An Economic Perspective on Terrorism and Counterterrorism

IF 2.3 2区 社会学 Q1 INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS Terrorism and Political Violence Pub Date : 2023-10-03 DOI:10.1080/09546553.2023.2259992
Todd Sandler
{"title":"An Economic Perspective on Terrorism and Counterterrorism","authors":"Todd Sandler","doi":"10.1080/09546553.2023.2259992","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTThis occasional-series paper offers an economic perspective on the study of terrorism and counterterrorism. At the outset, the paper identifies how the economic perspective enriches terrorism analysis by stressing rational choice of myriad agents (e.g., the terrorist groups, their supporters, and targeted governments) subject to constraints. Game-theoretic strategic rational choice allows allied and adversarial agents to incorporate the responses of others into their interdependent choices. Economists’ theoretical paradigms are judged by their success in predicting agents’ behavior and informing effective policies. Since 9/11, many political scientists, operation researchers, sociologists, and others applied economic methods to their study of terrorism. To illustrate selected applications of the economic approach, the paper considers findings from economic studies on bargaining and making concessions during hostage incidents, judging the effectiveness of counterterrorism strategies, identifying the economic consequences of terrorism, and finding adequate identification strategies in empirical studies. Future directions and some shortcomings of the economic approach complete the study.KEYWORDS: Economic approachrationality and terrorismconcessions in hostage incidentseconomic consequences of terrorist attacksempirical identification strategies AcknowledgmentsThe author profited from comments from two anonymous reviewers.Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1. Lionel Robbins, The Nature and Significance of Economic Science (London: Macmillan, 1962), 16.2. Jack Hirshleifer, “The Expanding Domain of Economics,” American Economic Review 75, no. 6 (1985): 53–68.3. See, e.g., Navin A. Bapat, “Transnational Terrorism, US Military Aid, and the Incentive to Misrepresent,” Journal of Peace Research 48, no. 3 (2011): 303–18; Ethan Bueno de Mesquita, “Conciliation, Counterterrorism, and Patterns of Terrorist Violence,” International Organization 59, no. 1 (2005): 145–76; Ethan Bueno de Mesquita, “The Quality of Terror,” American Journal of Political Science 49, no. 3 (2005): 515–30; David B. Carter, “The Strategy of Territorial Conflict,” American Journal of Political Science 54, no. 4 (2010): 969–87; David B. Carter, “A Blessing or Curse? State Support for Terrorist Groups,” International Organization 66, no. 1 (2012): 129–51; James A. Piazza, “Incubators of Terror: Do Failed and Failing States Promote Transnational Terrorism?” International Studies Quarterly 52, no. 3 (2008): 469–88; James A. Piazza, “Poverty, Minority Economic Discrimination, and Domestic Terrorism,” Journal of Peace Research 48, no. 3 (2011): 339–53.4. Walter Enders and Todd Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism, 2nd ed. (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2012), 4.5. See, e.g., Yonah Alexander and Dennis Pluchinsky, Europe’s Red Terrorists: The Fighting Communist Organizations (London: Frank Cass, 1992); Martha Crenshaw, “The Causes of Terrorism,” Comparative Politics 13, no. 4 (1981): 379–99: William L. Eubank and Leonard B. Weinberg, “Does Democracy Encourage Terrorism?” Terrorism and Political Violence 6, no. 4 (1994): 417–35; Bruce Hoffman, Inside Terrorism, 3rd ed. (New York: Columbia University Press, 2012); Paul Wilkinson, Terrorism and the Liberal State, revised ed. (London: Frank Cass, 1986).6. Reinhard Selten, “A Simple Game Model of Kidnappings,” in Mathematical Economics and Game Theory: Essays in Honor of Oskar Morgenstern, ed. Rudolf Henn and Otto Moeschlin (Berlin: Springer, 1977), 139–55.7. Harvey E. Lapan and Todd Sandler, “To Bargain or Not to Bargain: That Is the Question,” American Economic Association Papers and Proceedings 78, no. 2 (1988): 16–21.8. William M. Landes, “An Economic Study of US Aircraft Hijackings, 1961–1976,” Journal of Law and Economics 21, no. 1 (1978): 1–31.9. Ibid., 12–13.10. Todd Sandler, John T. Tschirhart, and Jon Cauley, “A Theoretical Analysis of Transnational Terrorism,” American Political Science Review 77, no. 1 (1983): 36–54.11. Scott E. Atkinson, Todd Sandler, and John T. Tschirhart, “Terrorism in a Bargaining Framework,” Journal of Law and Economics 30, no. 1 (1987): 1–21.12. Charles H. Anderton and John R. Carter, “On Rational Choice Theory and the Study of Terrorism,” Defence and Peace Economics 16, no. 4 (2005): 275–82: Andreas Freytag, Jens J. Krüger, Daniel Meierrieks, and Friedrich Schneider, “The Origins of Terrorism: Cross-Country Estimates of Socio-Economic Determinants of Terrorism,” European Journal of Political Economy 27, no. Suppl. (2011): S5–S16; Sandler et al., “A Theoretical Analysis of Transnational Terrorism.”13. Walter Enders and Todd Sandler, “The Effectiveness of Antiterrorism Policies: A Vector-Autoregression-Intervention Analysis,” American Political Science Review 87, no. 4 (1993): 829–44; Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism.14. Enders and Sandler, “The Effectiveness of Antiterrorism Policies,” 839–41.15. Ibid., 843; Walter Enders and Todd Sandler, “What Do We know about the Substitution Effect in Transnational Terrorism,” in Researching Terrorism: Trends, Achievements and Failures, ed. Andrew Silke (Abingdon: Routledge, 2004), 119–37; Todd Sandler and Harvey E. Lapan, “The Calculus of Dissent: An Analysis of Terrorists’ Choice of Targets,” Synthese 76, no. 2 (1988): 245–61.16. Patrick T. Brandt and Todd Sandler, “What Do Transnational Terrorists Target? Has It Changed? Are We Safer?” Journal of Conflict Resolution 54, no. 2 (2010): 214–36; Patrick T. Brandt and Todd Sandler, “A Bayesian Poisson Vector Autoregression Model,” Political Analysis 20, no. 3 (2012): 292–315; Sara M. T. Polo, “The Quality of Terrorist Violence: Explaining the Logic of Terrorism Target Choice,” Journal of Peace Research 57, no. 2 (2020): 233–50; Sandler and Lapan, “The Calculus of Dissent.”17. Walter Enders and Todd Sandler, “Distribution of Transnational Terrorism among Countries by Income Classes and Geography after 9/11,” International Studies Quarterly 50, no. 2 (2006): 367–93; Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism.18. Todd Sandler, “The Analytical Study of Terrorism: Taking Stock,” Journal of Peace Research 51, no. 4 (2014): 257–71; Todd Sandler and Daniel G. Arce, “Terrorism and Game Theory,” Simulation and Gaming 34, no. 3 (2003): 319–37; Kevin Siqueira, “Political and Militant Wings within Dissident Movements and Organizations,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 49, no. 2 (2005): 218–36.19. Enders and Sandler, “The Effectiveness of Antiterrorism Policies,” 839–40; Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism.20. National Consortium for the Study of Terrorism and Responses to Terrorism (START), “Global Terrorism Database (GTD),” www.start.umd.edu/gtd/ (accessed February 3, 2023); Edward F. Mickolus, Todd Sandler, Jean M. Murdock, and Peter Flemming, International Terrorism: Attributes of Terrorist Events (ITERATE), 1968–2021 (Ponte Vedra, FL: Vinyard Software, 2022).21. For domestic terrorist incidents, the victims and perpetrators are citizens from the venue country of the