冲击持续性与武装冲突研究:实证偏差及补救措施

IF 1.5 3区 社会学 Q2 INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS International Interactions Pub Date : 2023-10-13 DOI:10.1080/03050629.2023.2266553
Jenny Guardado, Steven Pennings
{"title":"冲击持续性与武装冲突研究:实证偏差及补救措施","authors":"Jenny Guardado, Steven Pennings","doi":"10.1080/03050629.2023.2266553","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"AbstractPoor employment prospects for potential insurgents are often thought to increase the intensity of armed conflict. A large empirical literature tries to identify the strength of this “opportunity cost” channel, in part by regressing conflict on commodity price shocks that affect the demand for workers. In this research note we develop a theoretical framework to interpret these empirical results. We argue that because commodity price shocks are usually persistent, the estimated strength of the opportunity cost mechanism will be biased upwards (towards zero)—even for labor-intensive commodities whose price shocks are not permanent. We define this bias analytically and, using regressions on simulated data, show that it is quantitatively important for commodities studied in the literature. The bias occurs because persistent shocks that reduce employment prospects today are correlated with unobserved dynamic motivations to fight, such as the expected value of an oil field or a fighter’s subjective value of a grievance. We conclude that the opportunity cost mechanism may be even stronger than has been estimated, and that researchers should use transient, seasonal or anticipated shocks to identify its magnitude.Con frecuencia, se tiene la tendencia a pensar que el hecho de que los potenciales insurgentes tengan unas expectativas pobres en materia de empleabilidad contribuye a aumentar la intensidad de los conflictos armados. Existe una amplia bibliografía, de carácter empírico, que trata de identificar la fortaleza de este canal de «coste de oportunidad». Esto, lo hace, en parte, mediante la regresión del conflicto con respecto a las perturbaciones en materia de precios de los productos básicos, las cuales afectan la demanda de trabajadores. En esta nota de investigación, desarrollamos un marco teórico para interpretar estos resultados empíricos. Argumentamos que, debido a que las perturbaciones en materia de precios de los productos básicos suelen ser persistentes, la fortaleza estimada del mecanismo de coste de oportunidad estará sesgada al alza (hacia cero), incluso para aquellos productos básicos intensivos en mano de obra para los cuales las perturbaciones en materia de precios no resultan permanentes. Definimos este sesgo de forma analítica y demostramos, mediante el uso de regresiones en datos simulados, que este resulta cuantitativamente importante para los productos estudiados en la bibliografía. El sesgo se produce porque los cambios persistentes que contribuyen, actualmente, a reducir las perspectivas de empleo se correlacionan con motivaciones dinámicas para luchar que no han sido tenidas en cuenta, como el valor esperado de un campo petrolero o el valor subjetivo que un combatiente otorga a un agravio. Concluimos que el mecanismo de coste de oportunidad puede ser incluso más fuerte de lo que se había estimado, y que los investigadores deben usar perturbaciones transitorias o estacionales para poder identificar su magnitud.Des perspectives d’emploi médiocres pour les rebelles potentiels intensifieraient souvent les conflits armés. Une abondante littérature empirique tente d’identifier la force de ce canal de « coût d’opportunité », en partie en remontant le conflit jusqu’à une crise des prix des matières premières qui a une incidence sur la demande de travailleurs. Dans cette note de recherche, nous développons un cadre théorique pour interpréter ces résultats empiriques. Nous affirmons que puisque les crises des prix des matières premières sont généralement de longue durée, l’estimation de la force du mécanisme coût-opportunité sera haussière (vers zéro), même pour les marchandises intensives en travail dont les crises de prix ne sont pas permanentes. Nous définissons ce biais sur le plan analytique et, à l’aide de régressions à partir de données simulées, nous montrons son importance quantitative pour les matières premières étudiées dans la littérature. Le biais intervient quand des crises persistantes qui réduisent les perspectives d’emploi aujourd’hui sont corrélées à des motifs de conflit dynamiques, comme la valeur attendue d’un champ pétrolifère ou la valeur subjective qu’un combattant accorde à un grief. La conclusion indique que l’importance du mécanisme coût-opportunité pourrait bien être plus élevée que nos estimations, et suggère aux chercheurs d’utiliser des crises passagères ou saisonnières pour identifier son ampleur.Keywords: Commodity price shocksconflictopportunity cost mechanismJEL: D74O13Q34 AcknowledgmentWe thank the editor, two anonymous referees, and participants at various conferences and seminars for helpful comments.Disclosure statementThe views expressed here are the authors’ and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank, its executive directors, or the countries they represent.Notes1 For example, Dube and Vargas (Citation2013) find that higher coffee prices reduce conflict intensity in Colombia and, as coffee price shocks are typically fairly persistent, their results might be even stronger than estimated. Exactly how much