Perspectives on trade and structural transformation

IF 1.4 Q3 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES Oxford Development Studies Pub Date : 2023-11-15 DOI:10.1080/13600818.2023.2279665
George Alessandria, Robert Johnson, Kei-Mu Yi
{"title":"Perspectives on trade and structural transformation","authors":"George Alessandria, Robert Johnson, Kei-Mu Yi","doi":"10.1080/13600818.2023.2279665","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTThis paper surveys macroeconomic and microeconomic perspectives on the role of international trade in structural transformation. We start by describing canonical frameworks that have been used to quantify how trade influences sectoral shares of employment and value added. We then pivot to survey micro-empirical evidence on the impact of changes in trade on the allocation of labor across sectors and productivity at the firm level. In this, we put special emphasis on the role of participation in global value chains and inward foreign direct investment in mediating these effects. Next, we evaluate evidence on the barriers to trade faced by low-income countries, with special attention to recent work that measures these costs taking firm dynamics into account. We conclude by discussing how these micro-perspectives can be integrated into macro models to advance our understanding of structural change.KEYWORDS: Global value chainsForeign direct investmentFirm-level costs of tradeMicro-evidence and macro modelsJEL CLASSIFICATION: F1F23F43F62 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1. Several papers have developed models to explain them. One of these papers includes international trade; see Sposi et al. (Citation2021).2. That said, measurement of GVCs has typically employed a more narrow definition: imported inputs are used in production and some of the resulting output is exported, i.e. some stages of production cross multiple national borders.3. We acknowledge that our survey here cannot cover the full range of perspectives; for example, we do not directly address industrial policy, so refer the reader to Chang (Citation2003) and Oqubay et al. (Citation2020) for complementary discussion.4. To clarify the scope of our discussion, we focus on the allocation of factors across sectors. Thus, we do not engage research on the allocation of factors across firms within a sector, which plays an important role in models of trade with heterogeneous firms. To the extent that this within sector reallocation alters sectoral productivity, it may be an additional mechanism through which trade influences structural change.5. A separate set of questions are related to the welfare effects of worker displacements due to trade. One might be concerned that displacements are particularly costly when workers do not have access to social insurance programs, as in most low-income countries. We are not aware of work that addresses these concerns explicitly, though they would be important for understanding the political economy of trade reforms.6. Dix-Carneiro et al. (Citation2021) shows that incorporating the informal sector into models is important quantitatively, and also qualitatively for wage inequality, productivity, and welfare.7. Our emphasis here is tailored to highlight particular issues pertaining to participation in global value chains and trade in low-income countries. See De Loecker and Goldberg (Citation2014) for a more comprehensive review of the literature on the impact of trade on firm performance.8. In addition to expanding import variety, imports (particularly from high income countries) are likely to be higher quality than domestic alternatives. Halpern et al. (Citation2015) links import variety and quality to firm productivity in Hungary.9. Looking forward to discussion below regarding inventories and trade costs, we also raise a point about measuring productivity gains here. Khan and Khederlarian (Citation2020) argues that omission of inventory holding costs in computing revenue based productivity leads to overestimation of the productivity gains of import liberalization. This is related to a broader issue in this literature: productivity changes hinge on accurate measurement of firm-level input price indexes (equivalently, input quantity). Input price and quantity measurement is challenging in most micro-data sets, and it is particularly difficult when the mix of inputs used in production changes rapidly due to liberalization itself. As such, many studies include changes in input prices in the firm’s measured productivity residual.10. Dai et al. (Citation2016) show that Chinese firms in the processing trade sector are less productive than ordinary exporters. Whether this pattern holds elsewhere is unknown; if it does, it suggests that countries are effectively subsidizing unproductive firms via their processing trade regimes. If these subsidies simply reallocate activity within the manufacturing sector from more productive to less productive firms, then they would seem unwise. If instead they serve to reallocate labor from lower productivity outside sectors, then they may raise economy-wide productivity overall, though not as much as subsidies that would have directed workers to the more productive non-processing firms. Work that investigates these alternatives, both in China and non-Chinese contexts, would be valuable.11. Newman et al. (Citation2015) uses a unique firm survey from Vietnam to unpack the role of direct sourcing relationships and technology transfers between firms in explaining the role of aggregated sector-to-sector linkages (as studied by Javorcik, Citation2004) in mediating spillovers.12. In the specific Bangladeshi context, there is potential for rich data sources could be used in research. For example, Grossi et al. (Citation2023) exploits a rich data set on transactions between domestic garments firms and foreign buyers, together with information about input sourcing by domestic firms.13. Low-income economies have relatively high domestic trade costs and import