Deflation, corrosive and otherwise

James Bullard, Charles M. Hokayem
{"title":"Deflation, corrosive and otherwise","authors":"James Bullard, Charles M. Hokayem","doi":"10.20955/ES.2003.17","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"R ecently the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) mentioned deflation as a possible risk for the U.S. economy. In the statement released after the May policy meeting, the Committee stated that “the probability of an unwelcome substantial fall in inflation, though minor, exceeds that of a pickup in inflation from its already low level.” Later, Chairman Greenspan spoke about more than just a mild deflation. In comments to the International Monetary Conference in early June, Chairman Greenspan referred to the risk of “corrosive” deflation “that essentially feeds on itself, creates falling asset prices, which in turn brings down levels of economic activity...” What is the main evidence on deflation? Are there corrosive and benign forms? Does economic perfor mance always suffer during periods of sustained deflation? The accompanying table provides some evidence on deflation and lists periods in which the United States or Japan have experienced three or more years of a declining price level. There are three main episodes: the late 19th century in the United States, the Great Depression in the United States, and Japan since 1999. For each deflationary episode, the table lists the average real GDP growth rate and the average inflation rate based on two popular inflation measures, the GDP deflator and the consumer price index. The table also lists a benchmark average growth rate of GDP for years surrounding the deflation experience, so we can consider whether deflation is associated with lower-than-average growth for the corresponding era or not. Generally speaking, the United States experienced rapid growth during the late 19th century, with GDP growth averaging about 4.0 percent for the period 1876-1900, despite an average deflation of about 1.0 percent. By itself, this suggests that a mild deflation is not necessarily asso ciated with poor economic performance. However, averaging over a long period of time could mask severe distress that may accompany deflation. To address this issue, we examine the subperiods 1876-1879 and 18831885. During the former, GDP growth actually was greater than the bench mark value, despite a rather hefty 3.0 to 4.0 percent annual average decline in the price level. Evidently, this deflationary episode was rather benign. In contrast, the deflationary episode of 1883-1885 was not so benign. GDP growth fell well below the benchmark average for that time. The same is also true at the onset of the Great Depression (1930-1933) and the recent episode in Japan (1999-2002). During the Great Depression, GDP growth averaged a whopping –8.36 percent and inflation was around –6.5 percent. While not as severe, Japan also experienced slow growth during its deflationary episode. As the table shows, U.S. experience with sustained deflation has been limited since the founding of the Federal Reserve in 1914. The results from 1930-1933 are uniformly bad, but deflation may simply have been a by-product of the economic collapse at that time. Japan’s experience is perhaps more relevant for today’s circumstances. Although sustained deflation is not everywhere and always “corrosive,” on balance the evidence suggests that deflationary episodes are marked by subpar growth. Deflation, Corrosive and Otherwise","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"166 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"4","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"National Economic Trends","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.20955/ES.2003.17","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4

