Keynesian Equilibria as Centers of Gravitation?

IF 1.2 Q3 ECONOMICS REVIEW OF POLITICAL ECONOMY Pub Date : 2023-10-17 DOI:10.1080/09538259.2023.2260321
Claudio Sardoni
{"title":"Keynesian Equilibria as Centers of Gravitation?","authors":"Claudio Sardoni","doi":"10.1080/09538259.2023.2260321","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTStarting from some of Geoff Harcourt’s contributions, this article deals with the problem of macroeconomic equilibria as centers of gravitation from a Keynesian perspective. It is argued that the Keynesian notion of short-period underemployment equilibrium (or rest state) represents a sustainable analytical notion of center of gravitation in so far as a static state is assumed. If the economy grows over time, dealing with the problem of centers of gravitation requires a long-period perspective, which, however, cannot be reduced to the use of equilibrium growth models. A more general approach to the dynamics of market economies is a better way to support Keynes’s idea that the economy tends to fluctuate around positions characterized by the unemployment of resources.KEYWORDS: Centers of gravitationshort- and long-period analysismodels of growthJEL CLASSIFICATION: E10E12O40P10 AcknowledgementsI would like to thank M. Boianovsky, B. Ingrao, F. Ruggeri for their helpful comments and suggestions. Any possible mistake is, of course, my sole responsibility. I would also like to use this opportunity to acknowledge and thank the reviewers who reviewed this article and aided in its publication.Disclosure StatementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.Notes1 Some of these papers have been re-published in Harcourt (Citation1992): ‘The legacy of Keynes: Theoretical methods and unfinished businesses’ (Citation1987); ‘Marshall, Sraffa and Keynes: Incompatible bedfellows?’ (Citation1981); ‘Marshall’s Principles as seen at Cambridge through the eyes of Gerald Shove, Dennis Robertson and Joan Robinson’ (Citation1991). This article focuses on the first two.2 Harcourt (Citation1992 [Citation1981], pp. 254–258) devotes considerable attention to Sraffa, his critique of Marshall, and the way in which Sraffa’s normal values can be interpreted. Harcourt (Citation2018) returns to the problem of centers of gravitation by concentrating on Sraffa and different interpretations of his theory.3 Keynes’s ‘indecisiveness’ resides in the fact that ‘he had all but despaired of finding a determinate unit of time into which all various interrelated processes and decisions he was analysing could be fitted so he decided never to push any particular piece of analysis very far past its starting point, preferring to get only the central message across’ (Harcourt Citation1992 [Citation1981], pp. 259–260).4 For Keynes (Citation1973 [Citation1936], p. 249), ‘it is an outstanding characteristic of the economic system in which we live that, whilst it is subject to severe fluctuations in respect of output and employment, it is not violently unstable. Indeed, it seems capable of remaining in a chronic condition of sub-normal activity for a considerable period without any marked tendency either towards recovery or towards complete collapse.’5 ‘Keynes … adopted Marshall’s methods for his own purposes, the determination of output and employment as a whole, the theory of effective demand, once he had convinced himself that Say’s law did not hold so that a general glut was a theoretical possibility, just as it was obviously a practical possibility in the world around him at the time’ (Harcourt Citation1992 [Citation1987], p. 240).6 In the book’s Acknowledgements, Kahn devotes several pages to clarifying the notion of the short period as distinct from the long period.7 Among Post Keynesians and Kaleckians, several reject the idea of a normal and constant degree of capacity utilization. For a summary of the debate on this issue, see, e.g., Lavoie (Citation2014, pp. 387-410) and also Patriarca and Sardoni (Citation2014). The debate on capacity utilization is mainly concerned with the long period. Here, without entering into this debate, we retain the hypothesis of a constant u∗, which we regard as a safe assumption in a short-period framework.8 If b=1, the adjustment is completed in one period.9 Wrong short-term expectations also cause a deviation in the degree of capacity utilization from u∗ and it would be reasonable to think that u≠u∗ should affect investment; here, however, this possibility is excluded by the restrictive hypothesis that investment remains unvaried.10 This would be the logic to follow for the analysis of cases in which there is an initial worsening of expectations.11 For simplicity, we assume that all equilibrium levels of the output are below the full employment level, say Yfe∗.12 Referring to Keynesian short-period analysis, Domar (Citation1957 [Citation1946], p. 73) argues: Because investment in the Keynesian system is merely an instrument for generating income, the system does not take into account the extremely essential, elementary, and well-known fact that investment also increases productive capacity. This dual character of the investment process makes the approach to the equilibrium rate of growth from the investment (capital) point of view more promising: if investment both increases productive capacity and generates income, it provides us with both sides of the equation the solution of which may yield the required rate of growth. 