stronger is difficult to calculate as they instrument coffee price shocks using other country’s exports (which have an unknown persistence), rather than using the international price series. Bazzi and Blattman (Citation2014) find that price shocks for all commodity types reduce conflict intensity (their Tables 7 and 8). As these are bundles of different commodities, its persistence is also difficult to calculate.2 Motivated by the high fraction of part-time fighters in insurgencies (Appendix Figure 3.2), our model assumes insurgent fighters can transition freely between working and fighting. However, in contexts where there are substantial fixed costs of moving from fighting to working (or vice-versa), it could be that the opportunity cost mechanism itself is weaker in response to temporary/seasonal shocks than persistent shocks, and in those contexts our theory may be less applicable.3 In terms of practical application, researchers need to be careful that (i) the transient/seasonal shocks used actually affect labor incomes and the opportunity cost of fighting (rainfall shocks outside the growing season may not), and (ii) results are not confounded by other seasonal variables, such as temperature and religious festivals. Guardado and Pennings (Citation2020) get around the second problem by utilizing subnational variation in the timing and intensity of harvest, which allows them to include month fixed effects and temperature controls in their specification.4 We focus on conflict intensity for simplicity, because that is where commodity price shocks are most likely to have an effect, but also because most insurgencies are long-lasting with low intensity (Fearon Citation2008). The connection between shocks and conflict incidence or onset is weaker (and is close to zero for most countries). The relation is also more complex, in part because shocks can affect bargaining which staves off conflict onset/incidence (Chassang and Padró i Miquel Citation2009). A recent empirical literature has emphasized the complexity of modeling conflict onset (rather than intensity): Malone (Citation2022) finds the opportunity cost mechanism tends to affect militant formation rather than conflict onset and Buhaug et al. (Citation2021) find that droughts are more likely to start a conflict in areas with a recently downgraded ethnic group.5 Alternatively, she might instrument the wage with a relevant shock.6 If shocks are anticipated, they will also leave the expected value of the prize (EtΠt+1Prize) unchanged—because the value of the changes in future profits have already been “priced in” (as in the stock market). Hence the estimated size of the opportunity cost mechanism is close to being unbiased using anticipated shocks, even when those shocks are persistent and the value of the prize is unobserved (results available upon request). Seasonal shocks are both transient and anticipated.7 Bias in some dynamic models of conflict might be due to omitted lags; see Beck and Katz (Citation2011). But in the greed models here, the estimated coefficient on lagged wages or lagged violence is zero, and does not affect the contemporaneous elasticity.8 This applies to types of commodities and production where insurgent groups are be able to tax production in the event their campaign is successful. Commodities with a benchmark world price studied in the literature are often easier to tax, given exports must pass through ports or through border crossings. But this is not universal. For example, Crost and Felter (Citation2020) find that higher world banana prices increase conflict and extortion by rebels in the Philippines only for large plantations, but not for small farmers.9 This is a good approximation of the “power form” of the contest function (Garfinkel and Skaperdas Citation2007, Equation 3) in a low-level insurgency where the strength of the government is large (and constant)–see Appendix 1. ϕ>1 ensures positive but diminishing marginal returns to fighting p′(Vt)>0,p″(Vt)<0.10 When ϕ→1 (weak opportunity cost mechanism), p(Vt) is very curved so when wages increase, violence barely needs to fall in order to increase p′(Vt) and make fighting more attractive. Conversely, when ϕ is very large (strong opportunity cost mechanism) p(Vt) is very flat, so when wages increase, violence has to fall substantially in order to increase p′(Vt) to make fighting more attractive to regain equilibrium.11 In this former case, let the price of domestic consumption goods be the numeraire and the international price of the commodity be θt, and assume that the volume of cash crops produced for export is Ltα . Then the amount of consumption goods that can be purchased is θtLtα.12 We abstract from any other costs of losing, like death, exile or imprisonment, which make the model more complicated. One could consider a more general setup with a fixed cost of losing, or where a losing insurgent is not able to work in the second period. The fixed cost from losing has little qualitative effect on our argument. Moreover, the inability to work in the second period actually strengthens the bias from persistent shocks, as a positive persistent shock that raises wages in t makes the value of winning (and hence working in t + 1) more valuable.13 The constant κ1=ϕlnψ(1−ϕ−1)+ϕlnδ. In Equation (5), κ2= ϕlnψ(1−ϕ−1)+ϕlnδ and κ3=(1−ρ)lnθ¯ and κ4=κ2+κ3−ϕlnα14 Fearon (Citation2008) and Chassang and Padró i Miquel (Citation2009) both