重新思考经济主权

IF 1.2 4区 社会学 Q2 ANTHROPOLOGY Economic Anthropology Pub Date : 2024-01-15 DOI:10.1002/sea2.12302
Leon Wansleben
{"title":"重新思考经济主权","authors":"Leon Wansleben","doi":"10.1002/sea2.12302","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>In his broad and compelling essay “The Rise and Fall of National Capitalism,” Keith Hart offers an alternative interpretation and periodization of global capitalist order that diverges from standard distinctions into prewar, postwar (Keynesian/progressive), and neoliberal eras. Hart's core claim is that, in the Second Industrial Revolution, a strong nexus between mass industrial capitalism and state power was forged. This nexus gradually loosened and now dissolves. Sovereign all-purpose money—money that links the financial sector with public debt and taxation, as well as national payment infrastructures—has been an important building block of “national capitalisms,” and its diminishing role indicates the latter's demise. The essay does not present one concise explanation of this development but rather engages with diverse themes, from neoliberal policies and ideology to “lawless global money circuits” to the power of transnational corporations to the digital revolution to secular stagnation in advanced economies (with a concomitant shift from productivist to rent-extracting capital accumulation). I have difficulties at times following Hart's precise argument with regard to each of the causal drivers. In many cases, the essay relies on explanations developed in more depth elsewhere in the author's work. For these reasons, I take the liberty to focus solely on the main descriptive claim, namely, that we have been living in national capitalisms that are about to disappear, with potentially catastrophic consequences.</p><p>A significant first question left unanswered by this essay concerns the linkage between national capitalisms, to the extent that they have come into existence, and the global order. Clearly, Hart sees this order as imperialist, with the United States as the hegemon since the turn of the 20th century. Indeed, as other authors have stressed, global monetary and financial structures, even more so than military and security structures, support this empire. The dollar is by far the globally dominant currency, used not only in most trade but even more so in financial transactions. The collapse of Bretton Woods institutions, and again the financial crisis of 2008, have not challenged but rather reinforced this hegemony. But if we have been living in imperialist global orders all the way through, this raises interesting questions about national capitalism. Clearly American imperialism has supported such capitalisms in some regions and some periods. In particular, dollar hegemony has facilitated the reemergence of national capitalisms in Europe after the Second World War by generating the institutions, necessary demand, and liquidity for capital formation and sustained growth. However, the very same dollar hegemony has undermined or inhibited attempts to build national capitalisms in most of South America and Africa, exposing these countries to resource-extraction logics and to financial cycles that destabilize exchange rates, purchasing power, and sovereign debt. Precisely because these countries could not develop monetary sovereignty within the larger imperialist context, mature industrializations have by and large failed.</p><p>On the other hand, even in the advanced economies of the West, the relationship between national capitalisms and dollar hegemony has been tenuous, and since 1970, these tensions have come to the fore. If it had been difficult to square the interests between surplus and deficit countries in the Bretton Woods system to start with, solutions became impossible to achieve under reinvigorated financial globalization, which was itself enabled chiefly by dollar hegemony. European monetary integration, perhaps the most striking turn away from national “monetary communities,” is Europe's (particularly France's) answer to these predicaments, with new monetary hierarchies (Northern vs. Southern Europe) and frictions of its own. More generally, the rise and fall of mass industrial production, associated forms of social organization (urbanization, unionization, party formation, etc.), and the attendant bureaucratization of public sectors and companies are only one part of the story in the development of national capitalisms. If these factors were all that mattered, you would wonder why so few countries have ever achieved economic sovereignty. A key reason for this, I believe, is that the few powerful countries at the apex of the system have ensured that global conditions support their own (Fordist and post-Fordist) national capitalist projects, often at the cost of blocking the rise of national capitalisms elsewhere and also increasingly leading to conflicts among those who pursue competing geoeconomic and geopolitical projects (especially after China entered the game).</p><p>A second intriguing question concerns the relationships between corporate, market, and state power in an increasingly fractured, imperialist world. The conventional story that Hart partly endorses is that the dominant corporations, and/or their CEOs and owners, essentially dominate today, with ideological protection from US-promoted market fundamentalism. But Hart's essay also allows for another interpretation that I deem more interesting and accurate. In this second version, we assume that not only do multinational corporations and banks exploit the opportunities of fragmented globalization; so do political actors, especially (authoritarian) governments. Rather than perceiving of themselves as actors in a strictly international system composed of nation-states, political elites as much as their private peers observe, leverage, and exploit the complex structures of financial markets, value chains, currency hierarchies, energy systems, the internet, and patterns of political loyalty and adversary. Those in control of certain hubs can exercise coercive and infrastructural power over and with others. Farrell and Newman (<span>2019</span>), concentrating on the coercive side, have theorized this situation as “weaponized interdependence,” in which controllers of hubs can coerce others, for example, by withdrawing vital resources from them (think of Putin's geopolitics of gas). My own work demonstrates that central banks in the key financial centers (the United States, Britain) have leveraged globalized money and capital markets to pursue domestic/in-group-focused monetary, macroeconomic, and financial stability policies (e.g., the Federal Reserve's quantitative easing, enabled by global dollar liquidity), often to the detriment of other countries (e.g., through the devastating global liquidity cycles) (Wansleben, <span>2023</span>).