Abstract

R ecently the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) mentioned deflation as a possible risk for the U.S. economy. In the statement released after the May policy meeting, the Committee stated that “the probability of an unwelcome substantial fall in inflation, though minor, exceeds that of a pickup in inflation from its already low level.” Later, Chairman Greenspan spoke about more than just a mild deflation. In comments to the International Monetary Conference in early June, Chairman Greenspan referred to the risk of “corrosive” deflation “that essentially feeds on itself, creates falling asset prices, which in turn brings down levels of economic activity...” What is the main evidence on deflation? Are there corrosive and benign forms? Does economic perfor mance always suffer during periods of sustained deflation? The accompanying table provides some evidence on deflation and lists periods in which the United States or Japan have experienced three or more years of a declining price level. There are three main episodes: the late 19th century in the United States, the Great Depression in the United States, and Japan since 1999. For each deflationary episode, the table lists the average real GDP growth rate and the average inflation rate based on two popular inflation measures, the GDP deflator and the consumer price index. The table also lists a benchmark average growth rate of GDP for years surrounding the deflation experience, so we can consider whether deflation is associated with lower-than-average growth for the corresponding era or not. Generally speaking, the United States experienced rapid growth during the late 19th century, with GDP growth averaging about 4.0 percent for the period 1876-1900, despite an average deflation of about 1.0 percent. By itself, this suggests that a mild deflation is not necessarily asso ciated with poor economic performance. However, averaging over a long period of time could mask severe distress that may accompany deflation. To address this issue, we examine the subperiods 1876-1879 and 18831885. During the former, GDP growth actually was greater than the bench mark value, despite a rather hefty 3.0 to 4.0 percent annual average decline in the price level. Evidently, this deflationary episode was rather benign. In contrast, the deflationary episode of 1883-1885 was not so benign. GDP growth fell well below the benchmark average for that time. The same is also true at the onset of the Great Depression (1930-1933) and the recent episode in Japan (1999-2002). During the Great Depression, GDP growth averaged a whopping –8.36 percent and inflation was around –6.5 percent. While not as severe, Japan also experienced slow growth during its deflationary episode. As the table shows, U.S. experience with sustained deflation has been limited since the founding of the Federal Reserve in 1914. The results from 1930-1933 are uniformly bad, but deflation may simply have been a by-product of the economic collapse at that time. Japan’s experience is perhaps more relevant for today’s circumstances. Although sustained deflation is not everywhere and always “corrosive,” on balance the evidence suggests that deflationary episodes are marked by subpar growth. Deflation, Corrosive and Otherwise
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
通货紧缩,腐蚀和其他
最近,联邦公开市场委员会(FOMC)提到通货紧缩是美国经济可能面临的风险。在5月政策会议后发布的声明中,委员会表示,“通胀出现不受欢迎的大幅下降的可能性,尽管很小,但超过了通胀从已经很低的水平回升的可能性。”后来,格林斯潘主席谈到的不仅仅是温和的通货紧缩。在6月初的国际货币会议上,格林斯潘主席提到了“腐蚀性”通货紧缩的风险,“本质上是自食其害,造成资产价格下跌,进而降低经济活动水平……”通货紧缩的主要证据是什么?有腐蚀性的和良性的吗?在持续通缩期间,经济表现是否总是受到影响?随附的表格提供了一些关于通货紧缩的证据,并列出了美国或日本经历了三年或三年以上价格水平下降的时期。主要有三个时期:19世纪末的美国,大萧条时期的美国,以及1999年以来的日本。对于每一个通货紧缩时期,该表列出了基于两种流行的通货膨胀指标——GDP平减指数和消费者价格指数——的平均实际GDP增长率和平均通货膨胀率。该表还列出了通货紧缩前后几年GDP的基准平均增长率,因此我们可以考虑通货紧缩是否与相应时代的低于平均增长率有关。总的来说,美国在19世纪后期经历了快速增长,1876年至1900年期间GDP平均增长约4.0%,尽管平均通货紧缩约为1.0%。就其本身而言,这表明温和的通货紧缩并不一定与糟糕的经济表现有关。然而,在很长一段时间内进行平均可能会掩盖可能伴随通货紧缩的严重困境。为了解决这个问题,我们研究了1876-1879和18831885两个子时期。在前一阶段,尽管物价水平年均下降3.0%至4.0%,但GDP增长实际上高于基准值。显然,这段通缩时期是相当温和的。相比之下,1883年至1885年的通货紧缩时期就不那么温和了。GDP增长远远低于同期的基准平均水平。大萧条(1930年至1933年)和最近的日本大萧条(1999年至2002年)之初也是如此。在大萧条时期,GDP平均增长率高达- 8.36%,通货膨胀率约为- 6.5%。虽然没有那么严重,但日本在通货紧缩时期也经历了缓慢的增长。如表所示,自1914年美联储成立以来,美国持续通缩的经验一直有限。1930-1933年的结果都很糟糕,但通货紧缩可能只是当时经济崩溃的副产品。日本的经验或许更适用于今天的情况。尽管持续的通货紧缩并非无处不在,而且总是具有“腐蚀性”,但总的来说,有证据表明,通货紧缩时期的标志是经济增长低于平均水平。通货紧缩,腐蚀和其他
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
The seasonal cycle and the business cycle U.S. exporters: a rare breed Expected stock market returns and business investment Ringing in the new year with an investment bust A case for oil
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1