barriers. See high-quality surveys such as the World Bank’s Doing Business Survey or Logistic Performance Index, for example.14. For instance, Baier and Bergstrand (Citation2007) and Baier et al. (Citation2014) show that preferential free trade agreements only gradually increase bilateral trade flows. Jung (Citation2012) estimates that less than half of the trade expansions from a free trade agreement occurs within the first 10 years. Likewise, the sharp movements in trade over the cycle do not reflect large changes in policy or trade barriers, but rather dynamic aspects of trade that are outside the static gravity model.15. Mix (forthcoming) develops a multi-country model with transition dynamics to study how the dynamics effects of trade reforms are shaped by financial openness, geography, country size, and development.16. See the recent survey by Alessandria et al. (Citation2021).17. These types of models are also needed to make sense of the aggregate trade data we discussed earlier.18. Though we do not review it here, the empirical macro-literature on trade and economic growth is almost entirely disconnected from this micro-evidence. See Irwin (Citation2019) for a recent survey.19. See Martin and Warr (Citation1993) and Friedberg (Citation2001) for evidence on Rybczynski effects. Sposi et al. (Citation2021b) provides a model with such feedback effects involving capital accumulation, but it does not have structural change.20. As discussed above, McCaig and Pavcnik (Citation2018) is one of the few papers that has addressed the role of trade in reallocation across formal and informal firms.21. Pahl and Timmer (Citation2020) presents related evidence on the positive correlation between GVC participation and manufacturing productivity growth for a wide set of countries.Additional informationFundingThe work was supported by the Department for International Development (DFID) [STEG LOA PP10 Alessandria Johnson Yi].","PeriodicalId":51612,"journal":{"name":"Oxford Development Studies","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.4000,"publicationDate":"2023-11-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Oxford Development Studies","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/13600818.2023.2279665","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q3","JCRName":"DEVELOPMENT STUDIES","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

ABSTRACTThis paper surveys macroeconomic and microeconomic perspectives on the role of international trade in structural transformation. We start by describing canonical frameworks that have been used to quantify how trade influences sectoral shares of employment and value added. We then pivot to survey micro-empirical evidence on the impact of changes in trade on the allocation of labor across sectors and productivity at the firm level. In this, we put special emphasis on the role of participation in global value chains and inward foreign direct investment in mediating these effects. Next, we evaluate evidence on the barriers to trade faced by low-income countries, with special attention to recent work that measures these costs taking firm dynamics into account. We conclude by discussing how these micro-perspectives can be integrated into macro models to advance our understanding of structural change.KEYWORDS: Global value chainsForeign direct investmentFirm-level costs of tradeMicro-evidence and macro modelsJEL CLASSIFICATION: F1F23F43F62 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1. Several papers have developed models to explain them. One of these papers includes international trade; see Sposi et al. (Citation2021).2. That said, measurement of GVCs has typically employed a more narrow definition: imported inputs are used in production and some of the resulting output is exported, i.e. some stages of production cross multiple national borders.3. We acknowledge that our survey here cannot cover the full range of perspectives; for example, we do not directly address industrial policy, so refer the reader to Chang (Citation2003) and Oqubay et al. (Citation2020) for complementary discussion.4. To clarify the scope of our discussion, we focus on the allocation of factors across sectors. Thus, we do not engage research on the allocation of factors across firms within a sector, which plays an important role in models of trade with heterogeneous firms. To the extent that this within sector reallocation alters sectoral productivity, it may be an additional mechanism through which trade influences structural change.5. A separate set of questions are related to the welfare effects of worker displacements due to trade. One might be concerned that displacements are particularly costly when workers do not have access to social insurance programs, as in most low-income countries. We are not aware of work that addresses these concerns explicitly, though they would be important for understanding the political economy of trade reforms.6. Dix-Carneiro et al. (Citation2021) shows that incorporating the informal sector into models is important quantitatively, and also qualitatively for wage inequality, productivity, and welfare.7. Our emphasis here is tailored to highlight particular issues pertaining to participation in global value chains and trade in low-income countries. See De Loecker and Goldberg (Citation2014) for a more comprehensive review of the literature on the impact of trade on firm performance.8. In addition to expanding import variety, imports (particularly from high income countries) are likely to be higher quality than domestic alternatives. Halpern et al. (Citation2015) links import variety and quality to firm productivity in Hungary.9. Looking forward to discussion below regarding inventories and trade costs, we also raise a point about measuring productivity gains here. Khan and Khederlarian (Citation2020) argues that omission of inventory holding costs in computing revenue based productivity leads to overestimation of the productivity gains of import liberalization. This is