argue that permanent changes in the level of economic development, or income, increase both the opportunity cost of violence and the spoils of war, leaving the level of violence unchanged, which we also find as ρ→1.15 This result (analytically and quantitatively) requires ψ, the efficiency of the fighting technology, to be adjusted to maintain the insurgency at only a low level so L≈1 (this is also the empirically relevant case, Fearon Citation2008).16 One might be concerned that seasonal or transient shocks might only have a small effect on wages or employment opportunities, as they are smoothed by employers. This seems unlikely in most cases, as employment in conflict-affected countries is typically informal, and informal employment lacks the binding long-term contracts that could isolate workers from changes in labor demand. One possible exception is “labor tying” arrangements in South Asia, but Mukherjee and Ray (Citation1995, 208) argue “the incidence of tying has undergone a steep secular decline to low current levels.” Drawing on de Janvry, Duquennois, and Sadoulet (Citation2022) and Guardado and Pennings (Citation2020), we report empirical evidence from Malawi and Iraq (respectively) that rural employment varies strongly with the seasons. See Appendix 3.1 for further discussion.17 As ρ→1 (more permanent), βOppMeas.→0, as in Proposition 1 above.18 i.e. βOppMeas.=−1.8 rather than βOppTrue=−3.19 The PIH states that only permanent changes in income should affect consumption (and transient shocks should be saved). Using data from Thailand, Paxson (Citation1993, 70) estimates how consumption varies with incomes across the seasons, and concludes that “the timing of income flows has little to do with the timing of [consumption] expenditure across seasons.”20 Appendix 2.3 includes a counterinsurgency information model of violence (motivated by Berman, Shapiro, and Felter Citation2011), which generates similar results through the same income-effect mechanism: a persistent increase in wages reduces violence directly, but also makes the agent richer, which makes passing-on counterinsurgency information for payment less attractive.","PeriodicalId":51513,"journal":{"name":"International Interactions","volume":"25 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":1.5000,"publicationDate":"2023-10-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Shock Persistence and the Study of Armed Conflict: Empirical Biases and Some Remedies\",\"authors\":\"Jenny Guardado, Steven Pennings\",\"doi\":\"10.1080/03050629.2023.2266553\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"AbstractPoor employment prospects for potential insurgents are often thought to increase the intensity of armed conflict. A large empirical literature tries to identify the strength of this “opportunity cost” channel, in part by regressing conflict on commodity price shocks that affect the demand for workers. In this research note we develop a theoretical framework to interpret these empirical results. We argue that because commodity price shocks are usually persistent, the estimated strength of the opportunity cost mechanism will be biased upwards (towards zero)—even for labor-intensive commodities whose price shocks are not permanent. We define this bias analytically and, using regressions on simulated data, show that it is quantitatively important for commodities studied in the literature. The bias occurs because persistent shocks that reduce employment prospects today are correlated with unobserved dynamic motivations to fight, such as the expected value of an oil field or a fighter’s subjective value of a grievance. We conclude that the opportunity cost mechanism may be even stronger than has been estimated, and that researchers should use transient, seasonal or anticipated shocks to identify its magnitude.Con frecuencia, se tiene la tendencia a pensar que el hecho de que los potenciales insurgentes tengan unas expectativas pobres en materia de empleabilidad contribuye a aumentar la intensidad de los conflictos armados. Existe una amplia bibliografía, de carácter empírico, que trata de identificar la fortaleza de este canal de «coste de oportunidad». Esto, lo hace, en parte, mediante la regresión del conflicto con respecto a las perturbaciones en materia de precios de los productos básicos, las cuales afectan la demanda de trabajadores. En esta nota de investigación, desarrollamos un marco teórico para interpretar estos resultados empíricos. Argumentamos que, debido a que las perturbaciones en materia de precios de los productos básicos suelen ser persistentes, la fortaleza estimada del mecanismo de coste de oportunidad estará sesgada al alza (hacia cero), incluso para aquellos productos básicos intensivos en mano de obra para los cuales las perturbaciones en materia de precios no resultan permanentes. Definimos este sesgo de forma analítica y demostramos, mediante el uso de regresiones en datos simulados, que este resulta cuantitativamente importante para los productos estudiados en la bibliografía. El sesgo se produce porque los cambios persistentes que contribuyen, actualmente, a reducir las perspectivas de empleo se correlacionan con motivaciones dinámicas para luchar que no han sido tenidas en cuenta, como el valor esperado de un campo petrolero o el valor subjetivo que un combatiente otorga a un agravio. Concluimos que el mecanismo de coste de oportunidad puede ser