评估收费机制对竞争的影响

Steven Semeraro
{"title":"评估收费机制对竞争的影响","authors":"Steven Semeraro","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.3148050","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"The Department of Justice’s theory of liability in its case attacking the non-discrimination provisions in American Express’s merchant acceptance contends that point-of-sale competition on the price of making a purchase with a credit card is an instrument creating economic efficiency. That is, the economy would run more efficiently, and consumers would be better off, if merchants were free to charge variable prices for different types of credit cards. After all, charging different prices for using different types of payment mechanisms appears to be just another form of presumptively positive price competition. The Second Circuit rejected that conclusion, recognizing that in credit card markets competition already occurs at multiple points. American Express must compete to: • convince cardholders to apply for and use its cards; and • convince merchants to accept its cards. The question, the Second Circuit correctly recognized, is whether adding a third type of competition – for cardholders to use the card when merchants pass through their card acceptance fees – would make American Express’s card network more efficient? By prohibiting merchants who accept American Express cards from discriminating against the brand, the card company imposed a unilateral vertical restraint. Such restraints are often deemed to be reasonable under the antitrust laws because they may “stimulate inter-brand competition.” This is because an upstream provider, like American Express, has little interest in reducing its downstream sales. It would only impose a vertical restraint if that restraint efficiently helped it to sell more products. Only when an upstream or downstream provider has market power enabling it to impose restraints that harm consumers by raising price or lowering quality does a vertical restraint violate the antitrust laws. The Department of Justice’s theory postulated that the non-discrimination provisions in American Express’s merchant agreements harmed consumers by effectively requiring merchants to increase their prices to cover higher credit card fees for all customers because merchants could not pass the cost of accepting American Express directly to American Express’s own customers. The Second Circuit acknowledged the potential for consumer harm would exist if American Express charged merchants supra-competitive prices and pocketed the excess as rents. But the court held that the government failed to prove that rivalry on the price consumers pay to use a credit card at the point of sale would increase efficiency in credit card markets. As the Second Circuit explained, credit card markets are two-sided. In order to prove harm to consumer welfare in a two-sided market, an antitrust plaintiff needs to show that a restraint makes the overall system less efficient. That is, do consumers overall pay more for less because of the restraint. A card network like American Express must compete for both cardholders and merchants. One therefore cannot demonstrate that price increases on one side of the market are inefficient without examining how those prices impact competition on the other side of the market. American Express argued that it used increased revenue from the merchant side to offer a better card product to its cardholders and compete more effectively with other card networks, like Visa, for cardholder loyalty. The Second Circuit did not definitively decide whether American Express’s non-discrimination provisions were pro- or anticompetitive. It simple concluded that two-sided market economics made the question more complex than the government plaintiffs acknowledged in trying the case. And based on the record evidence, the court couldn’t tell whether the non-discrimination provisions made the market more or less efficient. Since the plaintiff bears the burden of proving harm to competition, i.e. a reduction in efficiency to the overall market, the government plaintiffs had failed to prove their case. Part I reviews the economics of two-sided markets and provides reasons to conclude that non-discrimination provisions in credit card markets are efficient. Part II explains that two-sided market economics do not guarantee against supra-competitive merchant fees that would make the market less efficient. It then contrasts Visa’s and MasterCard’s fees in the 1990s and early 2000s – which were challenged by merchants in a class action – with American Express’s current fees. It concludes that the factors