Too Many Things to Do: How to Deal with the Dysfunctions of Multiple-Goal Agencies

IF 0.7 4区 社会学 Q4 ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES Harvard Environmental Law Review Pub Date : 2009-04-10 DOI:10.2139/SSRN.1090313
Eric Biber
{"title":"Too Many Things to Do: How to Deal with the Dysfunctions of Multiple-Goal Agencies","authors":"Eric Biber","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1090313","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"All federal agencies must cope with the challenges of trying to achieve success on the multiple goals laid out for them by Congress, the President, or the public at large. Recent economics and political science literature provides a theoretical framework that helps explain why agencies might succeed in achieving some goals and fail in achieving others: Agencies will systematically underperform on goals that are hard to measure and that conflict with the achievement of other, more measurable goals. While agencies in theory might be able to improve their ability to measure performance through technological and organizational innovation, in many cases agency missions, historical inertia, and the professional orientation of agency staff will interfere with innovation. Principals (such as Congress) have various options to address this problem. Some options focus on changing the agency itself: (1) having the principal take back decision-making authority from the agency; (2) splitting agencies into components that pursue different goals; or (3) mandating that the agency innovate in developing information about undervalued goals. All of these intra-agency efforts have their limitations: Principals only have so much time and energy to make decisions themselves; splitting agencies is often not feasible; and agencies may be resistant to external cultural change. Another range of options involves having another agency monitor the decision-making agency to ensure minimal compliance with performance on one or more goals. This could include having one agency comment on the decision-making agency's performance on an undervalued goal (the agency as lobbyist model) or could extend to having another agency make legally binding determinations about whether the decision-making agency has met minimum standards for that undervalued goal (the agency as regulator model). The more stringent the inter-agency monitoring is, the more effective regulation might be at achieving minimum compliance with undervalued goals, but with the consequence of greatly increasing transaction costs such as litigation. Thus, principals will not only have to trade off agency performance among multiple goals, but will also have to trade off among the various solutions they might try to use to address the problems of multiple-goal agencies.","PeriodicalId":45668,"journal":{"name":"Harvard Environmental Law Review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.7000,"publicationDate":"2009-04-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"56","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Harvard Environmental Law Review","FirstCategoryId":"90","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1090313","RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q4","JCRName":"ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 56

Abstract

All federal agencies must cope with the challenges of trying to achieve success on the multiple goals laid out for them by Congress, the President, or the public at large. Recent economics and political science literature provides a theoretical framework that helps explain why agencies might succeed in achieving some goals and fail in achieving others: Agencies will systematically underperform on goals that are hard to measure and that conflict with the achievement of other, more measurable goals. While agencies in theory might be able to improve their ability to measure performance through technological and organizational innovation, in many cases agency missions, historical inertia, and the professional orientation of agency staff will interfere with innovation. Principals (such as Congress) have various options to address this problem. Some options focus on changing the agency itself: (1) having the principal take back decision-making authority from the agency; (2) splitting agencies into components that pursue different goals; or (3) mandating that the agency innovate in developing information about undervalued goals. All of these intra-agency efforts have their limitations: Principals only have so much time and energy to make decisions themselves; splitting agencies is often not feasible; and agencies may be resistant to external cultural change. Another range of options involves having another agency monitor the decision-making agency to ensure minimal compliance with performance on one or more goals. This could include having one agency comment on the decision-making agency's performance on an undervalued goal (the agency as lobbyist model) or could extend to having another agency make legally binding determinations about whether the decision-making agency has met minimum standards for that undervalued goal (the agency as regulator model). The more stringent the inter-agency monitoring is, the more effective regulation might be at achieving minimum compliance with undervalued goals, but with the consequence of greatly increasing transaction costs such as litigation. Thus, principals will not only have to trade off agency performance among multiple goals, but will also have to trade off among the various solutions they might try to use to address the problems of multiple-goal agencies.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
太多的事情要做:如何处理多目标机构的功能失调
所有联邦机构都必须应对挑战,努力实现国会、总统或广大公众为它们设定的多重目标。最近的经济学和政治学文献提供了一个理论框架,有助于解释为什么机构可能会成功实现某些目标,而无法实现其他目标:机构在难以衡量的目标上系统性地表现不佳,并且与其他更可衡量的目标的实现相冲突。虽然从理论上讲,机构可以通过技术和组织创新来提高衡量绩效的能力,但在许多情况下,机构的使命、历史惯性和机构工作人员的专业取向会干扰创新。主体(如国会)有各种选择来解决这个问题。一些方案侧重于改变代理机构本身:(1)让委托人从代理机构收回决策权;(2)将机构划分为追求不同目标的组成部分;或者(3)要求机构在开发有关被低估目标的信息方面进行创新。所有这些机构内部的努力都有其局限性:校长只有那么多的时间和精力来自己做决定;拆分机构通常是不可行的;机构可能会抵制外部文化变革。另一种选择包括让另一个机构监督决策机构,以确保在一个或多个目标上的表现达到最低限度。这可能包括让一个机构对决策机构在一个被低估的目标上的表现发表评论(作为说客模式的机构),或者可以扩展到让另一个机构对决策机构是否达到了该被低估目标的最低标准做出具有法律约束力的决定(作为监管者模式的机构)。机构间监测越严格,就越能有效地实现最低限度地遵守被低估的目标,但其后果是大大增加诸如诉讼等交易成本。因此,委托人不仅必须在多个目标之间权衡代理绩效,而且还必须在他们可能试图用来解决多目标代理问题的各种解决方案之间进行权衡。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
1.50
自引率
15.40%
发文量
0
期刊介绍: The Harvard Environmental Law Review is published semiannually by Harvard Law School students. Views expressed in the Review are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of HELR members. Editorial Policy: HELR has adopted a broad view of environmental affairs to include such areas as land use and property rights; air, water, and noise regula-tion; toxic substances control; radiation control; energy use; workplace pollution; science and technology control; and resource use and regulation. HELR is interested in developments on the local, state, federal, foreign, or international levels.
期刊最新文献
Reconstituting the Federalism Battle in Energy Transportation How Cheap is Corporate Talk? Comparing Companies' Comments on Regulations With Their Securities Disclosures Fracking, Federalism, and Private Governance Solving the CSO Conundrum: Green Infrastructure and the UnfulfilledPromise of Federal-Municipal Cooperation Ten Ways States Can Combat Ocean Acidification (and Why They Should)
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1