incluso más fuerte de lo que se había estimado, y que los investigadores deben usar perturbaciones transitorias o estacionales para poder identificar su magnitud.Des perspectives d’emploi médiocres pour les rebelles potentiels intensifieraient souvent les conflits armés. Une abondante littérature empirique tente d’identifier la force de ce canal de « coût d’opportunité », en partie en remontant le conflit jusqu’à une crise des prix des matières premières qui a une incidence sur la demande de travailleurs. Dans cette note de recherche, nous développons un cadre théorique pour interpréter ces résultats empiriques. Nous affirmons que puisque les crises des prix des matières premières sont généralement de longue durée, l’estimation de la force du mécanisme coût-opportunité sera haussière (vers zéro), même pour les marchandises intensives en travail dont les crises de prix ne sont pas permanentes. Nous définissons ce biais sur le plan analytique et, à l’aide de régressions à partir de données simulées, nous montrons son importance quantitative pour les matières premières étudiées dans la littérature. Le biais intervient quand des crises persistantes qui réduisent les perspectives d’emploi aujourd’hui sont corrélées à des motifs de conflit dynamiques, comme la valeur attendue d’un champ pétrolifère ou la valeur subjective qu’un combattant accorde à un grief. La conclusion indique que l’importance du mécanisme coût-opportunité pourrait bien être plus élevée que nos estimations, et suggère aux chercheurs d’utiliser des crises passagères ou saisonnières pour identifier son ampleur.Keywords: Commodity price shocksconflictopportunity cost mechanismJEL: D74O13Q34 AcknowledgmentWe thank the editor, two anonymous referees, and participants at various conferences and seminars for helpful comments.Disclosure statementThe views expressed here are the authors’ and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank, its executive directors, or the countries they represent.Notes1 For example, Dube and Vargas (Citation2013) find that higher coffee prices reduce conflict intensity in Colombia and, as coffee price shocks are typically fairly persistent, their results might be even stronger than estimated. Exactly how much stronger is difficult to calculate as they instrument coffee price shocks using other country’s exports (which have an unknown persistence), rather than using the international price series. Bazzi and Blattman (Citation2014) find that price shocks for all commodity types reduce conflict intensity (their Tables 7 and 8). As these are bundles of different commodities, its persistence is also difficult to calculate.2 Motivated by the high fraction of part-time fighters in insurgencies (Appendix Figure 3.2), our model assumes insurgent fighters can transition freely between working and fighting. However, in contexts where there are substantial fixed costs of moving from fighting to working (or vice-versa), it could be that the opportunity cost mechanism itself is weaker in response to temporary/seasonal shocks than persistent shocks, and in those contexts our theory may be less applicable.3 In terms of practical application, researchers need to be careful that (i) the transient/seasonal shocks used actually affect labor incomes and the opportunity cost of fighting (rainfall shocks outside the growing season may not), and (ii) results are not confounded by other seasonal variables, such as temperature and religious festivals. Guardado and Pennings (Citation2020) get around the second problem by utilizing subnational variation in the timing and intensity of harvest, which allows them to include month fixed effects and temperature controls in their specification.4 We focus on conflict intensity for simplicity, because that is where commodity price shocks are most likely to have an effect, but also because most insurgencies are long-lasting with low intensity (Fearon Citation2008). The connection between shocks and conflict incidence or onset is weaker (and is close to zero for most countries). The relation is also more complex, in part because shocks can affect bargaining which staves off conflict onset/incidence (Chassang and Padró i Miquel Citation2009). A recent empirical literature has emphasized the complexity of modeling conflict onset (rather than intensity): Malone (Citation2022) finds the opportunity cost mechanism tends to affect militant formation rather than conflict onset and Buhaug et al. (Citation2021) find that droughts are more likely to start a conflict in areas with a recently downgraded ethnic group.5 Alternatively, she might instrument the wage with a relevant shock.6 If shocks are anticipated, they will also leave the expected value of the prize (EtΠt+1Prize) unchanged—because the value of the changes in future profits have already been “priced in” (as in the stock market). Hence the estimated size of the opportunity cost mechanism is close to being unbiased using anticipated shocks, even when those shocks are persistent and the value of the prize is unobserved (results available upon request). Seasonal shocks are both transient and anticipated.7 Bias in some dynamic models of conflict might be due to omitted lags; see Beck and Katz (Citation2011). But in the greed models here, the estimated coefficient on lagged wages or lagged violence is zero, and does not affect the contemporaneous elasticity.8 This applies to types of commodities