13 Keynesian, post-Keynesian, and Kaleckian economists have been particularly interested in the problem of growth path stability; for a review of this literature, see, e.g., Lavoie (Citation2014, pp. 377–410). For a discussion of the stability of neo-classical growth models, see, e.g., Aghion and Howitt (Citation2009, pp. 21–46).14 As Asimakopulos (Citation1991, p. 145) observes, Keynes had no problem conceiving of a growth path like those determined by equilibrium growth models, but he contested the capacity of such models to be a realistic depiction of modern capitalist economies.15 The normative character of Domar’s model of growth is revealed by the fact that it does not contain any investment function describing firms’ behavior. Also, Harrod’s growth model — which is often associated with Domar’s, though erroneously — can be interpreted in normative terms: ‘the “natural” growth rate is determined by population increase and technological progress, and specifies what saving ratio is required in consequence of that. It is up to the authorities to ensure that this amount of saving is made’ (Citation1973, p. 28). On the models of Domar and Harrod and their normative nature, see also Hein (Citation2014, pp. 23–49).16 Kalecki was another economist whose work was highly appreciated by Harcourt (see, e.g., Harcourt Citation2006).17 See Hein (Citation2014) and Lavoie (Citation2014, pp. 347–455) for surveys of this literature.18 Kalecki (Citation1971) contains a collection of his works on cycles and growth.19 ‘The contemporary theory of growth of capitalist economies tends to consider this problem in terms of a moving equilibrium, which is frequently not checked for stability’ (Kalecki Citation1971 [Citation1968], p. 165).20 They include the autonomous component of capitalists’ consumption, technical change, coefficients of the equation of investment decisions, profits and their ratio to income.21 Kalecki thought that full employment cannot be a stable equilibrium solution for capitalist economies. Social and political factors prevent the economy from maintaining full employment for a long time (see Kalecki, M. Citation1971 [1943]).22 Hicks (Citation1982 [Citation1976]) also strongly argued in favor of the abandonment of the equilibrium method and the adoption of a notion of irreversible historical time.23 On Harcourt’s views of Joan Robinson’s economics, see, e.g., Harcourt (Citation1995), Harcourt (Citation2001), and Harcourt and Kerr (Citation2009).24 Harcourt and Riach (Citation1997) edited two volumes containing the contributions of many economists who have speculated on how Keynes would have written a hypothetical second edition of The General Theory to cope with the ‘unfinished business’ of the first.","PeriodicalId":46174,"journal":{"name":"REVIEW OF POLITICAL ECONOMY","volume":"11 6 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":1.2000,"publicationDate":"2023-10-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"REVIEW OF POLITICAL ECONOMY","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/09538259.2023.2260321","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q3","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

ABSTRACTStarting from some of Geoff Harcourt’s contributions, this article deals with the problem of macroeconomic equilibria as centers of gravitation from a Keynesian perspective. It is argued that the Keynesian notion of short-period underemployment equilibrium (or rest state) represents a sustainable analytical notion of center of gravitation in so far as a static state is assumed. If the economy grows over time, dealing with the problem of centers of gravitation requires a long-period perspective, which, however, cannot be reduced to the use of equilibrium growth models. A more general approach to the dynamics of market economies is a better way to support Keynes’s idea that the economy tends to fluctuate around positions characterized by the unemployment of resources.KEYWORDS: Centers of gravitationshort- and long-period analysismodels of growthJEL CLASSIFICATION: E10E12O40P10 AcknowledgementsI would like to thank M. Boianovsky, B. Ingrao, F. Ruggeri for their helpful comments and suggestions. Any possible mistake is, of course, my sole responsibility. I would also like to use this opportunity to acknowledge and thank the reviewers who reviewed this article and aided in its publication.Disclosure StatementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.Notes1 Some of these papers have been re-published in Harcourt (Citation1992): ‘The legacy of Keynes: Theoretical methods and unfinished businesses’ (Citation1987); ‘Marshall, Sraffa and Keynes: Incompatible bedfellows?’ (Citation1981); ‘Marshall’s Principles as seen at Cambridge through the eyes of Gerald Shove, Dennis Robertson and Joan Robinson’ (Citation1991). This article focuses on the first two.2 Harcourt (Citation1992 [Citation1981], pp. 254–258) devotes considerable attention to Sraffa, his critique of Marshall, and the way in which Sraffa’s normal values can be interpreted. Harcourt (Citation2018) returns to the problem of centers of gravitation by concentrating on Sraffa and different interpretations of his theory.3 Keynes’s ‘indecisiveness’ resides in the fact that ‘he had all but despaired of finding a determinate unit of time into which all various interrelated processes and decisions he was analysing could be fitted so he decided never to push any particular piece of analysis very far past its starting point, preferring to get only the central message across’ (Harcourt Citation1992 [Citation1981], pp. 259–260).4 For Keynes (Citation1973 [Citation1936], p. 249), ‘it is an outstanding characteristic of the economic system in which we live that, whilst it is subject to severe fluctuations in respect of output and employment, it is not violently unstable. Indeed, it seems capable of remaining in a chronic condition of sub-normal activity for a considerable period without any marked tendency either towards recovery or towards complete collapse.’5 ‘Keynes … adopted Marshall’s methods for his own purposes, the determination of output and employment as a whole, the theory of effective demand, once he had convinced himself that Say’s law did not hold so that a general glut was a theoretical possibility, just as it was obviously a practical possibility in the world around him at the time’ (Harcourt Citation1992 [Citation1987], p. 240).6 In the book’s Acknowledgements, Kahn devotes several pages to clarifying the notion of the short period as distinct from the long period.7 Among Post Keynesians and Kaleckians, several reject the idea of a normal and constant degree of capacity utilization. For a summary of the debate on this issue, see, e.g., Lavoie (Citation2014, pp. 387-410) and also Patriarca and Sardoni (Citation2014). The debate on capacity utilization is mainly concerned with the long period. Here, without entering into this debate, we retain the hypothesis of a constant u∗, which we regard as a safe assumption in a short-period framework.8 If b=1, the adjustment is completed in one period.9 Wrong short-term expectations also cause a deviation in the degree of capacity utilization from u∗ and it would be reasonable to think that u≠u∗ should affect investment; here, however, this possibility is excluded by the restrictive hypothesis that investment remains unvaried.10 This would be the logic to follow for the analysis of cases in which there is an initial worsening of expectations.11 For simplicity, we assume that all equilibrium levels of the output are below the full employment level, say Yfe∗.12 Referring to Keynesian short-period analysis, Domar (Citation1957 [Citation1946], p. 73) argues: Because investment in the Keynesian system is merely an instrument for generating income, the system does not take into account the extremely essential, elementary, and well-known fact that investment also increases productive capacity. This dual character of the investment process makes the approach to the equilibrium rate of growth from the investment (capital) point of view more promising: if investment both increases productive capacity and generates income, it provides us with both sides of the equation the solution of which may yield the required rate of growth. 13 Keynesian, post-Keynesian, and Kaleckian economists have been particularly interested in the problem of growth path stability; for a review of this literature, see, e.g., Lavoie (Citation2014, pp. 377–410). For a discussion of the stability of neo-classical growth models, see, e.g., Aghion and Howitt (Citation2009, pp. 21–46).14 As Asimakopulos (Citation1991, p. 145) observes, Keynes had no problem conceiving of a growth path like those determined by equilibrium growth models, but he contested the capacity of such models to be a realistic depiction of modern capitalist economies.15 The normative character of Domar’s model of growth is revealed by the fact that it does not contain any investment function describing firms’ behavior. Also, Harrod’s growth model — which is often associated with Domar’s, though erroneously — can be interpreted in normative terms: ‘the “natural” growth rate is determined by population increase and technological progress, and specifies what saving ratio is required in consequence of that. It is up to the authorities to ensure that this amount of saving is made’ (Citation1973, p. 28). On the models of Domar and Harrod and their normative nature, see also Hein (Citation2014, pp. 23–49).16 Kalecki was another economist whose work was highly appreciated by Harcourt (see, e.g., Harcourt Citation2006).17 See Hein (Citation2014) and Lavoie (Citation2014, pp. 347–455) for surveys of this literature.18 Kalecki (Citation1971) contains a collection of his works on cycles and growth.19 ‘The contemporary theory of growth of capitalist economies tends to consider this problem in terms of a moving equilibrium, which is frequently not checked for stability’ (Kalecki Citation1971 [Citation1968], p. 165).20 They include the autonomous component of capitalists’ consumption, technical change, coefficients of the equation of investment decisions, profits and their ratio to income.21 Kalecki thought that full employment cannot be a stable equilibrium solution for capitalist economies. Social and political factors prevent the economy from maintaining full employment for a long time (see Kalecki, M. Citation1971 [1943]).22 Hicks (Citation1982 [Citation1976]) also strongly argued in favor of the abandonment of the equilibrium method and the adoption of a notion of irreversible historical time.23 On Harcourt’s views of Joan Robinson’s economics, see, e.g., Harcourt (Citation1995), Harcourt (Citation2001), and Harcourt and Kerr (Citation2009).24 Harcourt and Riach (Citation1997) edited two volumes containing the contributions of many economists who have speculated on how Keynes would have written a hypothetical second edition of The General Theory to cope with the ‘unfinished business’ of the first.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
凯恩斯均衡是重心吗?
