自主需求增长和金融反馈的组成部分:对增长驱动因素和增长机制分析的影响

IF 1.2 Q3 ECONOMICS REVIEW OF POLITICAL ECONOMY Pub Date : 2023-11-02 DOI:10.1080/09538259.2023.2269369
Ryan Woodgate, Eckhard Hein, Ricardo Summa
{"title":"自主需求增长和金融反馈的组成部分:对增长驱动因素和增长机制分析的影响","authors":"Ryan Woodgate, Eckhard Hein, Ricardo Summa","doi":"10.1080/09538259.2023.2269369","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTThis paper presents a simple closed-economy model that is driven by the growth of two autonomous components of demand, namely government spending and rentiers’ consumption out of interest income. Using this model, it seeks to make two contributions. First, by focusing on the financial dynamics that arise from debt-financed government spending, we show that an underlying stock-flow interaction provides an endogenous mechanism which, under certain conditions, aligns the two autonomous growth rates in the long run. Hence, an economy can be driven by two autonomous components of demand, without one dominating the other in the long-run nor without policy changes being required to align the two growth drivers. Second, we prove that if two autonomous demand components are dynamically interdependent, then the relative size of their growth contributions may be misleading as a guide to classify growth regimes, both in the long-run equilibrium as well as during the traverse towards this equilibrium. Furthermore, we show that the relative growth contributions are economic policy contingent. We thus argue that interdependencies between autonomous growth components arising from financial stock-flow interactions should not be ignored in Sraffian supermultiplier growth decomposition exercises that aim to identify underlying growth drivers.KEYWORDS: Sraffian supermultiplier and endogenous credittwo autonomous growth driversdemand-led growth accountinggrowth regimesJEL CODE: E11E12E20E62 AcknowledgementsWe would like to use this opportunity to acknowledge and thank the reviewers who reviewed this article and aided in its publication.Disclosure StatementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 See Cesaratto (Citation2017), Cesaratto and Di Bucchianico (Citation2020), and Cesaratto and Pariboni (Citation2022) for detailed accounts of the close relationship between autonomous demand-led growth and post-Keynesian monetary circuit and endogenous money theory. In this context, Cesaratto and Pariboni (Citation2022, 306) also point out the close relationship of Sraffian supermultiplier models with Kalecki’s notion that external markets created by government deficits and export surpluses are drivers of growth: ‘The autonomous components of aggregate demand, which in the supermultiplier model drive growth and coincide with Kalecki-Luxemburg’s external markets, can be financed by purchasing power creation by banks, by accumulated wealth or foreign income. … By definition, external markets are fueled by debt creation, and the seed of financial instability and crisis can be traced here.’2 For a stock-flow supermultiplier model with two debt-financed autonomous expenditures (autonomous government and household consumption), and interrelations between sectoral autonomous demand growth and sectoral indebtedness, with possible emergence of financial fragility processes, see Pedrosa, Brochier, and Freitas (Citation2023).3 We do not mention government expenditure here, because we hold that in sovereign money economies, governments do not have to pre-fund their expenditures, although policy makers may have imposed some policy rules (government debt ceilings, debt brakes, balanced budgets etc.) which may impose a constraint on government expenditures, which may then interact with other autonomous expenditure components. In countries without sovereign money, government expenditures would have to be mentioned here, too.4 Freitas and Christianes (Citation2020) have two autonomous growth rates (government expenditures and capitalist consumption), but just assume that the two will be equal in the long run, without discussing their interaction. Brochier and Macedo e Silva (Citation2019) have presented an autonomous demand-led stock-flow consistent growth model driven by consumption out of wealth, with wealth being endogenous in the long run. They thus include financial issues, but only have one autonomous growth rate which is endogenous.5 In the journal version of his paper, Allain (Citation2022) has abandoned the distinction between ‘active’ and ‘passive’ components of autonomous demand in favour of ‘autonomous’ and ‘semi-autonomous’ demand components. He thus follows Fiebiger (Citation2018, 2020) and Lavoie and Fiebiger (2019), who have argued that ‘semi-autonomous’ may be a better terminology to indicate the independence of parts of demand from income generated in current production, which may be, nonetheless, through some other mechanism be related to the dynamics of production in the long run. They refer to Kalecki (Citation1968, 265–269), who is using ‘semi-autonomous’ for the autonomous part of capitalists’ consumption, and the effect of technical change and innovations on investment.6 For simplifying purposes, we are not considering class distinctions and its consequences for different propensities