and production where insurgent groups are be able to tax production in the event their campaign is successful. Commodities with a benchmark world price studied in the literature are often easier to tax, given exports must pass through ports or through border crossings. But this is not universal. For example, Crost and Felter (Citation2020) find that higher world banana prices increase conflict and extortion by rebels in the Philippines only for large plantations, but not for small farmers.9 This is a good approximation of the “power form” of the contest function (Garfinkel and Skaperdas Citation2007, Equation 3) in a low-level insurgency where the strength of the government is large (and constant)–see Appendix 1. ϕ>1 ensures positive but diminishing marginal returns to fighting p′(Vt)>0,p″(Vt)<0.10 When ϕ→1 (weak opportunity cost mechanism), p(Vt) is very curved so when wages increase, violence barely needs to fall in order to increase p′(Vt) and make fighting more attractive. Conversely, when ϕ is very large (strong opportunity cost mechanism) p(Vt) is very flat, so when wages increase, violence has to fall substantially in order to increase p′(Vt) to make fighting more attractive to regain equilibrium.11 In this former case, let the price of domestic consumption goods be the numeraire and the international price of the commodity be θt, and assume that the volume of cash crops produced for export is Ltα . Then the amount of consumption goods that can be purchased is θtLtα.12 We abstract from any other costs of losing, like death, exile or imprisonment, which make the model more complicated. One could consider a more general setup with a fixed cost of losing, or where a losing insurgent is not able to work in the second period. The fixed cost from losing has little qualitative effect on our argument. Moreover, the inability to work in the second period actually strengthens the bias from persistent shocks, as a positive persistent shock that raises wages in t makes the value of winning (and hence working in t + 1) more valuable.13 The constant κ1=ϕlnψ(1−ϕ−1)+ϕlnδ. In Equation (5), κ2= ϕlnψ(1−ϕ−1)+ϕlnδ and κ3=(1−ρ)lnθ¯ and κ4=κ2+κ3−ϕlnα14 Fearon (Citation2008) and Chassang and Padró i Miquel (Citation2009) both argue that permanent changes in the level of economic development, or income, increase both the opportunity cost of violence and the spoils of war, leaving the level of violence unchanged, which we also find as ρ→1.15 This result (analytically and quantitatively) requires ψ, the efficiency of the fighting technology, to be adjusted to maintain the insurgency at only a low level so L≈1 (this is also the empirically relevant case, Fearon Citation2008).16 One might be concerned that seasonal or transient shocks might only have a small effect on wages or employment opportunities, as they are smoothed by employers. This seems unlikely in most cases, as employment in conflict-affected countries is typically informal, and informal employment lacks the binding long-term contracts that could isolate workers from changes in labor demand. One possible exception is “labor tying” arrangements in South Asia, but Mukherjee and Ray (Citation1995, 208) argue “the incidence of tying has undergone a steep secular decline to low current levels.” Drawing on de Janvry, Duquennois, and Sadoulet (Citation2022) and Guardado and Pennings (Citation2020), we report empirical evidence from Malawi and Iraq (respectively) that rural employment varies strongly with the seasons. See Appendix 3.1 for further discussion.17 As ρ→1 (more permanent), βOppMeas.→0, as in Proposition 1 above.18 i.e. βOppMeas.=−1.8 rather than βOppTrue=−3.19 The PIH states that only permanent changes in income should affect consumption (and transient shocks should be saved). Using data from Thailand, Paxson (Citation1993, 70) estimates how consumption varies with incomes across the seasons, and concludes that “the timing of income flows has little to do with the timing of [consumption] expenditure across seasons.”20 Appendix 2.3 includes a counterinsurgency information model of violence (motivated by Berman, Shapiro, and Felter Citation2011), which generates similar results through the same income-effect mechanism: a persistent increase in wages reduces violence directly, but also makes the agent richer, which makes passing-on counterinsurgency information for payment less attractive.\",\"PeriodicalId\":51513,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"International Interactions\",\"volume\":\"25 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":1.5000,\"publicationDate\":\"2023-10-13\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"International Interactions\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.1080/03050629.2023.2266553\",\"RegionNum\":3,\"RegionCategory\":\"社会学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q2\",\"JCRName\":\"INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"International Interactions","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/03050629.2023.2266553","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