giving the merchants a plausible case against Visa and MasterCard do not support the government plaintiffs in their case against American Express. Part III addresses a systemic concern expressed in a recent New York Times editorial about how a decision in American Express’s favor might impact the future enforcement of antitrust claims against dominant firms. This Part concludes that those concerns are unfounded because truly dominant firms would be subject to scrutiny under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, and Section 1 vertical restraint cases already require proof of consumer harm no different from what the Second Circuit required in its decision favoring American Express.","PeriodicalId":175183,"journal":{"name":"LSN: Payment Systems (Sub-Topic)","volume":"74 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2018-03-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Assessing the Competitive Effects of Surcharging the Use of Payment Mechanisms\",\"authors\":\"Steven Semeraro\",\"doi\":\"10.2139/SSRN.3148050\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"The Department of Justice’s theory of liability in its case attacking the non-discrimination provisions in American Express’s merchant acceptance contends that point-of-sale competition on the price of making a purchase with a credit card is an instrument creating economic efficiency. That is, the economy would run more efficiently, and consumers would be better off, if merchants were free to charge variable prices for different types of credit cards. After all, charging different prices for using different types of payment mechanisms appears to be just another form of presumptively positive price competition. The Second Circuit rejected that conclusion, recognizing that in credit card markets competition already occurs at multiple points. American Express must compete to: • convince cardholders to apply for and use its cards; and • convince merchants to accept its cards. The question, the Second Circuit correctly recognized, is whether adding a third type of competition – for cardholders to use the card when merchants pass through their card acceptance fees – would make American Express’s card network more efficient? By prohibiting merchants who accept American Express cards from discriminating against the brand, the card company imposed a unilateral vertical restraint. Such restraints are often deemed to be reasonable under the antitrust laws because they may “stimulate inter-brand competition.” This is because an upstream provider, like American Express, has little interest in reducing its downstream sales. It would only impose a vertical restraint if that restraint efficiently helped it to sell more products. Only when an upstream or downstream provider has market power enabling it to impose restraints that harm consumers by raising price or lowering quality does a vertical restraint violate the antitrust laws. The Department of Justice’s theory postulated that the non-discrimination provisions in American Express’s merchant agreements harmed consumers by effectively requiring merchants to increase their prices to cover higher credit card fees for all customers because merchants could not pass the cost of accepting American Express directly to American Express’s own customers. The Second Circuit acknowledged the potential for consumer harm would exist if American Express charged merchants supra-competitive prices and pocketed the excess as rents. But the court held that the government failed to prove that rivalry on the price consumers pay to use a credit card at the point of sale would increase efficiency in credit card markets. As the Second Circuit explained, credit card markets are two-sided. In order to prove harm to consumer welfare in a two-sided market, an antitrust plaintiff needs to show that a restraint makes the overall system less efficient. That is, do consumers overall pay more for less because of the restraint. A card network like American Express must compete for both cardholders and merchants. One therefore cannot demonstrate that price increases on one side of the market are inefficient without examining how those prices impact competition on the other side of the market. American Express argued that it used increased revenue from the merchant side to offer a better card product to its cardholders and compete more effectively with other card networks, like Visa, for cardholder loyalty. The Second Circuit did not definitively decide whether American Express’s non-discrimination provisions were pro- or anticompetitive. It simple concluded that two-sided market economics made the question