient. First, consider in the security context whether it is efficient to disclose the combination to a bank safe or other security information. Second, consider whether it is efficient for a bank to disclose confidential business information about a corporate borrower to that company's competitors. Third, consider, given the risk of identity theft, whether it is efficient for a bank to reveal a customer's online password or other information that acts as a key to the customer's account. The likely efficiency of keeping this key security information confidential thus can strengthen the intuition that confidentiality may also be efficient when it comes to sensitive personal information, or the "keys to the heart." The Article next suggests reasons why economists have tended to undervalue the harms from unwanted disclosures of information. Economists, who themselves may on average care little about privacy, may have mis-gauged the tastes of other people. The Article explains significant externalities that may lead to inefficiently high use of telemarketing and other business activities that rely on information sharing. The technique of cost/benefit analysis likely tends to emphasize the costs of privacy protections, which are more easily monetizable, instead of the benefits. Certain sorts of harms, including long-run societal harms from lack of privacy, have also likely not received full weight. Fourth, a Ponemon Institute study provides new evidence about revealed behavior, and not simply about poll responses, when it comes to financial services and privacy. The most significant finding is that customers that trusted their financial institution on privacy were substantially more likely to engage in online banking. Additional research would be helpful, but this data supports the possibility that individuals will participate more in some financial services where confidentiality is provided. The Article also places the economic efficiency analysis into broader debates about the desirability of privacy protection. Many non-economist scholars, and the legal system, have stressed the violations of rights that occur when important data about individuals is disclosed without their agreement. Economic analysis gives no independent weight to the violation of rights. Economists have thus systematically given less weight than those trained in other academic disciplines to many of the strongest arguments for privacy protection.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
对隐私、安全和机密商业信息的有效保密
这篇文章阐述了我的观察,基于我在政府服务的经验,那些受过经济学训练的人比那些受过其他学科训练的人更不可能认为隐私保护是重要的。经济学家的核心直觉来自竞争市场的基本模型,在这个模型中,人们认为市场越接近完美信息,效率就越高。充分的信息使买卖双方有效匹配。对信息的限制,如隐私规则,提高了交换的成本,甚至可能通过隐瞒负面信息来促进欺诈。本文从多个方面阐述了经济学家的直觉。由于这篇文章是为一个关于金融服务未来的研讨会而编写的,第一部分强调了银行业保密的实质性历史。许多经济学家认为,市场的持久特征可能具有适应性和有效性。因此,保密的历史提出了一个可反驳的假设,即保密具有重要的效率特征。第二部分将隐私辩论置于经济学家可能有积极直觉的环境中,即保密是有效的。首先,考虑在安全性上下文中向银行保险箱或其他安全性信息披露组合是否有效。其次,考虑银行将公司借款人的机密商业信息披露给该公司的竞争对手是否有效。第三,考虑到身份被盗的风险,银行披露客户的在线密码或充当客户账户密钥的其他信息是否有效。因此,将这些关键安全信息保密的可能效率可以增强这样一种直觉,即机密性在涉及敏感的个人信息或“通往心灵的钥匙”时也可能是有效的。接下来,这篇文章提出了经济学家倾向于低估不受欢迎的信息披露的危害的原因。一般来说,经济学家自己可能不太关心隐私,他们可能错误地判断了其他人的品味。这篇文章解释了可能导致电话营销和其他依赖信息共享的商业活动效率低下的显著外部性。成本/收益分析技术可能倾向于强调隐私保护的成本,这更容易货币化,而不是收益。某些类型的危害,包括缺乏隐私造成的长期社会危害,可能也没有得到充分重视。第四,波耐蒙研究所(Ponemon Institute)的一项研究提供了新的证据,证明了当涉及金融服务和隐私时,人们的行为是公开的,而不仅仅是民意调查的结果。最重要的发现是,在隐私方面信任金融机构的客户更有可能使用网上银行。进一步的研究可能会有所帮助,但这些数据支持了个人将更多地参与某些提供保密的金融服务的可能性。文章还将经济效率分析置于更广泛的关于隐私保护可取性的辩论中。许多非经济学者和法律体系都强调,在未经个人同意的情况下,披露有关个人的重要数据是对权利的侵犯。经济分析对侵犯权利没有给予独立的权重。因此,与受过其他学科训练的人相比,经济学家对许多支持隐私保护的最有力的论据给予的系统性重视要少得多。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
Tort Liability, Insurance Rates, and the Insurance Cycle Brokers and the Insurance of Non-Verifiable Losses Editors' Summary Extending the Theory to Meet the Practice of Insurance The "Crisis" in Medical Malpractice Insurance
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1