related to a broader issue in this literature: productivity changes hinge on accurate measurement of firm-level input price indexes (equivalently, input quantity). Input price and quantity measurement is challenging in most micro-data sets, and it is particularly difficult when the mix of inputs used in production changes rapidly due to liberalization itself. As such, many studies include changes in input prices in the firm’s measured productivity residual.10. Dai et al. (Citation2016) show that Chinese firms in the processing trade sector are less productive than ordinary exporters. Whether this pattern holds elsewhere is unknown; if it does, it suggests that countries are effectively subsidizing unproductive firms via their processing trade regimes. If these subsidies simply reallocate activity within the manufacturing sector from more productive to less productive firms, then they would seem unwise. If instead they serve to reallocate labor from lower productivity outside sectors, then they may raise economy-wide productivity overall, though not as much as subsidies that would have directed workers to the more productive non-processing firms. Work that investigates these alternatives, both in China and non-Chinese contexts, would be valuable.11. Newman et al. (Citation2015) uses a unique firm survey from Vietnam to unpack the role of direct sourcing relationships and technology transfers between firms in explaining the role of aggregated sector-to-sector linkages (as studied by Javorcik, Citation2004) in mediating spillovers.12. In the specific Bangladeshi context, there is potential for rich data sources could be used in research. For example, Grossi et al. (Citation2023) exploits a rich data set on transactions between domestic garments firms and foreign buyers, together with information about input sourcing by domestic firms.13. Low-income economies have relatively high domestic trade costs and import barriers. See high-quality surveys such as the World Bank’s Doing Business Survey or Logistic Performance Index, for example.14. For instance, Baier and Bergstrand (Citation2007) and Baier et al. (Citation2014) show that preferential free trade agreements only gradually increase bilateral trade flows. Jung (Citation2012) estimates that less than half of the trade expansions from a free trade agreement occurs within the first 10 years. Likewise, the sharp movements in trade over the cycle do not reflect large changes in policy or trade barriers, but rather dynamic aspects of trade that are outside the static gravity model.15. Mix (forthcoming) develops a multi-country model with transition dynamics to study how the dynamics effects of trade reforms are shaped by financial openness, geography, country size, and development.16. See the recent survey by Alessandria et al. (Citation2021).17. These types of models are also needed to make sense of the aggregate trade data we discussed earlier.18. Though we do not review it here, the empirical macro-literature on trade and economic growth is almost entirely disconnected from this micro-evidence. See Irwin (Citation2019) for a recent survey.19. See Martin and Warr (Citation1993) and Friedberg (Citation2001) for evidence on Rybczynski effects. Sposi et al. (Citation2021b) provides a model with such feedback effects involving capital accumulation, but it does not have structural change.20. As discussed above, McCaig and Pavcnik (Citation2018) is one of the few papers that has addressed the role of trade in reallocation across formal and informal firms.21. Pahl and Timmer (Citation2020) presents related evidence on the positive correlation between GVC participation and manufacturing productivity growth for a wide set of countries.Additional informationFundingThe work was supported by the Department for International Development (DFID) [STEG LOA PP10 Alessandria Johnson Yi].
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
贸易与结构转型的视角
(Citation2015)利用一项来自越南的独特企业调查,揭示了企业之间的直接采购关系和技术转移在解释部门间总联系(如Javorcik, Citation2004所研究的)在中介溢出效应中的作用。在孟加拉国的具体情况下,有可能在研究中使用丰富的数据来源。例如,Grossi等人(Citation2023)利用了国内服装公司与外国买家之间交易的丰富数据集,以及国内公司投入采购的信息。低收入经济体的国内贸易成本和进口壁垒相对较高。参见高质量的调查,例如世界银行的《营商环境调查》或《物流绩效指数》。例如,Baier和Bergstrand (Citation2007)以及Baier et al. (Citation2014)表明,优惠自由贸易协定只是逐渐增加双边贸易流量。Jung (Citation2012)估计,自由贸易协定带来的贸易扩张中,不到一半发生在前10年内。同样,周期内贸易的急剧变动并不反映政策或贸易壁垒的重大变化,而是反映静态重力模型之外的贸易动态方面。Mix(即将出版)开发了一个具有转型动态的多国模型,以研究贸易改革的动态效应如何受到金融开放、地理、国家规模和发展的影响。参见Alessandria等人最近的调查(Citation2021)。这些类型的模型也需要理解我们前面讨论过的贸易数据总量。尽管我们不在这里回顾,但关于贸易和经济增长的实证宏观文献几乎完全与这些微观证据脱节。参见Irwin (Citation2019)最近的一项调查。参见Martin和Warr (Citation1993)和Friedberg (Citation2001)关于Rybczynski效应的证据。Sposi等人(Citation2021b)提供了一个涉及资本积累的反馈效应模型,但不存在结构性变化。如上所述,McCaig和Pavcnik (Citation2018)是少数几篇研究贸易在正式和非正式企业之间再配置中的作用的论文之一。Pahl和Timmer (Citation2020)为许多国家的全球价值链参与与制造业生产率增长之间的正相关提供了相关证据。这项工作得到了国际发展部(DFID)的支持[STEG LOA PP10 Alessandria Johnson Yi]。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
Oxford Development Studies
Oxford Development Studies DEVELOPMENT STUDIES-
CiteScore
2.70
自引率
0.00%
发文量
20
期刊介绍: Oxford Development Studies is a multidisciplinary academic journal aimed at the student, research and policy-making community, which provides a forum for rigorous and critical analysis of conventional theories and policy issues in all aspects of development, and aims to contribute to new approaches. It covers a number of disciplines related to development, including economics, history, politics, anthropology and sociology, and will publish quantitative papers as well as surveys of literature.
期刊最新文献
Social equity and care for the earth: tensions and synergies in Latin America Microfinance trials on trial Are wars detrimental to the environment? Evidence from air pollution and land use Non-contributory social protection for adolescents in low- and middle-income countries: a review of government programmes and impacts Process evaluation of a disability-inclusive employment programme: examining the design and implementation of STAR+
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1