高国内出口附加值应该成为政策目标吗?

David L. Dollar
{"title":"高国内出口附加值应该成为政策目标吗?","authors":"David L. Dollar","doi":"10.30875/0a2c5fe2-en","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Global value chains make it easier for developing countries to move away from export reliance on unprocessed primary products to become exporters of manufactures and services. Global value chains (GVCs) allow countries to specialize in a particular activity and join a global production network. As a developing country moves from export of primary products to export of manufactures and services via GVCs, the ratio of domestic value added to gross export value tends to fall. Many developing country policy-makers worry about this trend and aspire to increase their value added contribution to exports. There are a number of reasons why this objective is not good policy. It may seem like simple math that a higher domestic value added share means more total value added exported and hence more GDP. But that simple idea ignores the reality that imported goods and services are a key support to a country’s competitiveness. The chapter documents this via the history of the successful East Asian industrializers as well as more recent evidence from Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) economies. If a country artificially replaces key inputs with inferior domestic versions, the end result is likely to be fewer gross exports and less, not more, total value added exports. Should high domestic value added in exports be an objective of policy? David Dollar (Brookings Institution), Bilal Khan (RCGVC-UIBE), and Jiansuo Pei (SITE-UIBE) • In almost all countries, developed and developing alike, the share of domestic value added in exports has tended to trend downwards recently. This reflects the expansion of global value chains. • Many developing countries worry about this phenomenon and aspire to increase their value-added contribution to exports. This objective should be approached cautiously. Imported goods and services are a key support to a country’s competitiveness. If a country artificially replaces key inputs with inferior domestic versions, the result is likely to be fewer gross exports and fewer, not more, total value-added exports. • China’s recent experience is often given as an important counter-example, since its domestic valueadded ratio has been rising over the past decade, but our research indicates that this trend is primarily the result of technological advances in China. • Consequently, the Chinese ratio can be expected to peak and later decline if China further opens up and follows in the steps of other earlier Asian industrializers, such as Japan and the Republic of Korea. 142 • Technological innovation, supply chain trade, and workers in a globalized world","PeriodicalId":296231,"journal":{"name":"Global Value Chain Development Report 2019","volume":"5 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"9","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Should high domestic value added in exports be an objective of policy?\",\"authors\":\"David L. Dollar\",\"doi\":\"10.30875/0a2c5fe2-en\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"Global value chains make it easier for developing countries to move away from export reliance on unprocessed primary products to become exporters of manufactures and services. Global value chains (GVCs) allow countries to specialize in a particular activity and join a global production network. As a developing country moves from export of primary products to export of manufactures and services via GVCs, the ratio of domestic value added to gross export value tends to fall. Many developing country policy-makers worry about this trend and aspire to increase their value added contribution to exports. There are a number of reasons why this objective is not good policy. It may seem like simple math that a higher domestic value added share means more total value added exported and hence more GDP. But that simple idea ignores the reality that imported goods and services are a key support to a country’s competitiveness. The chapter documents this via the history of the successful East Asian industrializers as well as more recent evidence from Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) economies. If a country artificially replaces key inputs with inferior domestic versions, the end result is likely to be fewer gross exports and less, not more, total value added exports. Should high domestic value added in exports be an objective of policy? David Dollar (Brookings Institution), Bilal Khan (RCGVC-UIBE), and Jiansuo Pei (SITE-UIBE) • In almost all countries, developed and developing alike, the share of domestic value added in exports has tended to trend downwards recently. This reflects the expansion of global value chains. • Many developing countries worry about this phenomenon and aspire to increase their value-added contribution to exports. This objective should be approached cautiously. Imported goods and services are a key support to a country’s competitiveness. If a country artificially replaces key inputs with inferior domestic versions, the result is likely to be fewer gross exports and fewer, not more, total value-added exports. • China’s recent experience is often given as an important counter-example, since its domestic valueadded ratio has been rising over the past decade, but our research indicates that this trend is primarily the result of technological advances in China. • Consequently, the Chinese ratio can be expected to peak and later decline if China further opens up and follows in the steps of other earlier Asian industrializers, such as Japan and the Republic of Korea. 142 • Technological innovation, supply chain trade, and workers in a globalized world\",\"PeriodicalId\":296231,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Global Value Chain Development Report 2019\",\"volume\":\"5 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"1900-01-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"9\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Global Value Chain Development Report 2019\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.30875/0a2c5fe2-en\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Global Value Chain Development Report 2019","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.30875/0a2c5fe2-en","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 9