摘要本文从杰夫·哈考特的一些贡献出发,从凯恩斯主义的角度探讨宏观经济均衡作为重心的问题。有人认为,凯恩斯主义关于短期就业不足均衡(或休息状态)的概念代表了一种可持续的分析重心概念,只要假设静止状态。如果经济随着时间的推移而增长,处理重心问题需要一个长期的视角,然而,这不能简化为使用均衡增长模型。对于市场经济的动态,一个更一般的方法是更好地支持凯恩斯的观点,即经济倾向于围绕以资源失业为特征的位置波动。关键词:重心;生长的短周期和长周期分析模型;jel分类:E10E12O40P10感谢M. Boianovsky、B. Ingrao、F. Ruggeri的宝贵意见和建议。当然,任何可能的错误都是我的责任。我还想借此机会感谢审阅本文并协助其发表的审稿人。披露声明作者未报告潜在的利益冲突。注1其中一些论文已在Harcourt (Citation1992)上重新发表:“凯恩斯的遗产:理论方法和未完成的事业”(Citation1987);马歇尔、斯拉法和凯恩斯:不相容的同床共枕?”(Citation1981);“杰拉尔德·普塞、丹尼斯·罗伯逊和琼·罗宾逊眼中的剑桥马歇尔原则”(Citation1991)。本文的重点是前两个Harcourt (Citation1992 [Citation1981], pp. 254-258)对斯拉法、他对马歇尔的批判以及斯拉法的正常价值观的解释方式给予了相当大的关注。Harcourt (Citation2018)通过关注斯拉法和对他的理论的不同解释,回到了引力中心的问题凯恩斯的“犹豫不决”存在于这样一个事实,“他几乎绝望地找到一个确定的时间单位,在这个时间单位里,他所分析的所有各种相互关联的过程和决定都可以被适应,所以他决定永远不要把任何特定的分析推到离起点太远的地方,而宁愿只得到中心信息”(Harcourt Citation1992 [Citation1981], pp. 259-260)对于凯恩斯(Citation1973 [Citation1936],第249页)来说,“这是我们所生活的经济体系的一个突出特征,尽管它受制于产出和就业方面的严重波动,但它并不是剧烈不稳定的。”事实上,它似乎能够在相当长的一段时间内保持一种低于正常活动的慢性状态,而没有任何明显的恢复或完全崩溃的趋势。“凯恩斯……为了自己的目的采用了马歇尔的方法,即产出和就业作为一个整体的决定,有效需求理论,一旦他确信萨伊定律不成立,那么普遍过剩是一种理论可能性,就像当时他周围的世界显然是一种实践可能性一样”(Harcourt Citation1992 [Citation1987], p. 240)在这本书的致谢中,卡恩花了几页来澄清短期与长期不同的概念在后凯恩斯主义者和卡莱金主义者中,有几个人反对正常和恒定程度的产能利用率。关于这个问题的辩论的总结,请参见,例如,Lavoie (Citation2014, pp. 387-410)和Patriarca和Sardoni (Citation2014)。关于产能利用的争论主要是关于长期的。在这里,我们保留一个常数u *的假设,我们认为它在短周期框架内是一个安全的假设如果b=1,调整在一个周期内完成错误的短期预期也会导致产能利用程度偏离u *,因此有理由认为u≠u *会影响投资;然而,在这里,投资保持不变的限制性假设排除了这种可能性这将是在分析最初出现预期恶化的情况时应遵循的逻辑为简单起见,我们假设产出的所有均衡水平都低于充分就业水平,设为Yfe * .12引用凯恩斯主义的短期分析,Domar (Citation1957 [Citation1946],第73页)认为:因为在凯恩斯主义体系中,投资仅仅是一种创造收入的工具,该体系没有考虑到一个极其重要、基本和众所周知的事实,即投资也能提高生产能力。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
2.60
自引率
20.00%
发文量
0
期刊介绍: The Review of Political Economy is a peer-reviewed journal welcoming constructive and critical contributions in all areas of political economy, including the Austrian, Behavioral Economics, Feminist Economics, Institutionalist, Marxian, Post Keynesian, and Sraffian traditions. The Review publishes both theoretical and empirical research, and is also open to submissions in methodology, economic history and the history of economic thought that cast light on issues of contemporary relevance in political economy. Comments on articles published in the Review are encouraged.
期刊最新文献
The Currency of Politics: The Political Theory of Money from Aristotle to Keynes The Monetary Theory of Production and the Supermultiplier: What Determines Savings? Revisiting the Pasinetti Index: Understanding Its Cyclical and Long-Term Features and Its Important Implications for Macroeconomic Policy Blurring Boundaries: An Analysis of the Digital Platforms-Military Nexus Public Investment as a Source of Capacity-Creating Autonomous Demand: Implications for Growth and Stability
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1