to consume. Therefore, we also do not explore the possible effect of different propensities to consume out of different income streams.7 Hence, this paper makes no further claims about the effects of changes of c nor i on demand and output.8 We ignore the trivial solutions where the long-run equilibrium values are zero.9 This has consequences for the level of output in the steady state (Equation 4), as a higher propensity to invest increases the level of output.10 See Freitas and Serrano (Citation2015, 14), who also elaborate on the interpretation of this stability condition. A similar stability condition is found in, for example, Hein and Woodgate (Citation2021) and Morlin (Citation2022).11 For an assessment of the empirical plausibility of the stability conditions (18) and (19) for the case of the United States, see respectively, Blanchard (Citation2019) and Haluska, Braga, and Summa (Citation2021).12 The level of disaggregation of autonomous components can be even more detailed, e.g., with the distinction between government consumption and investment, investment by state-owned enterprises, business investment in R&D, and consumption out of public transfers and public wages (Labat and Summa Citation2023). However, in none of the papers of the SSM demand-led growth accounting literature the consumption out of interest on public debt is included. We believe that empirically estimating this latter effect and including it in demand-led decompositions exercises for different countries, to check its contribution to growth, should be a desirable future development of this research agenda.13 We are simplifying the story, because exports can also be included as a second active autonomous driver for the Spanish economy.14 This is, of course, just a simplified stylized story, as autonomous consumption out of credit and residential investment can be included as important active autonomous drivers in the Brazilian case, too.15 Though it is, of course, possible that decreases in γ and/or increases in i may not be sufficient in size to change the dominant growth contribution. Though not illustrated here, one could equally examine the opposite cases wherein the policy shock is a rise in γ and/or fall ini. Unsurprisingly, the result in the post-shock period is, in qualitative terms, the mirror image of what is depicted in Figure 2, i.e. a rising government spending-debt ratio ρ, lower threshold value d, higher (and rising) growth contributions of government spending, as well as lower (and falling) growth contribution of autonomous expenditure.","PeriodicalId":46174,"journal":{"name":"REVIEW OF POLITICAL ECONOMY","volume":"99 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":1.2000,"publicationDate":"2023-11-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"1","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Components of Autonomous Demand Growth and Financial Feedbacks: Implications for Growth Drivers and Growth Regime Analysis\",\"authors\":\"Ryan Woodgate, Eckhard Hein, Ricardo Summa\",\"doi\":\"10.1080/09538259.2023.2269369\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"ABSTRACTThis paper presents a simple closed-economy model that is driven by the growth of two autonomous components of demand, namely government spending and rentiers’ consumption out of interest income. Using this model, it seeks to make two contributions. First, by focusing on the financial dynamics that arise from debt-financed government spending, we show that an underlying stock-flow interaction provides an endogenous mechanism which, under certain conditions, aligns the two autonomous growth rates in the long run. Hence, an economy can be driven by two autonomous components of demand, without one dominating the other in the long-run nor without policy changes being required to align the two growth drivers. Second, we prove that if two autonomous demand components are dynamically interdependent, then the relative size of their growth contributions may be misleading as a guide to classify growth regimes, both in the long-run equilibrium as well as during the traverse towards this equilibrium. Furthermore, we show that the relative growth contributions are economic policy contingent. We thus argue that interdependencies between autonomous growth components arising from financial stock-flow interactions should not be ignored in Sraffian supermultiplier growth decomposition exercises that aim to identify underlying growth drivers.KEYWORDS: Sraffian supermultiplier and endogenous credittwo autonomous growth driversdemand-led growth accountinggrowth regimesJEL CODE: E11E12E20E62 AcknowledgementsWe would like to use this opportunity to acknowledge and thank the reviewers who reviewed this article and aided in its publication.Disclosure StatementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 See Cesaratto (Citation2017), Cesaratto and Di Bucchianico (Citation2020), and Cesaratto and Pariboni (Citation2022) for detailed accounts of the close relationship between autonomous demand-led growth and post-Keynesian monetary circuit and endogenous money theory. In this context, Cesaratto and Pariboni (Citation2022, 306) also point out the close relationship of Sraffian