注1例如,Dube和Vargas (Citation2013)发现,较高的咖啡价格降低了哥伦比亚的冲突强度,并且由于咖啡价格冲击通常相当持久,其结果可能比估计的还要强烈。究竟有多强很难计算,因为他们使用其他国家的出口(持续时间未知)来衡量咖啡价格冲击,而不是使用国际价格序列。Bazzi和Blattman (Citation2014)发现,所有商品类型的价格冲击都会降低冲突强度(他们的表7和表8)。由于这些是不同商品的捆绑,其持续时间也难以计算由于叛乱中兼职战士的比例很高(附录图3.2),我们的模型假设叛乱战士可以在工作和战斗之间自由转换。然而,在从战斗转向工作(或反之亦然)有大量固定成本的情况下,可能是机会成本机制本身对临时/季节性冲击的反应弱于对持续冲击的反应,在这些情况下,我们的理论可能不太适用在实际应用方面,研究人员需要注意(i)使用的瞬时/季节性冲击实际上会影响劳动力收入和战斗的机会成本(生长季节以外的降雨冲击可能不会),(ii)结果不会受到其他季节性变量(如温度和宗教节日)的混淆。Guardado和Pennings (Citation2020)通过利用不同国家在收获时间和强度上的差异来解决第二个问题,这使得他们可以在其规格中包括月份固定效应和温度控制为了简单起见,我们关注冲突强度,因为这是大宗商品价格冲击最有可能产生影响的地方,但也因为大多数叛乱是持久的,强度低(Fearon Citation2008)。冲击与冲突发生率或爆发之间的联系较弱(对大多数国家来说,这种联系接近于零)。这种关系也更加复杂,部分原因是冲击可以影响讨价还价,从而避免冲突的发生/发生(Chassang和Padró i Miquel Citation2009)。最近的实证文献强调了冲突开始(而不是强度)建模的复杂性:Malone (Citation2022)发现机会成本机制倾向于影响武装分子的形成而不是冲突的开始,Buhaug等人(Citation2021)发现干旱更有可能在种族群体最近降级的地区引发冲突或者,她也可以用相应的电击来衡量工资如果预期到冲击,它们也会使奖金的预期价值保持不变(EtΠt+1Prize),因为未来利润变化的价值已经被“定价”了(就像在股票市场中一样)。因此,使用预期冲击,机会成本机制的估计规模接近无偏,即使这些冲击是持续的,奖励的价值是未观察到的(结果可根据要求提供)。季节性冲击是暂时的和可预见的某些动态冲突模型中的偏差可能是由于忽略了滞后;参见Beck和Katz (Citation2011)。但在这里的贪婪模型中,滞后工资或滞后暴力的估计系数为零,并且不影响同期弹性这适用于某些商品和生产类型,叛乱组织可以在他们的行动成功的情况下对生产征税。鉴于出口必须通过港口或边境口岸,文献中研究的具有世界基准价格的商品往往更容易征税。但这并不普遍。例如,Crost和Felter (Citation2020)发现,世界香蕉价格上涨只会增加菲律宾大型种植园的冲突和叛乱分子的敲诈勒索,而对小农则没有影响这是一个很好的近似“权力形式”的竞争函数(Garfinkel和Skaperdas引文2007,方程3)在一个低水平的叛乱中,政府的力量是大的(和恒定的)-见附录1。ϕ>1确保战斗p ' (Vt)>0,p″(Vt)<0.10的积极但递减的边际收益当ϕ→1(弱机会成本机制)时,p (Vt)非常弯曲,因此当工资增加时,暴力几乎不需要下降,以增加p ' (Vt)并使战斗更具吸引力。相反,当ϕ非常大(强机会成本机制)时,p(Vt)非常平坦,因此当工资增加时,暴力必须大幅下降,以增加p ' (Vt),使战斗更有吸引力以恢复平衡在前一种情况下,设国内消费品的价格为数数,商品的国际价格为θt,并假设用于出口的经济作物产量为Ltα。那么可以购买的消费品的数量为θtLtα。 我们不考虑任何其他损失的代价,如死亡、流放或监禁,这使模型更加复杂。我们可以考虑一个更一般的设定,设定一个固定的损失成本,或者一个失败的叛乱分子在第二阶段无法工作。失败的固定成本对我们的论点几乎没有什么定性影响。此外,在第二阶段无法工作实际上加强了持续冲击的偏见,因为积极的持续冲击提高了t中的工资,使获胜的价值(因此在t + 1中工作)更有价值常数κ1= φ(1−φ−1)+ φ(1−φ)。在式(5)中,κ2= lnψ(1−φ−1)+ lnδ和κ3=(1−ρ)lnθ¯和κ4= 2+ 3−lnα14 Fearon (Citation2008)和Chassang和Padró i Miquel (Citation2009)都认为,经济发展水平或收入水平的永久变化增加了暴力的机会成本和战利品,使暴力水平不变,我们也发现ρ→1.15这个结果(分析和定量)需要ψ,战斗技术的效率,为了将叛乱维持在较低的水平,所以L≈1(这也是与经验相关的案例,Fearon Citation2008)人们可能会担心,季节性或短暂的冲击可能只对工资或就业机会产生很小的影响,因为雇主会消除这些影响。在大多数情况下,这似乎不太可能,因为受冲突影响国家的就业通常是非正式的,而非正式就业缺乏具有约束力的长期合同,可能使工人与劳动力需求的变化隔绝开来。一个可能的例外是南亚的“劳动力捆绑”安排,但Mukherjee和Ray (citation1995,208)认为“捆绑的发生率已经经历了急剧的长期下降到目前的低水平。”利用de Janvry、Duquennois和Sadoulet (Citation2022)以及Guardado和Pennings (Citation2020),我们报告了马拉维和伊拉克(分别)的经验证据,表明农村就业随季节变化很大。进一步的讨论见附录3.1当ρ→1(更持久)时,β oppmeans。→0,如上面的命题1。18即βOppMeas.=−1.8而不是βOppTrue=−3.19 PIH指出,只有收入的永久变化才会影响消费(应避免短暂的冲击)。Paxson (citation1993,70)利用泰国的数据估计了不同季节的消费随收入的变化情况,并得出结论:“收入流动的时间与不同季节[消费]支出的时间关系不大。20附录2.3包含了一个暴力的反叛乱信息模型(由Berman、Shapiro和Felter Citation2011提出),该模型通过相同的收入效应机制产生了类似的结果:工资的持续增长直接减少了暴力,但也使代理人更富有,这使得传递反叛乱信息以获得报酬的吸引力降低。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
Shock Persistence and the Study of Armed Conflict: Empirical Biases and Some Remedies
AbstractPoor employment prospects for potential insurgents are often thought to increase the intensity of armed conflict. A large empirical literature tries to identify the strength of this “opportunity cost” channel, in part by regressing conflict on commodity price shocks that affect the demand for workers. In this research note we develop a theoretical framework to interpret these empirical results. We argue that because commodity price shocks are usually persistent, the estimated strength of the opportunity cost mechanism will be biased upwards (towards zero)—even for labor-intensive commodities whose price shocks are not permanent. We define this bias analytically and, using regressions on simulated data, show that it is quantitatively important for commodities studied in the literature. The bias occurs because persistent shocks that reduce employment prospects today are correlated with unobserved dynamic motivations to fight, such as the expected value of an oil field or a fighter’s subjective value of a grievance. We conclude that the opportunity cost mechanism may be even stronger than has been estimated, and that researchers should use transient, seasonal or anticipated shocks to identify its magnitude.Con frecuencia, se tiene la tendencia a pensar que el hecho de que los potenciales insurgentes tengan unas expectativas pobres en materia de empleabilidad contribuye a aumentar la intensidad de los conflictos armados. Existe una amplia bibliografía, de carácter empírico, que trata de identificar la fortaleza de este canal de «coste de oportunidad». Esto, lo hace, en parte, mediante la regresión del conflicto con respecto a las perturbaciones en materia de precios de los productos básicos, las cuales afectan la demanda de trabajadores. En esta nota de investigación, desarrollamos un marco teórico para interpretar estos resultados empíricos. Argumentamos que, debido a que las perturbaciones en materia de precios de los productos básicos suelen ser persistentes, la fortaleza estimada del mecanismo de coste de oportunidad estará sesgada al alza (hacia cero), incluso para aquellos productos básicos intensivos en mano de obra para los cuales las perturbaciones en materia de precios no resultan permanentes. Definimos este sesgo de forma analítica y demostramos, mediante el uso de regresiones en datos simulados, que este resulta cuantitativamente importante para los productos estudiados en la bibliografía. El sesgo se produce porque los cambios persistentes que contribuyen, actualmente, a reducir las perspectivas de empleo se correlacionan con motivaciones dinámicas para luchar que no han sido tenidas en cuenta, como el valor esperado de un campo petrolero o el valor subjetivo que un combatiente otorga a un agravio. Concluimos que el mecanismo de coste de oportunidad puede ser incluso más fuerte de lo que se había estimado, y que los investigadores deben usar perturbaciones transitorias o estacionales