attack. Transnational terrorist events involve victims or perpetrators or both from more than one country. If some of the victims or perpetrators are not citizens of the venue country, then the terrorist attack is also a transnational incident.22. Enders and Sandler, “The Effectiveness of Antiterrorism Policies”; Christopher Hewitt, Effectiveness of Anti-Terrorist Policies (Lanham, MD: University Press of America, 1984); Michele L. Malvesti, “Bombing bin Laden: Accessing the Effectiveness of Air Strikes as a Counter-Terrorism Strategy,” The Fletcher Forum of World Affairs 26, no. 1 (2002): 17–29; Nadav Morag, “Measuring Success in Coping with Terrorism: The Israeli Case,” Studies in Conflict & Terrorism 28, no. 4 (2005): 307–20.23. Mikel Buesa, Aurelia Valiño, Joost Heijs, Thomas Baumert, and Javier G. Gomez, “The Economic Costs of March 11: Measuring Direct Economic Cost of the Terrorist Attack on March 11, 2004,” Terrorism and Political Violence 19, no. 4 (2007): 489–509; Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism, 288–316.24. S. Brock Blomberg, Gregory D. Hess, and Athanasios Orphanides, “The Macroeconomic Consequences of Terrorism,” Journal of Monetary Economics 51, no. 5 (2004): 1007–32; Todd Sandler and Walter Enders, “Economic Consequences of Terrorism in Developed and Developing Countries: An Overview,” in Terrorism, Economic Development and Political Openness, ed. Philip Keefer and Norman Loayza (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2008), 17–47.25. See, e.g., case studies in Stephen D. Collins, “Dissuading State Support of Terrorism: Strikes or Sanctions? (An Analysis of Dissuasion Measures Employed against Libya),” Studies in Conflict & Terrorism 27, no. 1 (2004): 1–18; Hewitt, Effectiveness of Anti-Terrorist Policies; Malvesti, “Bombing bin Laden”; Morag, “Measuring Success in Coping with Terrorism.”26. Patrick T. Brandt, Justin George, and Todd Sandler, “Why Concessions Should Not Be Made to Terrorist Kidnappers,” European Journal of Political Economy 44 (2016): 41–52; Adam Dolnik and Keith M. Fitzgerald, Negotiating Hostage Crises with the New Terrorists (New York: Bloomsbury Academic, 2008); Margaret A. Wilson, “Toward a Model of Terrorist Behavior in Hostage-Taking Incidents,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 44, no. 4 (2000): 403–24.27. Konstantinos Drakos and Nicholas Giannakopoulos, “An Econometric Analysis of Counterterrorism Effectiveness: The Impact of Life and Property Losses,” Public Choice 139, no. 1 (2009): 135–51; Enders and Sandler, “The Effectiveness of Antiterrorism Policies”; Landes, “An Economic Study of US Aircraft Hijackings.”28. This percentage is based on data from ITERATE. The latest hostage-taking data with key variables coded currently end in 2018.29. Wukki Kim, Justin George, and Todd Sandler, “Introducing Transnational Terrorist Hostage Event (TTHE) Data Set, 1978 to 2018,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 65, no. 2–3 (2021): 619–41.30. Brandt et al., “Why Concessions Should Not Be Made to Terrorist Kidnappers.”31. These incidents and other larger scale hostage attacks are described in Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism, 350–52.32. Patrick T. Brandt and Todd Sandler, “Hostage Taking: Understanding Terrorism Event Dynamics,” Journal of Policy Modeling 31, no. 5 (2009): 758–78; Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism, 201–3; Wilson, “Toward a Model of Terrorist Behavior in Hostage-Taking Incidents.”33. Kerim P. Arin, Eberhard Feess, Torben Kuhlenkasper, and Otto F. M. Reich, “Negotiating with Terrorists: The Costs of Compliance,” Southern Economic Journal 86, no. 1 (2019): 305–17; Khusrav Gaibulloev and Todd Sandler, “Hostage Taking: Determinants of Terrorist Logistical and Negotiation Success,” Journal of Peace Research 46, no. 6 (2009): 739–56; Kim et al., “Introducing Transnational Terrorist Hostage Event (TTHE) Data Set.”34. Arin et al., “Negotiating with Terrorists”; Atkinson et al., “Terrorism in a Bargaining Framework”; Brandt and Sandler, “Hostage Taking”; Alexander Fink and Mark Pringle, “Kidnap Insurance and Its Impact on Kidnapping Outcomes,” Public Choice 160, no. 3–4 (2014): 481–99; Gaibulloev and Sandler, “Hostage Taking”; Lapan and Sandler, “To Bargain or Not to Bargain”; Chia-yi Lee, “Democracy, Civil Liberties, and Hostage-Taking Terrorism,” Journal of Peace Research 50, no. 2 (2013): 235–48; Charlinda Santifort and Todd Sandler, “Terrorist Success in Hostage-Taking Missions: 1978–2010,” Public Choice 156, no. 1–2 (2013): 125–37.35. Kim et al., “Introducing Transnational Terrorist Hostage Event (TTHE) Data Set,” 624–5.36. Avinash Dixit, Susan Skeath, and David Reiley, Jr., Games of Strategy, 4th ed. (New York: W. W. Norton & Co., 2015).37. See, e.g., Atkinson et al., “Terrorism in a Bargaining Framework”; Brandt and Sandler, “Hostage Taking”; Gaibulloev and Sandler, “Hostage Taking”; Lee, “Democracy, Civil Liberties, and Hostage-Taking Terrorism”; Santifort and Sandler, “Terrorist Success in Hostage-Taking Missions.”38. See, e.g., Kim et al., “Introducing Transnational Terrorist Hostage Event (TTHE) Data Set.”39. The relevant literature on this no-concession policy includes Arin et al., “Negotiating with Terrorists”; Brandt et al., “Why Concessions Should Not Be Made to Terrorist Kidnappers”; Brandt and Sandler, “Hostage Taking”; Lapan and Sandler, “To Bargain or Not to Bargain”; Steven Poe, “Nations’ Responses to Transnational Hostage Events: A Empirical Evaluation,” International Interaction 14, no. 1 (1988): 27–40; Aslihan Saygili, “Concessions or Crackdown: How Regime Stability Shapes Democratic Responses to Hostage Taking Terrorism,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 63, no. 2 (2019): 468–501; John L. Scott, “Reputation Building in Hostage Taking Incidents,” Defence and Peace Economics 2, no. 3 (1991): 209–18.40. Brandt et al., “Why Concessions Should Not Be Made to Terrorist Kidnappers,” 47–9.41. Ibid., 49–51.42. A similar result is found for skyjackings and barricade missions by Brandt and Sandler, “Hostage Taking.”43. Kim et al., “Introducing Transnational Terrorist Hostage Event (TTHE) Data Set.”44. Daniel G. Arce and Todd Sandler, “Counterterrorism: A Game-Theoretic Analysis,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 49, no. 2 (2005): 183–200; Subhayu Bandyopadhyay and Todd Sandler, “The Interplay between Preemptive and Defensive Counterterrorism Measures: A Two-Stage Game,” Economica 78, no. 311 (2011): 546–64; Navin A. Bapat, “The Internationalization of Terrorist Campaigns,” Conflict Management and Peace Science 24, no. 4 (2007): 265–80; Ethan Bueno de Mesquita, “Politics and the Suboptimal Provision of Counterterror,” International Organization 61, no. 1 (2007): 9–36; Eva Cárceles-Poveda and Yair Tauman, “A Strategic Analysis of the War against Transnational Terrorism,” Games and Economic Behavior 74, no. 1 (2011): 49–65; Harvey E. Lapan and Todd Sandler, “Terrorism and Signalling,” European Journal of Political Economy 9, no. 3 (1993): 383–97; Per B. Overgaard, “The Scale of Terrorist Attacks as a Signal of Resources,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 38, no. 3 (1994): 452–78; Sandler and Lapan, “The Calculus of Dissent”; Sandler et al., “A Theoretical Analysis of Transnational Terrorism”; Friedrich Schneider, Tilman Brück, and Daniel Meierrieks, “The Economics of Counterterrorism: A Survey,” Journal of Economic Surveys 29, no. 1 (2015): 131–57.45. Efraim Benmelech, Claude Berrebi, and Esteban F. Klor, “Counter-Suicide-Terrorism: Evidence from House Demolitions,” Journal of Politics 77, no. 1 (2015): 27–43; Walter Enders and Paan Jindapon, “Network Externalities and the Structure of Terror Networks,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 54, no. 2 (2020): 262–80; Daniel Jacobson and Edward H. Kaplan, “Suicide Bombings and Targeted Killings in (Counter-) Terror Games,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 51, no. 5 (2007): 772–92; Malvesti, “Bombing bin Laden”; Morag, “Measuring Success in Coping with Terrorism”; B. Peter Rosendorff and Todd Sandler, “Too Much of a Good Thing? The Proactive Response Dilemma,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 48, no. 5 (2004): 657–71.46. Bandyopadhyay and Sandler, “The Interplay between Preemptive and Defensive Counterterrorism Measures”; Cárceles-Poveda and Tauman, “A Strategic Analysis of the War against Transnational Terrorism”; Todd Sandler and Kevin Siqueira, “Global Terrorism: Deterrence versus Preemption,” Canadian Journal of Economics 39, no. 4 (2006): 1370–87.47. Anderton and Carter, “On Rational Choice Theory and the Study of Terrorism”; Laura Dugan and Erica Chenoweth, “Moving beyond Deterrence: The Effectiveness of Raising the Expected Utility of Abstaining from Terrorism in Israel,” American Sociological Review 77, no. 4 (2012): 597–624; Bruno S. Frey and Simon Luechinger, “How to Fight Terrorism: Alternatives to Deterrence,” Defence and Peace Economics 14, no. 4 (2003): 237–49; Morag, “Measuring Success in Coping with Terrorism.”48. Brandt and Sandler, “What Do Transnational Terrorists Target?”49. Bandyopadhyay and Sandler, “The Interplay between Preemptive and Defensive Counterterrorism Measures”; Sandler and Lapan, “The Calculus of Dissent.”50. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay, Todd Sandler, and Javed Younas, “Foreign Direct Investment, Aid, and Terrorism,” Oxford Economic Papers 66, no. 1 (2014): 25–50.51. On backlash, See, e.g., Daniel G. Arce and Todd Sandler, “Terrorist Spectaculars: Backlash Attacks and the Focus of Intelligence,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 54, no. 2 (2010): 354–73; Mia Bloom, Dying to Kill: The Allure of Suicide Terror (New York: Columbia University Press, 2005); Rosendorff and Sandler, “Too Much of a Good Thing?”; B. Peter Rosendorff and Todd Sandler, “Suicide Terrorism and the Backlash Effect,” Defence and Peace Economics 21, no. 5–6 (2010): 443–57.52. Hoffman, Inside Terrorism.53. Bandyopadhyay and Sandler, “The Interplay between Preemptive and Defensive Counterterrorism Measures”; Sandler and Lapan, “The Calculus of Dissent”; Sandler and Siqueira, “Global Terrorism.”54. Cárceles-Poveda and Tauman, “A Strategic Analysis of the War against Transnational Terrorism”; Andre R. de Oliveira, João R. Faria, and Emilson C. Silva, “Transnational Terrorism: Externalities and Coalition Formation,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 62, no. 3 (2018): 496–528.55. Sandler and Siqueira, “Global Terrorism.”56. Brandt and Sandler, “What Do Transnational Terrorists Target?” 220–4.57. Vicki Bier, Santiago Oliveros, and Larry Samuelson, “Choosing What to Protect: Strategic Defensive Allocation against an Unknown Attacker,” Journal of Public Economic Theory 9, no. 4 (2007): 563–87.58. Bandyopadhyay and Sandler, “The Interplay between Preemptive and Defensive Counterterrorism Measures.”59. Blomberg et al., “The Macroeconomic Consequences of Terrorism.”60. Jose Tavares, “The Open Society Assesses Its Enemies: Shocks, Disasters and Terrorist Attacks,” Journal of Monetary Economics 51, no. 5 (2004): 1039–70.61. S. Brock Blomberg, Nzinga H. Broussard, and Gregory D. Hess, “New Wine in Old Wineskins? Growth, Terrorism and the Resource Curse in sub-Saharan Africa,” European Journal of Political Economy 27, no. Suppl. (2011): S50–S63; Khusrav Gaibulloev and Todd Sandler, “Growth Consequences of Terrorism in Western Europe,” Kyklos 61, no. 3 (2008): 411–24; Khusrav Gaibulloev and Todd Sandler, “Impact of Terrorism and Conflicts on Growth in Asia,” Economics & Politics 21, no. 3 (2009): 359–83; Khusrav Gaibulloev and Todd Sandler, “The Adverse Effect of Transnational and Domestic Terrorism on Growth in Africa,” Journal of Peace Research 48, no. 3 (2011): 355–71.62. Gaibulloev and Sandler, “Impact of Terrorism and Conflicts on Growth in Asia”; Gaibulloev and Sandler, “The Adverse Effect of Transnational and Domestic Terrorism on Growth in Africa.”63. Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism, 290–8.64. Sandler and Enders, “Economic Consequences of Terrorism in Developed and Developing Countries.”65. Alberto Abadie and Javier Gardeazabal, “The Economic Cost of Conflict: A Case Study of the Basque Country,” American Economic Review 93, no. 1 (2003): 113–32; Zvi Eckstein and Daniel Tsiddon, “Macroeconomic Consequences of Terror: Theory and Case of Israel,” Journal of Monetary Economics 51, no. 5 (2004): 971–1002.66. Khusrav Gaibulloev, Todd Sandler, and Donggyu Sul, “Dynamic Panel Analysis under Cross-Sectional Dependence,” Political Analysis 22, no. 2 (2014): 258–73; Khusrav Gaibulloev and Todd Sandler, “Common Myths of Terrorism,” Journal of Economic Surveys 37, no. 2 (2023): 271–301.67. Gaibulloev and Sandler, “Common Myths of Terrorism.”68. Konstantinos Drakos and Andreas Gofas, “Regional Effects of Terrorism on Tourism in Three Mediterranean Countries,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 47, no. 5 (2003): 621–41; Walter Enders and Todd Sandler, “The Causality Between Transnational Terrorism and Tourism: The Case of Spain,” Terrorism: An International Journal 14, no. 1 (1991): 49–58; Walter Enders, Todd Sandler, and Gerry F. Parise, “An Econometric Analysis of the Impact of Terrorism on Tourism,” Kyklos 45, no. 4 (1992): 531–54.69. Enders et al., “An Econometric Analysis of the Impact of Terrorism on Tourism.”70. Walter Enders and Todd Sandler, “Terrorism and Foreign Direct Investment in Spain and Greece,” Kyklos 49, no. 3 (1996): 331–52.71. Alberto Abadie and Javier Gardeazabal, “Terrorism and the World Economy,” European Economic Review 52, no. 1 (2008): 1–27; Bandyopadhyay et al., “Foreign Direct Investment, Aid, and Terrorism”; Walter Enders, Adolfo Sachsida, and Todd Sandler, “The Impact of Transnational Terrorism on US Foreign Direct Investment,” Political Research Quarterly 59, no. 4 (2006): 517–31.72. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay, Todd Sandler, and Javed Younas, “Trade and Terrorism: A Disaggregated Approach,” Journal of Peace Research 55, no. 5 (2018): 656–70; S. Brock Blomberg and Gregory D. Hess, “How Much Does Violence Tax Trade?” Review of Economics and Statistics 88, no. 4 (2006): 599–612; Daniel Mirza and Thierry Verdier, “Are Lives a Substitute for Livelihoods? Terrorism, Security and US Bilateral Imports,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 58, no. 6 (2014): 943–75; Volker Nitsch and Dieter Schumacher, “Terrorism and International Trade: An Empirical Investigation,” European Journal of Political Economy 20, no. 2 (2004): 423–33.73. Abel Brodeur, “The Effect of Terrorism on Employment and Consumer Sentiments: Evidence from Successful and Failed Terror Attacks,” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 10, no. 4 (2018): 246–82.74. Yunhao Dai, Raghavendra Rau, Aris Stouraitis, and Weiqiang Tan, “An Ill Wind? Terrorist Attacks and CEO Compensation,” Journal of Financial Economics 135, no. 2 (2020): 379–98.75. Seongjae Mun, Seung H. Han, and Hyeong J. Kim, “Terrorist Attacks and Total Factor Productivity,” Economics Letters 202, Article 109808 (2021): 1–5.76. Wukki Kim and Todd Sandler, “Does Transnational Terrorism Stimulate Foreign Assistance?” Conflict Management and Peace Science 40, no. 2 (2023): 187–206.77. Joseph K. Young and Michael G. Findley, “Can Peace Be Purchased? A Sectoral-Level Analysis of Aid’s Influence on Transnational Terrorism,” Public Choice 149, no. 3–4 (2011): 365–81.78. Rafat Mahmood and Michael Jetter, “Gone with the Wind: The Consequences of US Drone Strikes in Pakistan,” Economic Journal 133, no. 2 (2023): 787–81.79. Ibid.80. See, e.g., Daniel Meierrieks and Laura Renner, “Islamist Terrorism and the Status of Women,” European Journal of Political Economy 78, Article 102364 (2023): 1–19.81. Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism, 322–28.82. On the choice of terrorist groups’ base of operations, consult Khusrav Gaibulloev, “Terrorist Group Location Decision: An Empirical Investigation,” Oxford Economic Papers 67, no. 1 (2015): 21–41. On the application of spatial econometrics to terrorism, See Josiah Marineau, Henry Pascoe, Alex Braithwaite, Michael G. Findley, and Joseph K. Young, “The Local Geography of Transnational Terrorism,” Conflict Management and Peace Science 37, no. 3 (2020): 350–81. This article identifies five local-level factors that influence the location of transnational terrorism based on the geocoding of ITERATE. The article does not look at group survival issues based on groups’ base locations.83. Enders and Jindapon, “Network Externalities and the Structure of Terror Networks”; Walter Enders and Xuejuan Su, “Rational Terrorists and Optimal Network Structure,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 51, no. 1 (2007): 33–57.Additional informationNotes on contributorsTodd SandlerTodd Sandler is Vibhooti Shukla Professor of Economics Emeritus at the University of Texas at Dallas. He has contributed articles and books on the economic study of terrorism since 1983. His articles on the topic has been published in the American Economic Review, American Political Science Review, Political Analysis, Journal of Conflict Resolution, Journal of Peace Research, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Journal of Law and Economics, and elsewhere. He has consulted on the topic with the United Nations Development Program, the U.S. Department of Homeland Security, and elsewhere.","PeriodicalId":51451,"journal":{"name":"Terrorism and Political Violence","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.3000,"publicationDate":"2023-10-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Terrorism and Political Violence","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/09546553.2023.2259992","RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

ABSTRACTThis occasional-series paper offers an economic perspective on the study of terrorism and counterterrorism. At the outset, the paper identifies how the economic perspective enriches terrorism analysis by stressing rational choice of myriad agents (e.g., the terrorist groups, their supporters, and targeted governments) subject to constraints. Game-theoretic strategic rational choice allows allied and adversarial agents to incorporate the responses of others into their interdependent choices. Economists’ theoretical paradigms are judged by their success in predicting agents’ behavior and informing effective policies. Since 9/11, many political scientists, operation researchers, sociologists, and others applied economic methods to their study of terrorism. To illustrate selected applications of the economic approach, the paper considers findings from economic studies on bargaining and making concessions during hostage incidents, judging the effectiveness of counterterrorism strategies, identifying the economic consequences of terrorism, and finding adequate identification strategies in empirical studies. Future directions and some shortcomings of the economic approach complete the study.KEYWORDS: Economic approachrationality and terrorismconcessions in hostage incidentseconomic consequences of terrorist attacksempirical identification strategies AcknowledgmentsThe author profited from comments from two anonymous reviewers.Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1. Lionel Robbins, The Nature and Significance of Economic Science (London: Macmillan, 1962), 16.2. Jack Hirshleifer, “The Expanding Domain of Economics,” American Economic Review 75, no. 6 (1985): 53–68.3. See, e.g., Navin A. Bapat, “Transnational Terrorism, US Military Aid, and the Incentive to Misrepresent,” Journal of Peace Research 48, no. 3 (2011): 303–18; Ethan Bueno de Mesquita, “Conciliation, Counterterrorism, and Patterns of Terrorist Violence,” International Organization 59, no. 1 (2005): 145–76; Ethan Bueno de Mesquita, “The Quality of Terror,” American Journal of Political Science 49, no. 3 (2005): 515–30; David B. Carter, “The Strategy of Territorial Conflict,” American Journal of Political Science 54, no. 4 (2010): 969–87; David B. Carter, “A Blessing or Curse? State Support for Terrorist Groups,” International Organization 66, no. 1 (2012): 129–51; James A. Piazza, “Incubators of Terror: Do Failed and Failing States Promote Transnational Terrorism?” International Studies Quarterly 52, no. 3 (2008): 469–88; James A. Piazza, “Poverty, Minority Economic Discrimination, and Domestic Terrorism,” Journal of Peace Research 48, no. 3 (2011): 339–53.4. Walter Enders and Todd Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism, 2nd ed. (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2012), 4.5. See, e.g., Yonah Alexander and Dennis Pluchinsky, Europe’s Red Terrorists: The Fighting Communist Organizations (London: Frank Cass, 1992); Martha Crenshaw, “The Causes of Terrorism,” Comparative Politics 13, no. 4 (1981): 379–99: William L. Eubank and Leonard B. Weinberg, “Does Democracy Encourage Terrorism?” Terrorism and Political Violence 6, no. 4 (1994): 417–35; Bruce Hoffman, Inside Terrorism, 3rd ed. (New York: Columbia University Press, 2012); Paul Wilkinson, Terrorism and the Liberal State, revised ed. (London: Frank Cass, 1986).6. Reinhard Selten, “A Simple Game Model of Kidnappings,” in Mathematical Economics and Game Theory: Essays in Honor of Oskar Morgenstern, ed. Rudolf Henn and Otto Moeschlin (Berlin: Springer, 1977), 139–55.7. Harvey E. Lapan and Todd Sandler, “To Bargain or Not to Bargain: That Is the Question,” American Economic Association Papers and Proceedings 78, no. 2 (1988): 16–21.8. William M. Landes, “An Economic Study of US Aircraft Hijackings, 1961–1976,” Journal of Law and Economics 21, no. 1 (1978): 1–31.9. Ibid., 12–13.10. Todd Sandler, John T. Tschirhart, and Jon Cauley, “A Theoretical Analysis of Transnational Terrorism,” American Political Science Review 77, no. 1 (1983): 36–54.11. Scott E. Atkinson, Todd Sandler, and John T. Tschirhart, “Terrorism in a Bargaining Framework,” Journal of Law and Economics 30, no. 1 (1987): 1–21.12. Charles H. Anderton and John R. Carter, “On Rational Choice Theory and the Study of Terrorism,” Defence and Peace Economics 16, no. 4 (2005): 275–82: Andreas Freytag, Jens J. Krüger, Daniel Meierrieks, and Friedrich Schneider, “The Origins of Terrorism: Cross-Country Estimates of Socio-Economic Determinants of Terrorism,” European Journal of Political Economy 27, no. Suppl. (2011): S5–S16; Sandler et al., “A Theoretical Analysis of Transnational Terrorism.”13. Walter Enders and Todd Sandler, “The Effectiveness of Antiterrorism Policies: A Vector-Autoregression-Intervention