supermultiplier models with Kalecki’s notion that external markets created by government deficits and export surpluses are drivers of growth: ‘The autonomous components of aggregate demand, which in the supermultiplier model drive growth and coincide with Kalecki-Luxemburg’s external markets, can be financed by purchasing power creation by banks, by accumulated wealth or foreign income. … By definition, external markets are fueled by debt creation, and the seed of financial instability and crisis can be traced here.’2 For a stock-flow supermultiplier model with two debt-financed autonomous expenditures (autonomous government and household consumption), and interrelations between sectoral autonomous demand growth and sectoral indebtedness, with possible emergence of financial fragility processes, see Pedrosa, Brochier, and Freitas (Citation2023).3 We do not mention government expenditure here, because we hold that in sovereign money economies, governments do not have to pre-fund their expenditures, although policy makers may have imposed some policy rules (government debt ceilings, debt brakes, balanced budgets etc.) which may impose a constraint on government expenditures, which may then interact with other autonomous expenditure components. In countries without sovereign money, government expenditures would have to be mentioned here, too.4 Freitas and Christianes (Citation2020) have two autonomous growth rates (government expenditures and capitalist consumption), but just assume that the two will be equal in the long run, without discussing their interaction. Brochier and Macedo e Silva (Citation2019) have presented an autonomous demand-led stock-flow consistent growth model driven by consumption out of wealth, with wealth being endogenous in the long run. They thus include financial issues, but only have one autonomous growth rate which is endogenous.5 In the journal version of his paper, Allain (Citation2022) has abandoned the distinction between ‘active’ and ‘passive’ components of autonomous demand in favour of ‘autonomous’ and ‘semi-autonomous’ demand components. He thus follows Fiebiger (Citation2018, 2020) and Lavoie and Fiebiger (2019), who have argued that ‘semi-autonomous’ may be a better terminology to indicate the independence of parts of demand from income generated in current production, which may be, nonetheless, through some other mechanism be related to the dynamics of production in the long run. They refer to Kalecki (Citation1968, 265–269), who is using ‘semi-autonomous’ for the autonomous part of capitalists’ consumption, and the effect of technical change and innovations on investment.6 For simplifying purposes, we are not considering class distinctions and its consequences for different propensities to consume. Therefore, we also do not explore the possible effect of different propensities to consume out of different income streams.7 Hence, this paper makes no further claims about the effects of changes of c nor i on demand and output.8 We ignore the trivial solutions where the long-run equilibrium values are zero.9 This has consequences for the level of output in the steady state (Equation 4), as a higher propensity to invest increases the level of output.10 See Freitas and Serrano (Citation2015, 14), who also elaborate on the interpretation of this stability condition. A similar stability condition is found in, for example, Hein and Woodgate (Citation2021) and Morlin (Citation2022).11 For an assessment of the empirical plausibility of the stability conditions (18) and (19) for the case of the United States, see respectively, Blanchard (Citation2019) and Haluska, Braga, and Summa (Citation2021).12 The level of disaggregation of autonomous components can be even more detailed, e.g., with the distinction between government consumption and investment, investment by state-owned enterprises, business investment in R&D, and consumption out of public transfers and public wages (Labat and Summa Citation2023). However, in none of the papers of the SSM demand-led growth accounting literature the consumption out of interest on public debt is included. We believe that empirically estimating this latter effect and including it in demand-led decompositions exercises for different countries, to check its contribution to growth, should be a desirable future development of this research agenda.13 We are simplifying the story, because exports can also be included as a second active autonomous driver for the Spanish economy.14 This is, of course, just a simplified stylized story, as autonomous consumption out of credit and residential investment can be included as important active autonomous drivers in the Brazilian case, too.15 Though it is, of course, possible that decreases in γ and/or increases in i may not be sufficient in size to change the dominant growth contribution. Though not illustrated here, one could equally examine the opposite cases wherein the policy shock is a rise in γ and/or fall ini. Unsurprisingly, the result in the post-shock period is, in qualitative terms, the mirror image of what is depicted in Figure 2, i.e. a rising government spending-debt ratio ρ, lower threshold value d, higher (and rising) growth contributions of government spending, as well as lower (and falling) growth contribution of autonomous expenditure.