para poder identificar su magnitud.Des perspectives d’emploi médiocres pour les rebelles potentiels intensifieraient souvent les conflits armés. Une abondante littérature empirique tente d’identifier la force de ce canal de « coût d’opportunité », en partie en remontant le conflit jusqu’à une crise des prix des matières premières qui a une incidence sur la demande de travailleurs. Dans cette note de recherche, nous développons un cadre théorique pour interpréter ces résultats empiriques. Nous affirmons que puisque les crises des prix des matières premières sont généralement de longue durée, l’estimation de la force du mécanisme coût-opportunité sera haussière (vers zéro), même pour les marchandises intensives en travail dont les crises de prix ne sont pas permanentes. Nous définissons ce biais sur le plan analytique et, à l’aide de régressions à partir de données simulées, nous montrons son importance quantitative pour les matières premières étudiées dans la littérature. Le biais intervient quand des crises persistantes qui réduisent les perspectives d’emploi aujourd’hui sont corrélées à des motifs de conflit dynamiques, comme la valeur attendue d’un champ pétrolifère ou la valeur subjective qu’un combattant accorde à un grief. La conclusion indique que l’importance du mécanisme coût-opportunité pourrait bien être plus élevée que nos estimations, et suggère aux chercheurs d’utiliser des crises passagères ou saisonnières pour identifier son ampleur.Keywords: Commodity price shocksconflictopportunity cost mechanismJEL: D74O13Q34 AcknowledgmentWe thank the editor, two anonymous referees, and participants at various conferences and seminars for helpful comments.Disclosure statementThe views expressed here are the authors’ and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank, its executive directors, or the countries they represent.Notes1 For example, Dube and Vargas (Citation2013) find that higher coffee prices reduce conflict intensity in Colombia and, as coffee price shocks are typically fairly persistent, their results might be even stronger than estimated. Exactly how much stronger is difficult to calculate as they instrument coffee price shocks using other country’s exports (which have an unknown persistence), rather than using the international price series. Bazzi and Blattman (Citation2014) find that price shocks for all commodity types reduce conflict intensity (their Tables 7 and 8). As these are bundles of different commodities, its persistence is also difficult to calculate.2 Motivated by the high fraction of part-time fighters in insurgencies (Appendix Figure 3.2), our model assumes insurgent fighters can transition freely between working and fighting. However, in contexts where there are substantial fixed costs of moving from fighting to working (or vice-versa), it could be that the opportunity cost mechanism itself is weaker in response to temporary/seasonal shocks than persistent shocks, and in those contexts our theory may be less applicable.3 In terms of practical application, researchers need to be careful that (i) the transient/seasonal shocks used actually affect labor incomes and the opportunity cost of fighting (rainfall shocks outside the growing season may not), and (ii) results are not confounded by other seasonal variables, such as temperature and religious festivals. Guardado and Pennings (Citation2020) get around the second problem by utilizing subnational variation in the timing and intensity of harvest, which allows them to include month fixed effects and temperature controls in their specification.4 We focus on conflict intensity for simplicity, because that is where commodity price shocks are most likely to have an effect, but also because most insurgencies are long-lasting with low intensity (Fearon Citation2008). The connection between shocks and conflict incidence or onset is weaker (and is close to zero for most countries). The relation is also more complex, in part because shocks can affect bargaining which staves off conflict onset/incidence (Chassang and Padró i Miquel Citation2009). A recent empirical literature has emphasized the complexity of modeling conflict onset (rather than intensity): Malone (Citation2022) finds the opportunity cost mechanism tends to affect militant formation rather than conflict onset and Buhaug et al. (Citation2021) find that droughts are more likely to start a conflict in areas with a recently downgraded ethnic group.5 Alternatively, she might instrument the wage with a relevant shock.6 If shocks are anticipated, they will also leave the expected value of the prize (EtΠt+1Prize) unchanged—because the value of the changes in future profits have already been “priced in” (as in the stock market). Hence the estimated size of the opportunity cost mechanism is close to being unbiased using anticipated shocks, even when those shocks are persistent and the value of the prize is unobserved (results available upon request). Seasonal shocks are both transient and anticipated.7 Bias in some dynamic models of conflict might be due to omitted lags; see Beck and Katz (Citation2011). But in the greed models here, the estimated coefficient on lagged wages or lagged violence is zero, and does not affect the contemporaneous elasticity.8 This applies to types of commodities and production where insurgent groups are be able to tax production in the event their campaign is successful. Commodities