Analysis,” American Political Science Review 87, no. 4 (1993): 829–44; Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism.14. Enders and Sandler, “The Effectiveness of Antiterrorism Policies,” 839–41.15. Ibid., 843; Walter Enders and Todd Sandler, “What Do We know about the Substitution Effect in Transnational Terrorism,” in Researching Terrorism: Trends, Achievements and Failures, ed. Andrew Silke (Abingdon: Routledge, 2004), 119–37; Todd Sandler and Harvey E. Lapan, “The Calculus of Dissent: An Analysis of Terrorists’ Choice of Targets,” Synthese 76, no. 2 (1988): 245–61.16. Patrick T. Brandt and Todd Sandler, “What Do Transnational Terrorists Target? Has It Changed? Are We Safer?” Journal of Conflict Resolution 54, no. 2 (2010): 214–36; Patrick T. Brandt and Todd Sandler, “A Bayesian Poisson Vector Autoregression Model,” Political Analysis 20, no. 3 (2012): 292–315; Sara M. T. Polo, “The Quality of Terrorist Violence: Explaining the Logic of Terrorism Target Choice,” Journal of Peace Research 57, no. 2 (2020): 233–50; Sandler and Lapan, “The Calculus of Dissent.”17. Walter Enders and Todd Sandler, “Distribution of Transnational Terrorism among Countries by Income Classes and Geography after 9/11,” International Studies Quarterly 50, no. 2 (2006): 367–93; Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism.18. Todd Sandler, “The Analytical Study of Terrorism: Taking Stock,” Journal of Peace Research 51, no. 4 (2014): 257–71; Todd Sandler and Daniel G. Arce, “Terrorism and Game Theory,” Simulation and Gaming 34, no. 3 (2003): 319–37; Kevin Siqueira, “Political and Militant Wings within Dissident Movements and Organizations,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 49, no. 2 (2005): 218–36.19. Enders and Sandler, “The Effectiveness of Antiterrorism Policies,” 839–40; Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism.20. National Consortium for the Study of Terrorism and Responses to Terrorism (START), “Global Terrorism Database (GTD),” www.start.umd.edu/gtd/ (accessed February 3, 2023); Edward F. Mickolus, Todd Sandler, Jean M. Murdock, and Peter Flemming, International Terrorism: Attributes of Terrorist Events (ITERATE), 1968–2021 (Ponte Vedra, FL: Vinyard Software, 2022).21. For domestic terrorist incidents, the victims and perpetrators are citizens from the venue country of the attack. Transnational terrorist events involve victims or perpetrators or both from more than one country. If some of the victims or perpetrators are not citizens of the venue country, then the terrorist attack is also a transnational incident.22. Enders and Sandler, “The Effectiveness of Antiterrorism Policies”; Christopher Hewitt, Effectiveness of Anti-Terrorist Policies (Lanham, MD: University Press of America, 1984); Michele L. Malvesti, “Bombing bin Laden: Accessing the Effectiveness of Air Strikes as a Counter-Terrorism Strategy,” The Fletcher Forum of World Affairs 26, no. 1 (2002): 17–29; Nadav Morag, “Measuring Success in Coping with Terrorism: The Israeli Case,” Studies in Conflict & Terrorism 28, no. 4 (2005): 307–20.23. Mikel Buesa, Aurelia Valiño, Joost Heijs, Thomas Baumert, and Javier G. Gomez, “The Economic Costs of March 11: Measuring Direct Economic Cost of the Terrorist Attack on March 11, 2004,” Terrorism and Political Violence 19, no. 4 (2007): 489–509; Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism, 288–316.24. S. Brock Blomberg, Gregory D. Hess, and Athanasios Orphanides, “The Macroeconomic Consequences of Terrorism,” Journal of Monetary Economics 51, no. 5 (2004): 1007–32; Todd Sandler and Walter Enders, “Economic Consequences of Terrorism in Developed and Developing Countries: An Overview,” in Terrorism, Economic Development and Political Openness, ed. Philip Keefer and Norman Loayza (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2008), 17–47.25. See, e.g., case studies in Stephen D. Collins, “Dissuading State Support of Terrorism: Strikes or Sanctions? (An Analysis of Dissuasion Measures Employed against Libya),” Studies in Conflict & Terrorism 27, no. 1 (2004): 1–18; Hewitt, Effectiveness of Anti-Terrorist Policies; Malvesti, “Bombing bin Laden”; Morag, “Measuring Success in Coping with Terrorism.”26. Patrick T. Brandt, Justin George, and Todd Sandler, “Why Concessions Should Not Be Made to Terrorist Kidnappers,” European Journal of Political Economy 44 (2016): 41–52; Adam Dolnik and Keith M. Fitzgerald, Negotiating Hostage Crises with the New Terrorists (New York: Bloomsbury Academic, 2008); Margaret A. Wilson, “Toward a Model of Terrorist Behavior in Hostage-Taking Incidents,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 44, no. 4 (2000): 403–24.27. Konstantinos Drakos and Nicholas Giannakopoulos, “An Econometric Analysis of Counterterrorism Effectiveness: The Impact of Life and Property Losses,” Public Choice 139, no. 1 (2009): 135–51; Enders and Sandler, “The Effectiveness of Antiterrorism Policies”; Landes, “An Economic Study of US Aircraft Hijackings.”28. This percentage is based on data from ITERATE. The latest hostage-taking data with key variables coded currently end in 2018.29. Wukki Kim, Justin George, and Todd Sandler, “Introducing Transnational Terrorist Hostage Event (TTHE) Data Set, 1978 to 2018,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 65, no. 2–3 (2021): 619–41.30. Brandt et al., “Why Concessions Should Not Be Made to Terrorist Kidnappers.”31. These incidents and other larger scale hostage attacks are described in Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism, 350–52.32. Patrick T. Brandt and Todd Sandler, “Hostage Taking: Understanding Terrorism Event Dynamics,” Journal of Policy Modeling 31, no. 5 (2009): 758–78; Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism, 201–3; Wilson, “Toward a Model of Terrorist Behavior in Hostage-Taking Incidents.”33. Kerim P. Arin, Eberhard Feess, Torben Kuhlenkasper, and Otto F. M. Reich, “Negotiating with Terrorists: The Costs of Compliance,” Southern Economic Journal 86, no. 1 (2019): 305–17; Khusrav Gaibulloev and Todd Sandler, “Hostage Taking: Determinants of Terrorist Logistical and Negotiation Success,” Journal of Peace Research 46, no. 6 (2009): 739–56; Kim et al., “Introducing Transnational Terrorist Hostage Event (TTHE) Data Set.”34. Arin et al., “Negotiating with Terrorists”; Atkinson et al., “Terrorism in a Bargaining Framework”; Brandt and Sandler, “Hostage Taking”; Alexander Fink and Mark Pringle, “Kidnap Insurance and Its Impact on Kidnapping Outcomes,” Public Choice 160, no. 3–4 (2014): 481–99; Gaibulloev and Sandler, “Hostage Taking”; Lapan and Sandler, “To Bargain or Not to Bargain”; Chia-yi Lee, “Democracy, Civil Liberties, and Hostage-Taking Terrorism,” Journal of Peace Research 50, no. 2 (2013): 235–48; Charlinda Santifort and Todd Sandler, “Terrorist Success in Hostage-Taking Missions: 1978–2010,” Public Choice 156, no. 1–2 (2013): 125–37.35. Kim et al., “Introducing Transnational Terrorist Hostage Event (TTHE) Data Set,” 624–5.36. Avinash Dixit, Susan Skeath, and David Reiley, Jr., Games of Strategy, 4th ed. (New York: W. W. Norton & Co., 2015).37. See, e.g., Atkinson et al., “Terrorism in a Bargaining Framework”; Brandt and Sandler, “Hostage Taking”; Gaibulloev and Sandler, “Hostage Taking”; Lee, “Democracy, Civil Liberties, and Hostage-Taking Terrorism”; Santifort and Sandler, “Terrorist Success in Hostage-Taking Missions.”38. See, e.g., Kim et al., “Introducing Transnational Terrorist Hostage Event (TTHE) Data Set.”39. The relevant literature on this no-concession policy