摘要

全球价值链使发展中国家更容易摆脱对未加工初级产品的出口依赖,成为制成品和服务的出口国。全球价值链(GVCs)使各国能够专门从事某一特定活动并加入全球生产网络。随着发展中国家从初级产品出口转向通过全球价值链出口制成品和服务,其国内增加值占出口总值的比例趋于下降。许多发展中国家的决策者对这一趋势感到担忧,并渴望增加其对出口的附加值贡献。这一目标不是好政策的原因有很多。较高的国内增加值份额意味着更多的总出口增加值,从而增加GDP,这似乎是一个简单的数学。但这种简单的想法忽视了一个现实,即进口商品和服务是一个国家竞争力的关键支撑。本章通过成功的东亚工业化国家的历史以及来自东南亚国家联盟(ASEAN)经济体的最新证据来证明这一点。如果一个国家人为地用劣质的国内产品取代关键投入,最终结果很可能是总出口减少,总增加值出口减少,而不是增加。高国内出口附加值应该成为政策目标吗?David Dollar(布鲁金斯学会),Bilal Khan (rcgvc -对外经济贸易大学),Pei Jiansuo(对外经济贸易大学)•几乎在所有国家,无论是发达国家还是发展中国家,最近国内增加值在出口中的份额都有下降的趋势。这反映了全球价值链的扩大。•许多发展中国家对这一现象感到担忧,并渴望增加其对出口的增值贡献。这一目标应该谨慎对待。进口商品和服务是国家竞争力的重要支撑。如果一个国家人为地用劣质的国内产品取代关键投入,其结果很可能是总出口减少,总增值出口减少,而不是增加。•中国最近的经验经常被作为一个重要的反例,因为其国内增值比率在过去十年中一直在上升,但我们的研究表明,这一趋势主要是中国技术进步的结果。•因此,如果中国进一步开放并跟随其他早期亚洲工业化国家(如日本和韩国)的步伐,中国的比例可以预期达到峰值,随后下降。142•全球化世界中的技术创新、供应链贸易和工人
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
Should high domestic value added in exports be an objective of policy?
Global value chains make it easier for developing countries to move away from export reliance on unprocessed primary products to become exporters of manufactures and services. Global value chains (GVCs) allow countries to specialize in a particular activity and join a global production network. As a developing country moves from export of primary products to export of manufactures and services via GVCs, the ratio of domestic value added to gross export value tends to fall. Many developing country policy-makers worry about this trend and aspire to increase their value added contribution to exports. There are a number of reasons why this objective is not good policy. It may seem like simple math that a higher domestic value added share means more total value added exported and hence more GDP. But that simple idea ignores the reality that imported goods and services are a key support to a country’s competitiveness. The chapter documents this via the history of the successful East Asian industrializers as well as more recent evidence from Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) economies. If a country artificially replaces key inputs with inferior domestic versions, the end result is likely to be fewer gross exports and less, not more, total value added exports. Should high domestic value added in exports be an objective of policy? David Dollar (Brookings Institution), Bilal Khan (RCGVC-UIBE), and Jiansuo Pei (SITE-UIBE) • In almost all countries, developed and developing alike, the share of domestic value added in exports has tended to trend downwards recently. This reflects the expansion of global value chains. • Many developing countries worry about this phenomenon and aspire to increase their value-added contribution to exports. This objective should be approached cautiously. Imported goods and services are a key support to a country’s competitiveness. If a country artificially replaces key inputs with inferior domestic versions, the result is likely to be fewer gross exports and fewer, not more, total value-added exports. • China’s recent experience is often given as an important counter-example, since its domestic valueadded ratio has been rising over the past decade, but our research indicates that this trend is primarily the result of technological advances in China. • Consequently, the Chinese ratio can be expected to peak and later decline if China further opens up and follows in the steps of other earlier Asian industrializers, such as Japan and the Republic of Korea. 142 • Technological innovation, supply chain trade, and workers in a globalized world
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
Understanding Supply Chain 4.0 and its potential impact on global value chains Acknowledgments Executive summary Improving the accounting frameworks for analyses of global value chains Global value chains and employment in developing economies
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1