Comment

IF 7.5 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Nber Macroeconomics Annual Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI:10.1086/707183
M. Rognlie
{"title":"Comment","authors":"M. Rognlie","doi":"10.1086/707183","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Recently, I had a dream where I was trying to explain supply and demand to an audience of intransigent economists.How could I say that demand curves sloped downward, they asked, when for so many goods, a simple plot of quantity demanded against price showed the opposite? How could these curves be useful concepts when, even by the most generous account, their parameters shifted from year to year? I knew the answers. The incorrect slope of demand was no surprise; a plot of quantities against prices would reveal the demand curve only if the variation was caused by supply shocks. And yes, supply and demand didmove around from year to year, but this did not invalidate the concepts. If I am selling oil, I can predict that a sudden decline in supply (embargo) will increase the price, I can predict that a new source of supply (fracking) will decrease the price, and I can predict that a decline in demand (fuel efficiency) will decrease the price. All of this is useful information. The dream audience was unmoved. But upon waking up, I was relieved to find myself in a world where economists are not so silly. We understand that supply and demand is a useful framework, even if there is an identification problem and even if there is no consensus on the parameters for a particular market. In fact, we persist even in the face of more profound theoretical complications, like imperfect competition or increasing returns. Then I started reading commentary on the Phillips curve and economists started seeming awfully silly again. Somehow, a weak reducedform relationship in the aggregate data has led many people to deny the Phillips curve as a structural relationship. In the face of this criticism, McLeay and Tenreyro’s paper is a vitally important rejoinder.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"34 1","pages":"267 - 279"},"PeriodicalIF":7.5000,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/707183","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1086/707183","RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

Recently, I had a dream where I was trying to explain supply and demand to an audience of intransigent economists.How could I say that demand curves sloped downward, they asked, when for so many goods, a simple plot of quantity demanded against price showed the opposite? How could these curves be useful concepts when, even by the most generous account, their parameters shifted from year to year? I knew the answers. The incorrect slope of demand was no surprise; a plot of quantities against prices would reveal the demand curve only if the variation was caused by supply shocks. And yes, supply and demand didmove around from year to year, but this did not invalidate the concepts. If I am selling oil, I can predict that a sudden decline in supply (embargo) will increase the price, I can predict that a new source of supply (fracking) will decrease the price, and I can predict that a decline in demand (fuel efficiency) will decrease the price. All of this is useful information. The dream audience was unmoved. But upon waking up, I was relieved to find myself in a world where economists are not so silly. We understand that supply and demand is a useful framework, even if there is an identification problem and even if there is no consensus on the parameters for a particular market. In fact, we persist even in the face of more profound theoretical complications, like imperfect competition or increasing returns. Then I started reading commentary on the Phillips curve and economists started seeming awfully silly again. Somehow, a weak reducedform relationship in the aggregate data has led many people to deny the Phillips curve as a structural relationship. In the face of this criticism, McLeay and Tenreyro’s paper is a vitally important rejoinder.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
评论
最近,我做了一个梦,试图向一群顽固的经济学家解释供求关系。他们问道,当这么多商品的需求量与价格的简单关系图显示出相反的情况时,我怎么能说需求曲线向下倾斜呢?即使是最慷慨的解释,当这些曲线的参数逐年变化时,它们怎么会是有用的概念?我知道答案。需求的不正确斜率并不奇怪;只有当需求曲线的变化是由供应冲击引起时,数量与价格的关系图才能揭示需求曲线。是的,供应和需求确实逐年变化,但这并没有使这些概念失效。如果我在卖石油,我可以预测供应的突然下降(禁运)会使价格上涨,我可以预见新的供应来源(水力压裂)会使油价下跌,我可以预言需求的下降(燃油效率)会使物价下跌。所有这些都是有用的信息。梦中的观众不为所动。但醒来后,我发现自己身处一个经济学家并不那么愚蠢的世界,这让我松了一口气。我们知道,即使存在识别问题,即使对特定市场的参数没有达成共识,供需也是一个有用的框架。事实上,即使面对更深刻的理论复杂性,比如不完全竞争或不断增加的回报,我们也会坚持下去。然后我开始阅读关于菲利普斯曲线的评论,经济学家们又开始显得非常愚蠢。不知何故,聚合数据中的弱归约形式关系导致许多人否认菲利普斯曲线是一种结构关系。面对这种批评,McLeay和Tenreyro的论文是至关重要的反驳。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
5.10
自引率
0.00%
发文量
23
期刊介绍: The Nber Macroeconomics Annual provides a forum for important debates in contemporary macroeconomics and major developments in the theory of macroeconomic analysis and policy that include leading economists from a variety of fields.
期刊最新文献
Front Matter Comment Comment Comment Comment
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1