includes Arin et al., “Negotiating with Terrorists”; Brandt et al., “Why Concessions Should Not Be Made to Terrorist Kidnappers”; Brandt and Sandler, “Hostage Taking”; Lapan and Sandler, “To Bargain or Not to Bargain”; Steven Poe, “Nations’ Responses to Transnational Hostage Events: A Empirical Evaluation,” International Interaction 14, no. 1 (1988): 27–40; Aslihan Saygili, “Concessions or Crackdown: How Regime Stability Shapes Democratic Responses to Hostage Taking Terrorism,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 63, no. 2 (2019): 468–501; John L. Scott, “Reputation Building in Hostage Taking Incidents,” Defence and Peace Economics 2, no. 3 (1991): 209–18.40. Brandt et al., “Why Concessions Should Not Be Made to Terrorist Kidnappers,” 47–9.41. Ibid., 49–51.42. A similar result is found for skyjackings and barricade missions by Brandt and Sandler, “Hostage Taking.”43. Kim et al., “Introducing Transnational Terrorist Hostage Event (TTHE) Data Set.”44. Daniel G. Arce and Todd Sandler, “Counterterrorism: A Game-Theoretic Analysis,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 49, no. 2 (2005): 183–200; Subhayu Bandyopadhyay and Todd Sandler, “The Interplay between Preemptive and Defensive Counterterrorism Measures: A Two-Stage Game,” Economica 78, no. 311 (2011): 546–64; Navin A. Bapat, “The Internationalization of Terrorist Campaigns,” Conflict Management and Peace Science 24, no. 4 (2007): 265–80; Ethan Bueno de Mesquita, “Politics and the Suboptimal Provision of Counterterror,” International Organization 61, no. 1 (2007): 9–36; Eva Cárceles-Poveda and Yair Tauman, “A Strategic Analysis of the War against Transnational Terrorism,” Games and Economic Behavior 74, no. 1 (2011): 49–65; Harvey E. Lapan and Todd Sandler, “Terrorism and Signalling,” European Journal of Political Economy 9, no. 3 (1993): 383–97; Per B. Overgaard, “The Scale of Terrorist Attacks as a Signal of Resources,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 38, no. 3 (1994): 452–78; Sandler and Lapan, “The Calculus of Dissent”; Sandler et al., “A Theoretical Analysis of Transnational Terrorism”; Friedrich Schneider, Tilman Brück, and Daniel Meierrieks, “The Economics of Counterterrorism: A Survey,” Journal of Economic Surveys 29, no. 1 (2015): 131–57.45. Efraim Benmelech, Claude Berrebi, and Esteban F. Klor, “Counter-Suicide-Terrorism: Evidence from House Demolitions,” Journal of Politics 77, no. 1 (2015): 27–43; Walter Enders and Paan Jindapon, “Network Externalities and the Structure of Terror Networks,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 54, no. 2 (2020): 262–80; Daniel Jacobson and Edward H. Kaplan, “Suicide Bombings and Targeted Killings in (Counter-) Terror Games,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 51, no. 5 (2007): 772–92; Malvesti, “Bombing bin Laden”; Morag, “Measuring Success in Coping with Terrorism”; B. Peter Rosendorff and Todd Sandler, “Too Much of a Good Thing? The Proactive Response Dilemma,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 48, no. 5 (2004): 657–71.46. Bandyopadhyay and Sandler, “The Interplay between Preemptive and Defensive Counterterrorism Measures”; Cárceles-Poveda and Tauman, “A Strategic Analysis of the War against Transnational Terrorism”; Todd Sandler and Kevin Siqueira, “Global Terrorism: Deterrence versus Preemption,” Canadian Journal of Economics 39, no. 4 (2006): 1370–87.47. Anderton and Carter, “On Rational Choice Theory and the Study of Terrorism”; Laura Dugan and Erica Chenoweth, “Moving beyond Deterrence: The Effectiveness of Raising the Expected Utility of Abstaining from Terrorism in Israel,” American Sociological Review 77, no. 4 (2012): 597–624; Bruno S. Frey and Simon Luechinger, “How to Fight Terrorism: Alternatives to Deterrence,” Defence and Peace Economics 14, no. 4 (2003): 237–49; Morag, “Measuring Success in Coping with Terrorism.”48. Brandt and Sandler, “What Do Transnational Terrorists Target?”49. Bandyopadhyay and Sandler, “The Interplay between Preemptive and Defensive Counterterrorism Measures”; Sandler and Lapan, “The Calculus of Dissent.”50. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay, Todd Sandler, and Javed Younas, “Foreign Direct Investment, Aid, and Terrorism,” Oxford Economic Papers 66, no. 1 (2014): 25–50.51. On backlash, See, e.g., Daniel G. Arce and Todd Sandler, “Terrorist Spectaculars: Backlash Attacks and the Focus of Intelligence,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 54, no. 2 (2010): 354–73; Mia Bloom, Dying to Kill: The Allure of Suicide Terror (New York: Columbia University Press, 2005); Rosendorff and Sandler, “Too Much of a Good Thing?”; B. Peter Rosendorff and Todd Sandler, “Suicide Terrorism and the Backlash Effect,” Defence and Peace Economics 21, no. 5–6 (2010): 443–57.52. Hoffman, Inside Terrorism.53. Bandyopadhyay and Sandler, “The Interplay between Preemptive and Defensive Counterterrorism Measures”; Sandler and Lapan, “The Calculus of Dissent”; Sandler and Siqueira, “Global Terrorism.”54. Cárceles-Poveda and Tauman, “A Strategic Analysis of the War against Transnational Terrorism”; Andre R. de Oliveira, João R. Faria, and Emilson C. Silva, “Transnational Terrorism: Externalities and Coalition Formation,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 62, no. 3 (2018): 496–528.55. Sandler and Siqueira, “Global Terrorism.”56. Brandt and Sandler, “What Do Transnational Terrorists Target?” 220–4.57. Vicki Bier, Santiago Oliveros, and Larry Samuelson, “Choosing What to Protect: Strategic Defensive Allocation against an Unknown Attacker,” Journal of Public Economic Theory 9, no. 4 (2007): 563–87.58. Bandyopadhyay and Sandler, “The Interplay between Preemptive and Defensive Counterterrorism Measures.”59. Blomberg et al., “The Macroeconomic Consequences of Terrorism.”60. Jose Tavares, “The Open Society Assesses Its Enemies: Shocks, Disasters and Terrorist Attacks,” Journal of Monetary Economics 51, no. 5 (2004): 1039–70.61. S. Brock Blomberg, Nzinga H. Broussard, and Gregory D. Hess, “New Wine in Old Wineskins? Growth, Terrorism and the Resource Curse in sub-Saharan Africa,” European Journal of Political Economy 27, no. Suppl. (2011): S50–S63; Khusrav Gaibulloev and Todd Sandler, “Growth Consequences of Terrorism in Western Europe,” Kyklos 61, no. 3 (2008): 411–24; Khusrav Gaibulloev and Todd Sandler, “Impact of Terrorism and Conflicts on Growth in Asia,” Economics & Politics 21, no. 3 (2009): 359–83; Khusrav Gaibulloev and Todd Sandler, “The Adverse Effect of Transnational and Domestic Terrorism on Growth in Africa,” Journal of Peace Research 48, no. 3 (2011): 355–71.62. Gaibulloev and Sandler, “Impact of Terrorism and Conflicts on Growth in Asia”; Gaibulloev and Sandler, “The Adverse Effect of Transnational and Domestic Terrorism on Growth in Africa.”63. Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism, 290–8.64. Sandler and Enders, “Economic Consequences of Terrorism in Developed and Developing Countries.”65. Alberto Abadie and Javier Gardeazabal, “The Economic Cost of Conflict: A Case Study of the Basque Country,” American Economic Review 93, no. 1 (2003): 113–32; Zvi Eckstein and Daniel Tsiddon, “Macroeconomic Consequences of Terror: Theory and Case of Israel,” Journal of Monetary Economics 51, no. 5 (2004): 971–1002.66. Khusrav Gaibulloev, Todd Sandler, and Donggyu Sul, “Dynamic Panel Analysis under Cross-Sectional Dependence,” Political Analysis 22, no. 2 (2014): 258–73; Khusrav Gaibulloev and Todd Sandler, “Common Myths of Terrorism,” Journal of Economic Surveys 37, no. 2 (2023): 271–301.67. Gaibulloev and Sandler, “Common Myths of Terrorism.”68. Konstantinos Drakos and Andreas Gofas, “Regional Effects of Terrorism on Tourism in Three Mediterranean Countries,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 47, no. 5 (2003): 621–41; Walter Enders and Todd Sandler, “The Causality Between Transnational Terrorism and Tourism: The Case of Spain,” Terrorism: An International Journal 14, no. 1 (1991): 49–58; Walter Enders, Todd Sandler, and Gerry F. Parise, “An Econometric Analysis of the Impact of Terrorism on Tourism,” Kyklos 45, no. 4 (1992): 531–54.69. Enders et al., “An Econometric Analysis of the Impact of Terrorism on Tourism.”70. Walter Enders and Todd Sandler, “Terrorism and Foreign Direct Investment in Spain and Greece,” Kyklos 49, no. 3 (1996): 331–52.71. Alberto Abadie and Javier Gardeazabal, “Terrorism and the World Economy,” European Economic Review 52, no. 1 (2008): 1–27; Bandyopadhyay et al., “Foreign Direct Investment, Aid, and Terrorism”; Walter Enders, Adolfo Sachsida, and Todd Sandler, “The Impact of Transnational Terrorism on US Foreign Direct Investment,” Political Research Quarterly 59, no. 4 (2006): 517–31.72. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay, Todd Sandler, and Javed Younas, “Trade and Terrorism: A Disaggregated Approach,” Journal of Peace Research 55, no. 5 (2018): 656–70; S. Brock Blomberg and Gregory D. Hess, “How Much Does Violence Tax Trade?” Review of Economics and Statistics 88, no. 4 (2006): 599–612; Daniel Mirza and Thierry Verdier, “Are Lives a Substitute for Livelihoods? Terrorism, Security and US Bilateral Imports,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 58, no. 6 (2014): 943–75; Volker Nitsch and Dieter Schumacher, “Terrorism and International Trade: An Empirical Investigation,” European Journal of Political Economy 20, no. 2 (2004): 423–33.73. Abel Brodeur, “The Effect of Terrorism on Employment and Consumer Sentiments: Evidence from Successful and Failed Terror Attacks,” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 10, no. 4 (2018): 246–82.74. Yunhao Dai, Raghavendra Rau, Aris Stouraitis, and Weiqiang Tan, “An Ill Wind? Terrorist Attacks and CEO Compensation,” Journal of Financial Economics 135, no. 2 (2020): 379–98.75. Seongjae Mun, Seung H. Han, and Hyeong J. Kim, “Terrorist Attacks and Total Factor Productivity,” Economics Letters 202, Article 109808 (2021): 1–5.76. Wukki Kim and Todd Sandler, “Does Transnational Terrorism Stimulate Foreign Assistance?” Conflict Management and Peace Science 40, no. 2 (2023): 187–206.77. Joseph K. Young and Michael G. Findley, “Can Peace Be Purchased? A Sectoral-Level Analysis of Aid’s Influence on Transnational Terrorism,” Public Choice 149, no. 3–4 (2011): 365–81.78. Rafat Mahmood and Michael Jetter, “Gone with the Wind: The Consequences of US Drone Strikes in Pakistan,” Economic Journal 133, no. 2 (2023): 787–81.79. Ibid.80. See, e.g., Daniel Meierrieks and Laura Renner, “Islamist Terrorism and the Status of Women,” European Journal of Political Economy 78, Article 102364 (2023): 1–19.81. Enders and Sandler, The Political Economy of Terrorism, 322–28.82. On the choice of terrorist groups’ base of operations, consult Khusrav Gaibulloev, “Terrorist Group Location Decision: An Empirical Investigation,” Oxford Economic Papers 67, no. 1 (2015): 21–41. On the application of spatial econometrics to terrorism, See Josiah Marineau, Henry Pascoe, Alex Braithwaite, Michael G. Findley, and Joseph K. Young, “The Local Geography of Transnational Terrorism,” Conflict Management and Peace Science 37, no. 3 (2020): 350–81. This article identifies five local-level factors that influence the location of transnational terrorism based on the geocoding of ITERATE. The article does not look at group survival issues based on groups’ base locations.83. Enders and Jindapon, “Network Externalities and the Structure of Terror Networks”; Walter Enders and Xuejuan Su, “Rational Terrorists and Optimal Network Structure,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 51, no. 1 (2007): 33–57.Additional informationNotes on contributorsTodd SandlerTodd Sandler is Vibhooti Shukla Professor of Economics Emeritus at the University of Texas at Dallas. He has contributed articles and books on the economic study of terrorism since 1983. His articles on the topic has been published in the American Economic Review, American Political Science Review, Political Analysis, Journal of Conflict Resolution, Journal of Peace Research, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Journal of Law and Economics, and elsewhere. He has consulted on the topic with the United Nations Development Program, the U.S. Department of Homeland Security, and elsewhere.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
从经济角度看恐怖主义和反恐
摘要本文从经济学的角度对恐怖主义和反恐问题进行了研究。首先,本文确定了经济视角如何通过强调受约束的无数行动者(如恐怖组织、其支持者和目标政府)的理性选择来丰富恐怖主义分析。博弈论的战略理性选择允许联盟和敌对代理将他人的反应纳入他们相互依赖的选择中。经济学家的理论范式是通过他们在预测代理人行为和告知有效政策方面的成功来判断的。自9/11以来,许多政治学家、运筹学家、社会学家和其他人将经济方法应用于他们对恐怖主义的研究。为了说明经济方法的选择应用,本文考虑了在人质事件中讨价还价和做出让步的经济研究结果,判断反恐战略的有效性,识别恐怖主义的经济后果,并在实证研究中找到适当的识别策略。未来的方向和一些不足的经济方法完成研究。关键词:经济学方法;理性与恐怖主义;人质事件中的让步;恐怖袭击的经济后果;实证识别策略。披露声明作者未报告潜在的利益冲突。莱昂内尔·罗宾斯,《经济学的性质与意义》(伦敦:麦克米伦出版社,1962),第16.2页。杰克·赫施莱弗,《不断扩大的经济学领域》,《美国经济评论》第75期。6(1985): 53-68.3。参见,例如,Navin A. Bapat,“跨国恐怖主义,美国军事援助和歪曲的动机”,《和平研究杂志》48期,第2期。3 (2011): 303-18;伊桑·布埃诺·德·梅斯奎塔,《和解、反恐和恐怖主义暴力模式》,《国际组织》第59期,第2期。1 (2005): 145-76;伊桑·布埃诺·德·梅斯奎塔,《恐怖的性质》,《美国政治科学杂志》第49期,第2期。3 (2005): 515-30;David B. Carter,“领土冲突的策略”,《美国政治科学杂志》,第54期。4 (2010): 969-87;大卫·b·卡特,《祝福还是诅咒?》国家对恐怖组织的支持"国际组织66号。1 (2012): 129-51;James A. Piazza,《恐怖的孵化器:失败的和即将失败的国家会促进跨国恐怖主义吗?》国际研究季刊,第52期。3 (2008): 469-88;James A. Piazza,《贫困、少数民族经济歧视与国内恐怖主义》,《和平研究》第48期。3(2011): 339-53.4。沃尔特·恩德斯和托德·桑德勒,《恐怖主义的政治经济学》,第二版(纽约:剑桥大学出版社,2012),第4.5页。参见,例如,Yonah Alexander和Dennis Pluchinsky,欧洲的红色恐怖分子:战斗的共产主义组织(伦敦:Frank Cass, 1992);玛莎·克伦肖,《恐怖主义的起因》,《比较政治》第13期,第2期。4(1981): 379-99:威廉L.尤班克和伦纳德B.温伯格,“民主鼓励恐怖主义吗?”恐怖主义和政治暴力6号。4 (1994): 417-35;布鲁斯·霍夫曼:《恐怖主义内部》,第3版(纽约:哥伦比亚大学出版社,2012);6.保罗·威尔金森:《恐怖主义与自由国家》,修订版(伦敦:弗兰克·卡斯出版社,1986)。Reinhard Selten,“绑架的一个简单的游戏模型”,载于数学经济学和博弈论:纪念奥斯卡·摩根斯坦的论文,Rudolf Henn和Otto Moeschlin编辑(柏林:Springer出版社,1977),139-55.7页。哈维·e·拉潘、托德·桑德勒:《讨价还价还是不讨价还价:这是一个问题》,《美国经济学会论文集》第78期。2(1988): 16-21.8。William M. Landes,《1961-1976年美国劫机事件的经济学研究》,《法律与经济学杂志》第21期,第2期。1(1978): 1 - 31.9。出处同上,12 - 13.10。Todd Sandler, John T. Tschirhart和Jon Cauley,《跨国恐怖主义的理论分析》,《美国政治科学评论》第77期。1(1983): 36-54.11。Scott E. Atkinson, Todd Sandler, John T. Tschirhart,《讨价还价框架中的恐怖主义》,《法律与经济杂志》,第30期。1(1987): 1 - 21.12。查尔斯·h·安德顿和约翰·r·卡特,《理性选择理论与恐怖主义研究》,《国防与和平经济》第16期。杨建军,杨建军,杨建军,“恐怖主义的社会经济影响因素的实证研究”,《国际经济研究》,2005年第4期。增刊。(2011): S5-S16;桑德勒等人,《跨国恐怖主义的理论分析》,13。Walter Enders和Todd Sandler,“反恐政策的有效性:向量自回归干预分析”,《美国政治科学评论》第87期。4 (1993): 829-44;恩德斯和桑德勒:《恐怖主义的政治经济学》,第14页。 恩德斯和桑德勒,《反恐政策的有效性》,839-41.15。出处同上,843;沃尔特·恩德斯和托德·桑德勒,“我们对跨国恐怖主义中的替代效应了解多少”,《研究恐怖主义:趋势、成就和失败》,安德鲁·西尔克主编(阿宾登:劳特利奇出版社,2004),第119-37页;托德·桑德勒和哈维·e·拉潘,《异议的计算:对恐怖分子选择目标的分析》,《综合》76期,第2期。2(1988): 245-61.16。Patrick T. Brandt和Todd Sandler,《跨国恐怖分子的目标是什么?》它改变了吗?我们更安全吗?”《冲突解决》杂志,第54期。2 (2010): 214-36;Patrick T. Brandt和Todd Sandler,“一个贝叶斯泊松向量自回归模型”,《政治分析》第20期。3 (2012): 292-315;Sara M. T. Polo,“恐怖主义暴力的性质:解释恐怖主义目标选择的逻辑”,《和平研究杂志》第57期。2 (2020): 233-50;桑德勒和拉潘,《异议的计算》,第17页。沃尔特·恩德斯和托德·桑德勒:《9/11事件后跨国恐怖主义在不同收入阶层和地理区域的分布》,《国际研究季刊》,第50期。2 (2006): 367-93;恩德斯和桑德勒,《恐怖主义的政治经济学》,第18页。托德·桑德勒,《恐怖主义的分析研究:盘点》,《和平研究杂志》第51期。4 (2014): 257-71;Todd Sandler和Daniel G. Arce,“恐怖主义和博弈论”,《模拟与游戏》第34期,no。3 (2003): 319-37;Kevin Siqueira,“不同政见运动和组织中的政治和军事派别”,《冲突解决杂志》第49期,第2期。2(2005): 218-36.19。恩德斯和桑德勒,《反恐政策的有效性》,839-40页;恩德斯和桑德勒,《恐怖主义的政治经济学》,第20页。