more complex than the government plaintiffs acknowledged in trying the case. And based on the record evidence, the court couldn’t tell whether the non-discrimination provisions made the market more or less efficient. Since the plaintiff bears the burden of proving harm to competition, i.e. a reduction in efficiency to the overall market, the government plaintiffs had failed to prove their case. Part I reviews the economics of two-sided markets and provides reasons to conclude that non-discrimination provisions in credit card markets are efficient. Part II explains that two-sided market economics do not guarantee against supra-competitive merchant fees that would make the market less efficient. It then contrasts Visa’s and MasterCard’s fees in the 1990s and early 2000s – which were challenged by merchants in a class action – with American Express’s current fees. It concludes that the factors giving the merchants a plausible case against Visa and MasterCard do not support the government plaintiffs in their case against American Express. Part III addresses a systemic concern expressed in a recent New York Times editorial about how a decision in American Express’s favor might impact the future enforcement of antitrust claims against dominant firms. This Part concludes that those concerns are unfounded because truly dominant firms would be subject to scrutiny under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, and Section 1 vertical restraint cases already require proof of consumer harm no different from what the Second Circuit required in its decision favoring American Express.\",\"PeriodicalId\":175183,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"LSN: Payment Systems (Sub-Topic)\",\"volume\":\"74 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2018-03-23\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"LSN: Payment Systems (Sub-Topic)\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3148050\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"LSN: Payment Systems (Sub-Topic)","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3148050","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

司法部在其攻击美国运通(American Express)商户接受中的非歧视条款的案件中提出的责任理论认为,使用信用卡购物的价格上的销售点竞争是一种创造经济效率的工具。也就是说,如果商家可以自由地对不同类型的信用卡收取可变价格,经济将会更有效地运行,消费者也会更富裕。毕竟,使用不同类型的支付机制收取不同的价格似乎只是另一种形式的假定积极的价格竞争。第二巡回法院驳回了这一结论,承认在信用卡市场竞争已经发生在多个点上。美国运通必须努力:•说服持卡人申请和使用它的信用卡;•说服商家接受它的信用卡。第二巡回法院正确地认识到,问题是增加第三种竞争——持卡人在商家支付信用卡接受费时使用信用卡——是否会使美国运通的信用卡网络更有效率?通过禁止接受美国运通卡的商家歧视该品牌,信用卡公司实施了单方面的纵向限制。根据反垄断法,这种限制通常被认为是合理的,因为它们可能“刺激品牌间竞争”。这是因为像美国运通这样的上游供应商没有兴趣减少下游的销售。只有当这种限制有效地帮助它销售更多产品时,它才会施加垂直限制。只有当上游或下游供应商拥有市场力量,使其能够通过提高价格或降低质量来施加限制,从而损害消费者时,垂直限制才违反反垄断法。司法部的理论假定美国运通的商户协议中的非歧视条款损害了消费者,因为商家不能将接受美国运通的成本直接转嫁给美国运通自己的客户,因此有效地要求商家提高价格,以支付所有客户更高的信用卡费用。第二巡回法院承认,如果美国运通向商家收取极具竞争力的价格,并将多余的部分作为租金收入囊中,可能会对消费者造成伤害。但法院认为,政府未能证明消费者在销售点支付的信用卡价格上的竞争会提高信用卡市场的效率。正如第二巡回法院解释的那样,信用卡市场是两面性的。为了证明在双边市场中对消费者福利的损害,反垄断原告需要证明一种限制使整个系统效率降低。也就是说,消费者是否因为限制而花更多的钱买更少的东西。像美国运通这样的信用卡网络必须同时争夺持卡人和商户。因此,如果不考察这些价格如何影响市场另一端的竞争,就不能证明市场一端的价格上涨是低效的。美国运通辩称,它利用来自商户的收入增加,为持卡人提供更好的信用卡产品,并更有效地与Visa等其他信用卡网络竞争,以争夺持卡人的忠诚度。第二巡回法院并没有明确决定美国运通的非歧视条款是支持还是反竞争。它简单地得出结论,双边市场经济使问题比政府原告在审理此案时承认的要复杂得多。根据记录证据,法院无法判断非歧视条款是提高了市场效率还是降低了市场效率。由于原告承担着证明损害竞争的责任,即对整个市场效率的降低,因此政府原告未能证明其案件。第一部分回顾了双边市场的经济学,并提供了得出信用卡市场非歧视条款是有效的结论的理由。第二部分解释了双边市场经济并不能保证不收取会使市场效率降低的超竞争性商人费用。然后,它将Visa和万事达在上世纪90年代和21世纪初的收费与美国运通目前的收费进行了对比。Visa和万事达在一次集体诉讼中遭到了商户的质疑。它的结论是,让商家对Visa和万事达提出合理指控的因素,并不支持政府原告对美国运通提起诉讼。第三部分阐述了《纽约时报》最近一篇社论中表达的系统性担忧,即美国运通胜诉的决定可能会影响未来针对主导企业的反垄断诉讼的执行。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
Assessing the Competitive Effects of Surcharging the Use of Payment Mechanisms
The Department of Justice’s theory of liability in its case attacking the non-discrimination provisions in American Express’s merchant acceptance contends that point-of-sale competition on the price of making a purchase with a credit card is an instrument creating economic efficiency. That is, the economy would run more efficiently, and consumers would be better off, if merchants were free to charge variable prices for different types of credit cards. After all, charging different prices for using different types of payment mechanisms appears to be just another form of presumptively positive price competition. The Second Circuit rejected that conclusion, recognizing that in credit card markets competition already occurs at multiple points. American Express must compete to: • convince cardholders to apply for and use its cards; and • convince merchants to accept its cards. The question, the Second Circuit correctly recognized, is whether adding a third type of competition – for cardholders to use the card when merchants pass