\",\"PeriodicalId\":46174,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"REVIEW OF POLITICAL ECONOMY\",\"volume\":\"99 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":1.2000,\"publicationDate\":\"2023-11-02\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"1\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"REVIEW OF POLITICAL ECONOMY\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.1080/09538259.2023.2269369\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q3\",\"JCRName\":\"ECONOMICS\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"REVIEW OF POLITICAL ECONOMY","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/09538259.2023.2269369","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q3","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

摘要

因此,我们也没有探讨不同收入流的不同消费倾向可能产生的影响因此,本文没有进一步说明c和i的变化对需求和产出的影响我们忽略长期均衡值为0的平凡解这对稳定状态下的产出水平产生了影响(公式4),因为较高的投资倾向增加了产出水平参见Freitas和Serrano (Citation2015, 14),他们也详细解释了这种稳定性条件。例如,Hein和Woodgate (Citation2021)以及Morlin (Citation2022)也发现了类似的稳定性条件对于美国情况下稳定性条件(18)和(19)的经验合理性评估,分别参见Blanchard (Citation2019)和Haluska, Braga和Summa (Citation2021)自主成分的分解水平可以更详细,例如,区分政府消费和投资、国有企业投资、企业研发投资以及公共转移和公共工资消费(Labat和Summa Citation2023)。然而,在SSM的需求导向增长会计文献中,没有一篇论文包括公共债务利息消费。我们认为,经验性地估计后一种影响,并将其纳入不同国家的需求主导的分解工作,以检查其对增长的贡献,应该是本研究议程的理想未来发展我们正在简化这个故事,因为出口也可以作为西班牙经济的第二个主动自动驱动因素当然,这只是一个简化的风格化的故事,因为在巴西的案例中,信贷和住宅投资之外的自主消费也可以被视为重要的主动自主驱动因素当然,γ的减少和/或i的增加可能不足以改变主要的生长贡献。虽然这里没有说明,但人们可以同样地研究相反的情况,其中政策冲击是γ的上升和/或下降。不出所料,冲击后时期的结果,在定性方面,是图2所示的镜像,即上升的政府支出-债务比率ρ,较低的阈值d,较高(和上升)的政府支出的增长贡献,以及较低(和下降)的自主支出的增长贡献。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
Components of Autonomous Demand Growth and Financial Feedbacks: Implications for Growth Drivers and Growth Regime Analysis
ABSTRACTThis paper presents a simple closed-economy model that is driven by the growth of two autonomous components of demand, namely government spending and rentiers’ consumption out of interest income. Using this model, it seeks to make two contributions. First, by focusing on the financial dynamics that arise from debt-financed government spending, we show that an underlying stock-flow interaction provides an endogenous mechanism which, under certain conditions, aligns the two autonomous growth rates in the long run. Hence, an economy can be driven by two autonomous components of demand, without one dominating the other in the long-run nor without policy changes being required to align the two growth drivers. Second, we prove that if two autonomous demand components are dynamically interdependent, then the relative size of their growth contributions may be misleading as a guide to classify growth regimes, both in the long-run equilibrium as well as during the traverse towards this equilibrium. Furthermore, we show that the relative growth contributions are economic policy contingent. We thus argue that interdependencies between autonomous growth components arising from financial stock-flow interactions should not be ignored in Sraffian supermultiplier growth decomposition exercises that aim to identify underlying growth drivers.KEYWORDS: Sraffian supermultiplier and endogenous credittwo autonomous growth driversdemand-led growth accountinggrowth regimesJEL CODE: E11E12E20E62 AcknowledgementsWe would like to use this opportunity to acknowledge and thank the reviewers who reviewed this article and aided in its publication.Disclosure StatementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 See Cesaratto (Citation2017), Cesaratto and Di Bucchianico (Citation2020), and Cesaratto and Pariboni (Citation2022) for detailed accounts of the close relationship between autonomous demand-led growth and post-Keynesian monetary circuit and endogenous money theory. In this context, Cesaratto and Pariboni (Citation2022, 306) also point out the close relationship of Sraffian supermultiplier models with Kalecki’s notion that external markets created by government deficits and export surpluses are drivers of growth: ‘The autonomous components of aggregate demand, which in the supermultiplier model drive growth and coincide with Kalecki-Luxemburg’s external markets, can be financed by purchasing power creation by banks, by accumulated wealth or foreign income. … By definition, external markets are fueled by debt creation, and the seed of financial instability and crisis can be traced here.’2 For a stock-flow supermultiplier model with two debt-financed autonomous expenditures (autonomous government and household consumption), and interrelations between sectoral autonomous demand growth and sectoral indebtedness, with possible emergence of financial fragility processes, see Pedrosa, Brochier, and Freitas (Citation2023).3 We do not mention government expenditure here, because we hold that in sovereign money economies, governments do not have to pre-fund their expenditures, although policy makers may have imposed some policy rules (government debt ceilings, debt brakes, balanced budgets etc.) which may impose a constraint on government expenditures, which may then interact with other autonomous expenditure components. In countries without sovereign money, government