国家恐怖主义和应对恐怖主义研究联盟(START),“全球恐怖主义数据库(GTD)”,www.start.umd.edu/gtd/(2023年2月3日访问);Edward F. Mickolus, Todd Sandler, Jean M. Murdock和Peter Flemming,《国际恐怖主义:恐怖事件的属性(ITERATE), 1968-2021》(Ponte Vedra, FL: Vinyard Software, 2022)。对于国内恐怖事件,受害者和肇事者都是袭击发生地国家的公民。跨国恐怖主义事件涉及来自一个以上国家的受害者或肇事者或两者。如果一些受害者或肇事者不是地点国的公民,那么恐怖袭击也是一个跨国事件。恩德斯和桑德勒:《反恐政策的有效性》;克里斯托弗·休伊特,《反恐政策的有效性》(兰哈姆医学博士:美国大学出版社,1984年);Michele L. Malvesti,《轰炸本·拉登:将空袭作为反恐战略的有效性》,《弗莱彻世界事务论坛》,第26期。1 (2002): 17-29;Nadav Morag,“衡量应对恐怖主义的成功:以色列的案例”,《冲突与恐怖主义研究》,第28期。4(2005): 307-20.23。Mikel Buesa, Aurelia Valiño, Joost Heijs, Thomas Baumert和Javier G. Gomez,“3·11的经济成本:衡量2004年3月11日恐怖袭击的直接经济成本”,《恐怖主义与政治暴力》19,第2期。4 (2007): 489-509;恩德斯和桑德勒,《恐怖主义的政治经济学》,288-316.24。S. Brock Blomberg, Gregory D. Hess, Athanasios Orphanides,“恐怖主义的宏观经济后果”,《货币经济学杂志》第51期。5 (2004): 1007-32;托德·桑德勒和沃尔特·恩德斯,《恐怖主义在发达国家和发展中国家的经济后果:概述》,载于《恐怖主义、经济发展和政治开放》,菲利普·基弗和诺曼·洛伊扎主编(纽约:剑桥大学出版社,2008),第17-47.25页。参见Stephen D. Collins的案例研究,“劝阻国家支持恐怖主义:打击还是制裁?”(《对利比亚采取的劝阻措施分析》,《冲突与恐怖主义研究》第27期。1 (2004): 1 - 18;休伊特,反恐政策的有效性;马尔维斯,《轰炸本·拉登》;衡量应对恐怖主义的成功> 26。Patrick T. Brandt, Justin George和Todd Sandler,“为什么不应该向恐怖分子绑架者做出让步”,《欧洲政治经济杂志》(2016),第44期:41-52;亚当·多尔尼克、基思·m·菲茨杰拉德:《与新恐怖分子谈判人质危机》(纽约:布鲁姆斯伯里学术出版社,2008);Margaret a . Wilson,“人质劫持事件中的恐怖主义行为模式”,《冲突解决杂志》,第44期。[4](2000): 403-24.27。Konstantinos Drakos和Nicholas Giannakopoulos,“反恐有效性的计量经济学分析:生命和财产损失的影响”,《公共选择》139期,第2期。1 (2009): 135-51;恩德斯和桑德勒:《反恐政策的有效性》;兰德斯,《美国劫机事件的经济研究》,第28页。这个百分比是基于ITERATE的数据得出的。带关键变量编码的最新劫持人质数据目前截止到2018.29年。 Wukki Kim, Justin George和Todd Sandler,“介绍跨国恐怖主义人质事件(TTHE)数据集,1978年至2018年”,《冲突解决杂志》第65期。2-3(2021): 619-41.30。勃兰特等人,“为什么不应该向恐怖分子绑架者做出让步”31。恩德斯和桑德勒的《恐怖主义的政治经济》,350-52.32描述了这些事件和其他更大规模的人质袭击事件。Patrick T. Brandt和Todd Sandler,“人质劫持:理解恐怖主义事件动力学”,《政策建模杂志》第31期。5 (2009): 758-78;恩德斯和桑德勒:《恐怖主义的政治经济学》,第201-3期;威尔逊,<人质劫持事件中恐怖分子行为的模型> 33。陈晓明,“与恐怖分子的谈判:服从的代价”,《南方经济》第86期。1 (2019): 305-17;Khusrav Gaibulloev和Todd Sandler,“劫持人质:恐怖分子后勤和谈判成功的决定因素”,《和平研究杂志》第46期。6 (2009): 739-56;Kim et al.,“引入跨国恐怖主义人质事件(TTHE)数据集”,34。Arin等人,“与恐怖分子谈判”;Atkinson et al.,“讨价还价框架中的恐怖主义”;勃兰特和桑德勒,《人质劫持》;亚历山大·芬克和马克·普林格尔,《绑架保险及其对绑架结果的影响》,《公共选择》第160期。3-4 (2014): 481-99;盖布洛夫和桑德勒,《人质劫持》;拉潘和桑德勒,《讨价还价还是不讨价还价》;李佳怡,“民主、公民自由与劫持人质的恐怖主义”,《和平研究杂志》第50期。2 (2013): 235-48;查琳达·桑蒂福特和托德·桑德勒,《恐怖分子劫持人质的成功:1978-2010》,《公共选择》156期。1-2(2013): 125-37.35。Kim et al.,“引入跨国恐怖主义人质事件(TTHE)数据集”,624-5.36。Avinash Dixit, Susan Skeath和David Reiley, Jr.,战略游戏,第4版(纽约:w.w. Norton & Co., 2015).37。例如,参见Atkinson等人的《讨价还价框架中的恐怖主义》;勃兰特和桑德勒,《人质劫持》;盖布洛夫和桑德勒,《人质劫持》;李,《民主、公民自由和劫持人质的恐怖主义》;桑提福尔和桑德勒,<恐怖分子成功劫持人质>,第38页。参见,例如,Kim等人,“介绍跨国恐怖分子人质事件(TTHE)数据集。”关于这种不让步政策的相关文献包括:Arin等人的《与恐怖分子谈判》;Brandt等人,“为什么不应该向恐怖绑架者让步”;勃兰特和桑德勒,《人质劫持》;拉潘和桑德勒,《讨价还价还是不讨价还价》;史蒂文·坡:《国家对跨国人质事件的反应:一个实证评估》,《国际互动》第14期。1 (1988): 27-40;Aslihan Saygili,“让步还是镇压:政权稳定如何影响对劫持人质恐怖主义的民主反应”,《冲突解决杂志》,第63期。2 (2019): 468-501;约翰·l·斯科特,“人质劫持事件中的声誉建设”,《国防与和平经济》第2期。3(1991): 209-18.40。Brandt等人,“为什么不应该向恐怖分子绑架者做出让步,”47-9.41。如上,49 - 51.42。勃兰特和桑德勒在《人质劫持》中也发现了类似的劫机和路障任务。Kim et al.,“引入跨国恐怖主义人质事件(TTHE)数据集”,44。Daniel G. Arce和Todd Sandler,“反恐:一个博弈论分析”,《冲突解决杂志》第49期,第2期。2 (2005): 183-200;Subhayu Bandyopadhyay和Todd Sandler,“先发制人和防御性反恐措施之间的相互作用:一个两阶段博弈”,《经济》第78期。311 (2011): 546-64;Navin A. Bapat,“恐怖主义运动的国际化”,《冲突管理与和平科学》,第24期。4 (2007): 265-80;伊桑·布埃诺·德·梅斯奎塔,《政治与次优反恐措施》,《国际组织》第61期。1 (2007): 9-36;Eva Cárceles-Poveda和Yair Tauman,“对跨国恐怖主义战争的战略分析”,《游戏与经济行为》,74期。1 (2011): 49-65;Harvey E. Lapan和Todd Sandler,“恐怖主义与信号”,《欧洲政治经济学杂志》第9期。3 (1993): 383-97;Per B. Overgaard,“恐怖袭击的规模作为资源的信号”,《冲突解决学报》第38期。3 (1994): 452-78;桑德勒和拉潘,《异议的计算》(The Calculus of Dissent);Sandler et al.,《跨国恐怖主义的理论分析》;Friedrich Schneider, Tilman br<e:1> ck和Daniel Meierrieks,“反恐经济学:调查”,《经济调查杂志》第29期。1(2015): 131-57.45。Efraim Benmelech, Claude Berrebi和Esteban F. Klor,“反自杀恐怖主义:来自房屋拆除的证据”,《政治杂志》,第77期。1 (2015): 27-43;Walter Enders和Paan Jindapon,“网络外部性和恐怖网络结构”,《冲突解决学报》第54期。2 (2020): 262-80;丹尼尔·雅各布森和爱德华·H。 Konstantinos Drakos和Andreas Gofas,“恐怖主义对三个地中海国家旅游业的区域影响”,《冲突解决杂志》,第47期。5 (2003): 621-41;沃尔特·恩德斯和托德·桑德勒,《跨国恐怖主义与旅游业之间的因果关系:以西班牙为例》,《恐怖主义:国际期刊》第14期。1 (1991): 49-58;Walter Enders, Todd Sandler和Gerry F. Parise,“恐怖主义对旅游业影响的计量经济学分析”,Kyklos, 45, no。4(1992): 531-54.69。恩德斯等人,“恐怖主义对旅游业影响的计量经济学分析”,70。沃尔特·恩德斯和托德·桑德勒,《西班牙和希腊的恐怖主义和外国直接投资》,Kyklos第49期,no。3(1996): 331-52.71。《恐怖主义与世界经济》,《欧洲经济评论》第52期。1 (2008): 1 - 27;Bandyopadhyay等人,《外国直接投资、援助和恐怖主义》;Walter Enders, Adolfo Sachsida和Todd Sandler,“跨国恐怖主义对美国外国直接投资的影响”,《政治研究季刊》,第59期。4(2006): 517-31.72。苏哈尤·班约帕德哈伊、托德·桑德勒、贾韦德·尤纳斯,《贸易与恐怖主义:一个分类的方法》,《和平研究杂志》第55期。5 (2018): 656-70;S. Brock Blomberg和Gregory D. Hess,“暴力对贸易征收多少税?”《经济与统计评论》第88期。4 (2006): 599-612;Daniel Mirza和Thierry Verdier,《生活是生计的替代品吗?》恐怖主义、安全与美国双边进口>,《冲突解决杂志》第58期。6 (2014): 943-75;《恐怖主义与国际贸易:实证研究》,《欧洲政治经济学》第20期。2(2004): 423-33.73。Abel Brodeur,“恐怖主义对就业和消费者情绪的影响:来自成功和失败的恐怖袭击的证据”,《美国经济杂志:应用经济学》第10期。4(2018): 246-82.74。戴云浩,Raghavendra Rau, Aris Stouraitis,谭伟强,“一种病风?”恐怖袭击与CEO薪酬,《金融经济学杂志》,第135期。2(2020): 379-98.75。孟成宰、韩承辉、金炯杰,“恐怖袭击与全要素生产率的关系”,《经济研究》,第2期,第1 - 5页。Wukki Kim和Todd Sandler,《跨国恐怖主义会刺激外国援助吗?》冲突管理与和平科学,第40期。2(2023): 187-206.77。Joseph K. Young和Michael G. Findley,《和平可以买到吗?》《援助对跨国恐怖主义影响的部门层面分析》,《公共选择》第149期。3-4(2011): 365-81.78。Rafat Mahmood和Michael Jetter,《乱世:美国无人机袭击巴基斯坦的后果》,《经济杂志》133期,第2期。2(2023): 787-81.79。Ibid.80。参见,例如,Daniel Meierrieks和Laura Renner,“伊斯兰恐怖主义与妇女地位”,《欧洲政治经济学》78,第102364(2023):1-19.81。恩德斯和桑德勒,《恐怖主义的政治经济学》,322-28.82。关于恐怖组织行动基地的选择,请参见胡斯拉夫·盖布洛夫:《恐怖组织选址决策:实证调查》,《牛津经济论文》第67期。1(2015): 21-41。论空间计量经济学在恐怖主义中的应用,见Josiah Marineau, Henry Pascoe, Alex Braithwaite, Michael G. Findley, Joseph K. Young,“跨国恐怖主义的地方地理学”,《冲突管理与和平科学》第37期。3(2020): 350-81。本文根据ITERATE的地理编码确定了影响跨国恐怖主义位置的五个地方级因素。这篇文章并没有根据群体的基地位置来研究群体的生存问题。Enders and Jindapon:“网络外部性与恐怖网络结构”;苏雪娟,“理性恐怖分子与最优网络结构”,《冲突解决》第51期。1(2007): 33-57。托德·桑德勒(todd Sandler)是德克萨斯大学达拉斯分校Vibhooti Shukla经济学名誉教授。自1983年以来,他撰写了有关恐怖主义经济研究的文章和书籍。他的文章发表在《美国经济评论》、《美国政治科学评论》、《政治分析》、《冲突解决杂志》、《和平研究杂志》、《经济行为与组织杂志》、《法律与经济学杂志》等杂志上。他曾就这个问题咨询过联合国开发计划署、美国国土安全部和其他机构。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
5.60
自引率
8.30%
发文量
87
期刊介绍: Terrorism and Political Violence advances scholarship on a broad range of issues associated with terrorism and political violence, including subjects such as: the political meaning of terrorist activity, violence by rebels and by states, the links between political violence and organized crime, protest, rebellion, revolution, the influence of social networks, and the impact on human rights. The journal draws upon many disciplines and theoretical perspectives as well as comparative approaches to provide some of the most groundbreaking work in a field that has hitherto lacked rigour. Terrorism and Political Violence features symposia and edited volumes to cover an important topic in depth. Subjects have included: terrorism and public policy; religion and violence; political parties and terrorism; technology and terrorism; and right-wing terrorism. The journal is essential reading for all academics, decision-makers, and security specialists concerned with understanding political violence.
期刊最新文献
Gendered Extremism in the Pacific on 4chan: A Mixed-methods Exploration of Australian and New Zealanders’ Concepts of Women, Gender, and Sexual Violence on /Pol/ “Today I Die like Jesus Christ”: An Analysis of Ressentiment in Perceptions, Motivations and Justifications of Violent Extremist Manifestos Using Deep Learning Neural Networks to Predict Violent vs. Nonviolent Extremist Behaviors Basic Psychological Needs and Extremism: Understanding Theories Through Meta-Analysis What Effect does Ideological Extremism have on Mass Shootings? An Assessment of Motivational Inconsistencies, Risk Profiles, and Attack Behaviors
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1