through their card acceptance fees – would make American Express’s card network more efficient? By prohibiting merchants who accept American Express cards from discriminating against the brand, the card company imposed a unilateral vertical restraint. Such restraints are often deemed to be reasonable under the antitrust laws because they may “stimulate inter-brand competition.” This is because an upstream provider, like American Express, has little interest in reducing its downstream sales. It would only impose a vertical restraint if that restraint efficiently helped it to sell more products. Only when an upstream or downstream provider has market power enabling it to impose restraints that harm consumers by raising price or lowering quality does a vertical restraint violate the antitrust laws. The Department of Justice’s theory postulated that the non-discrimination provisions in American Express’s merchant agreements harmed consumers by effectively requiring merchants to increase their prices to cover higher credit card fees for all customers because merchants could not pass the cost of accepting American Express directly to American Express’s own customers. The Second Circuit acknowledged the potential for consumer harm would exist if American Express charged merchants supra-competitive prices and pocketed the excess as rents. But the court held that the government failed to prove that rivalry on the price consumers pay to use a credit card at the point of sale would increase efficiency in credit card markets. As the Second Circuit explained, credit card markets are two-sided. In order to prove harm to consumer welfare in a two-sided market, an antitrust plaintiff needs to show that a restraint makes the overall system less efficient. That is, do consumers overall pay more for less because of the restraint. A card network like American Express must compete for both cardholders and merchants. One therefore cannot demonstrate that price increases on one side of the market are inefficient without examining how those prices impact competition on the other side of the market. American Express argued that it used increased revenue from the merchant side to offer a better card product to its cardholders and compete more effectively with other card networks, like Visa, for cardholder loyalty. The Second Circuit did not definitively decide whether American Express’s non-discrimination provisions were pro- or anticompetitive. It simple concluded that two-sided market economics made the question more complex than the government plaintiffs acknowledged in trying the case. And based on the record evidence, the court couldn’t tell whether the non-discrimination provisions made the market more or less efficient. Since the plaintiff bears the burden of proving harm to competition, i.e. a reduction in efficiency to the overall market, the government plaintiffs had failed to prove their case. Part I reviews the economics of two-sided markets and provides reasons to conclude that non-discrimination provisions in credit card markets are efficient. Part II explains that two-sided market economics do not guarantee against supra-competitive merchant fees that would make the market less efficient. It then contrasts Visa’s and MasterCard’s fees in the 1990s and early 2000s – which were challenged by merchants in a class action – with American Express’s current fees. It concludes that the factors giving the merchants a plausible case against Visa and MasterCard do not support the government plaintiffs in their case against American Express. Part III addresses a systemic concern expressed in a recent New York Times editorial about how a decision in American Express’s favor might impact the future enforcement of antitrust claims against dominant firms. This Part concludes that those concerns are unfounded because truly dominant firms would be subject to scrutiny under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, and Section 1 vertical restraint cases already require proof of consumer harm no different from what the Second Circuit required in its decision favoring American Express.
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
The Importance of Where Central Bank Digital Currencies Are Custodied: Exploring the Need of a Universal Access Device Cash, Crime, and Cryptocurrencies Assessing the Competitive Effects of Surcharging the Use of Payment Mechanisms Distributed Ledger Technology and the Future of Payment Services Corporate Governance for Complex Cryptocurrencies? A Framework for Stability and Decision Making in Blockchain-Based Organizations
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1