expenditures would have to be mentioned here, too.4 Freitas and Christianes (Citation2020) have two autonomous growth rates (government expenditures and capitalist consumption), but just assume that the two will be equal in the long run, without discussing their interaction. Brochier and Macedo e Silva (Citation2019) have presented an autonomous demand-led stock-flow consistent growth model driven by consumption out of wealth, with wealth being endogenous in the long run. They thus include financial issues, but only have one autonomous growth rate which is endogenous.5 In the journal version of his paper, Allain (Citation2022) has abandoned the distinction between ‘active’ and ‘passive’ components of autonomous demand in favour of ‘autonomous’ and ‘semi-autonomous’ demand components. He thus follows Fiebiger (Citation2018, 2020) and Lavoie and Fiebiger (2019), who have argued that ‘semi-autonomous’ may be a better terminology to indicate the independence of parts of demand from income generated in current production, which may be, nonetheless, through some other mechanism be related to the dynamics of production in the long run. They refer to Kalecki (Citation1968, 265–269), who is using ‘semi-autonomous’ for the autonomous part of capitalists’ consumption, and the effect of technical change and innovations on investment.6 For simplifying purposes, we are not considering class distinctions and its consequences for different propensities to consume. Therefore, we also do not explore the possible effect of different propensities to consume out of different income streams.7 Hence, this paper makes no further claims about the effects of changes of c nor i on demand and output.8 We ignore the trivial solutions where the long-run equilibrium values are zero.9 This has consequences for the level of output in the steady state (Equation 4), as a higher propensity to invest increases the level of output.10 See Freitas and Serrano (Citation2015, 14), who also elaborate on the interpretation of this stability condition. A similar stability condition is found in, for example, Hein and Woodgate (Citation2021) and Morlin (Citation2022).11 For an assessment of the empirical plausibility of the stability conditions (18) and (19) for the case of the United States, see respectively, Blanchard (Citation2019) and Haluska, Braga, and Summa (Citation2021).12 The level of disaggregation of autonomous components can be even more detailed, e.g., with the distinction between government consumption and investment, investment by state-owned enterprises, business investment in R&D, and consumption out of public transfers and public wages (Labat and Summa Citation2023). However, in none of the papers of the SSM demand-led growth accounting literature the consumption out of interest on public debt is included. We believe that empirically estimating this latter effect and including it in demand-led decompositions exercises for different countries, to check its contribution to growth, should be a desirable future development of this research agenda.13 We are simplifying the story, because exports can also be included as a second active autonomous driver for the Spanish economy.14 This is, of course, just a simplified stylized story, as autonomous consumption out of credit and residential investment can be included as important active autonomous drivers in the Brazilian case, too.15 Though it is, of course, possible that decreases in γ and/or increases in i may not be sufficient in size to change the dominant growth contribution. Though not illustrated here, one could equally examine the opposite cases wherein the policy shock is a rise in γ and/or fall ini. Unsurprisingly, the result in the post-shock period is, in qualitative terms, the mirror image of what is depicted in Figure 2, i.e. a rising government spending-debt ratio ρ, lower threshold value d, higher (and rising) growth contributions of government spending, as well as lower (and falling) growth contribution of autonomous expenditure.
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
2.60
自引率
20.00%
发文量
0
期刊介绍: The Review of Political Economy is a peer-reviewed journal welcoming constructive and critical contributions in all areas of political economy, including the Austrian, Behavioral Economics, Feminist Economics, Institutionalist, Marxian, Post Keynesian, and Sraffian traditions. The Review publishes both theoretical and empirical research, and is also open to submissions in methodology, economic history and the history of economic thought that cast light on issues of contemporary relevance in political economy. Comments on articles published in the Review are encouraged.
期刊最新文献
The Currency of Politics: The Political Theory of Money from Aristotle to Keynes The Monetary Theory of Production and the Supermultiplier: What Determines Savings? Revisiting the Pasinetti Index: Understanding Its Cyclical and Long-Term Features and Its Important Implications for Macroeconomic Policy Blurring Boundaries: An Analysis of the Digital Platforms-Military Nexus Public Investment as a Source of Capacity-Creating Autonomous Demand: Implications for Growth and Stability
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1