with a benchmark world price studied in the literature are often easier to tax, given exports must pass through ports or through border crossings. But this is not universal. For example, Crost and Felter (Citation2020) find that higher world banana prices increase conflict and extortion by rebels in the Philippines only for large plantations, but not for small farmers.9 This is a good approximation of the “power form” of the contest function (Garfinkel and Skaperdas Citation2007, Equation 3) in a low-level insurgency where the strength of the government is large (and constant)–see Appendix 1. ϕ>1 ensures positive but diminishing marginal returns to fighting p′(Vt)>0,p″(Vt)<0.10 When ϕ→1 (weak opportunity cost mechanism), p(Vt) is very curved so when wages increase, violence barely needs to fall in order to increase p′(Vt) and make fighting more attractive. Conversely, when ϕ is very large (strong opportunity cost mechanism) p(Vt) is very flat, so when wages increase, violence has to fall substantially in order to increase p′(Vt) to make fighting more attractive to regain equilibrium.11 In this former case, let the price of domestic consumption goods be the numeraire and the international price of the commodity be θt, and assume that the volume of cash crops produced for export is Ltα . Then the amount of consumption goods that can be purchased is θtLtα.12 We abstract from any other costs of losing, like death, exile or imprisonment, which make the model more complicated. One could consider a more general setup with a fixed cost of losing, or where a losing insurgent is not able to work in the second period. The fixed cost from losing has little qualitative effect on our argument. Moreover, the inability to work in the second period actually strengthens the bias from persistent shocks, as a positive persistent shock that raises wages in t makes the value of winning (and hence working in t + 1) more valuable.13 The constant κ1=ϕlnψ(1−ϕ−1)+ϕlnδ. In Equation (5), κ2= ϕlnψ(1−ϕ−1)+ϕlnδ and κ3=(1−ρ)lnθ¯ and κ4=κ2+κ3−ϕlnα14 Fearon (Citation2008) and Chassang and Padró i Miquel (Citation2009) both argue that permanent changes in the level of economic development, or income, increase both the opportunity cost of violence and the spoils of war, leaving the level of violence unchanged, which we also find as ρ→1.15 This result (analytically and quantitatively) requires ψ, the efficiency of the fighting technology, to be adjusted to maintain the insurgency at only a low level so L≈1 (this is also the empirically relevant case, Fearon Citation2008).16 One might be concerned that seasonal or transient shocks might only have a small effect on wages or employment opportunities, as they are smoothed by employers. This seems unlikely in most cases, as employment in conflict-affected countries is typically informal, and informal employment lacks the binding long-term contracts that could isolate workers from changes in labor demand. One possible exception is “labor tying” arrangements in South Asia, but Mukherjee and Ray (Citation1995, 208) argue “the incidence of tying has undergone a steep secular decline to low current levels.” Drawing on de Janvry, Duquennois, and Sadoulet (Citation2022) and Guardado and Pennings (Citation2020), we report empirical evidence from Malawi and Iraq (respectively) that rural employment varies strongly with the seasons. See Appendix 3.1 for further discussion.17 As ρ→1 (more permanent), βOppMeas.→0, as in Proposition 1 above.18 i.e. βOppMeas.=−1.8 rather than βOppTrue=−3.19 The PIH states that only permanent changes in income should affect consumption (and transient shocks should be saved). Using data from Thailand, Paxson (Citation1993, 70) estimates how consumption varies with incomes across the seasons, and concludes that “the timing of income flows has little to do with the timing of [consumption] expenditure across seasons.”20 Appendix 2.3 includes a counterinsurgency information model of violence (motivated by Berman, Shapiro, and Felter Citation2011), which generates similar results through the same income-effect mechanism: a persistent increase in wages reduces violence directly, but also makes the agent richer, which makes passing-on counterinsurgency information for payment less attractive.
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
International Interactions
International Interactions INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS-
CiteScore
2.40
自引率
7.70%
发文量
38
期刊介绍: International Interactions is a leading interdisciplinary journal that publishes original empirical, analytic, and theoretical studies of conflict and political economy. The journal has a particular interest in research that focuses upon the broad range of relations and interactions among the actors in the global system. Relevant topics include ethnic and religious conflict, interstate and intrastate conflict, conflict resolution, conflict management, economic development, regional integration, trade relations, institutions, globalization, terrorism, and geopolitical analyses.
期刊最新文献
Demographic Consequences of Major Wars Bombs and Banners: Battlefield Dynamics and Armed Groups’ Use of Nonviolent Tactics in Civil War Climate Harshness, Opportunity, and Environmental Violence Sequencing the Steps to War Corrupting the Battlefield: How Corruption Influences Belligerents’ Battlefield Performance
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1