</p><p>Under the (sometimes misleading) labels of “postcolonialism” and “political ecology,” scholars in recent years have increasingly rendered visible the enabling, often exploitative conditions of capitalist modernity of which “all-purpose money” is one aspect. Following this path, such money has never been a pure social convention or expression of collective trust among members of a national community. Instead, every national currency is nested in an international stratified order and is predicated on natural resource–exploiting growth that allows the fulfillment of debt promises whose issuance creates money in the first place. As Geoffrey Ingham has aptly put it, modern money is capitalist credit money and as such deeply entangled with exploitative, unsustainable global-political and ecological conditions. The dilemma that is at the heart of Hart's article, and reflected in his own ambiguous stance, is that we have a hard time imagining any other formula for coordinating, if not harmonizing, the demands for democracy and welfare with the forces of capitalism. No other significant political project of the past decades, springing from this crisis of Western national capitalisms, gives much hope. China's authoritarian, growth-focused control state does not, nor do Bitcoin or global social movements that, instead of building robust foundations of their own, are parasitic to the very institutions and infrastructures of capitalist democracies, whose crises give them force. I therefore fully understand Hart's pessimism that many of us share. Perhaps it is inevitable that things get worse before they can get better. The alternative to that is, I fear, to remain an enlightened reformist who tries to create more sustainable, equitable foundations for national capitalism.</p>","PeriodicalId":45372,"journal":{"name":"Economic Anthropology","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.2000,"publicationDate":"2024-01-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1002/sea2.12302","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Rethinking economic sovereignty\",\"authors\":\"Leon Wansleben\",\"doi\":\"10.1002/sea2.12302\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"<p>In his broad and compelling essay “The Rise and Fall of National Capitalism,” Keith Hart offers an alternative interpretation and periodization of global capitalist order that diverges from standard distinctions into prewar, postwar (Keynesian/progressive), and neoliberal eras. Hart's core claim is that, in the Second Industrial Revolution, a strong nexus between mass industrial capitalism and state power was forged. This nexus gradually loosened and now dissolves. Sovereign all-purpose money—money that links the financial sector with public debt and taxation, as well as national payment infrastructures—has been an important building block of “national capitalisms,” and its diminishing role indicates the latter's demise. The essay does not present one concise explanation of this development but rather engages with diverse themes, from neoliberal policies and ideology to “lawless global money circuits” to the power of transnational corporations to the digital revolution to secular stagnation in advanced economies (with a concomitant shift from productivist to rent-extracting capital accumulation). I have difficulties at times following Hart's precise argument with regard to each of the causal drivers. In many cases, the essay relies on explanations developed in more depth elsewhere in the author's work. For these reasons, I take the liberty to focus solely on the main descriptive claim, namely, that we have been living in national capitalisms that are about to disappear, with potentially catastrophic consequences.</p><p>A significant first question left unanswered by this essay concerns the linkage between national capitalisms, to the extent that they have come into existence, and the global order. Clearly, Hart sees this order as imperialist, with the United States as the hegemon since the turn of the 20th century. Indeed, as other authors have stressed, global monetary and financial structures, even more so than military and security structures, support this empire. The dollar is by far the globally dominant currency, used not only in most trade but even more so in financial transactions. The collapse of Bretton Woods institutions, and again the financial crisis of 2008, have not challenged but rather reinforced this hegemony. But if we have been living in imperialist global orders all the way through, this raises interesting questions about national capitalism. Clearly American imperialism has supported such capitalisms in some regions and some periods. In particular, dollar hegemony has facilitated the reemergence of national capitalisms in Europe after the Second World War by generating the institutions, necessary demand, and liquidity for capital formation and sustained growth. However, the very same dollar hegemony has undermined or inhibited attempts to build national capitalisms in most of South America and Africa, exposing these countries to resource-extraction logics and to financial cycles that destabilize exchange rates, purchasing power, and sovereign debt. Precisely because these countries could not develop monetary sovereignty within the larger imperialist context, mature industrializations have by and large failed.</p><p>On the other hand, even in the advanced economies of the West, the relationship between national capitalisms and dollar hegemony has been tenuous, and since 1970, these tensions have come to the fore. If it had been difficult to square the interests between surplus and deficit countries in the Bretton Woods system to start with, solutions became impossible to achieve under reinvigorated financial globalization, which was itself enabled chiefly by dollar hegemony. European monetary integration, perhaps the most striking turn away from national “monetary communities,” is Europe's (particularly France's) answer to these predicaments, with new monetary hierarchies (Northern vs. Southern Europe) and frictions of its own. More generally, the rise and fall of mass industrial production, associated forms of social organization (urbanization, unionization, party formation, etc.), and the attendant bureaucratization of public sectors and companies are only one part of the story in the development of national capitalisms. If these factors were all that mattered, you would wonder why so few countries have ever achieved economic sovereignty. A key reason for this, I believe, is that the few powerful countries at the apex of the system have ensured that global conditions support their own (Fordist and post-Fordist) national capitalist projects, often at the cost of blocking the rise of national capitalisms elsewhere and also increasingly leading to conflicts among those who pursue competing geoeconomic and geopolitical projects (especially after China entered the game).</p><p>A second intriguing question concerns the relationships between corporate, market, and state power in an increasingly fractured, imperialist world. The conventional story that Hart partly endorses is that the dominant corporations, and/or their CEOs and owners, essentially dominate today, with ideological protection from US-promoted market fundamentalism. But Hart's essay also allows for another interpretation that I deem more interesting and accurate. In this second version, we assume that not only do multinational corporations and banks exploit the opportunities of fragmented globalization; so do political actors, especially (authoritarian) governments. Rather than perceiving of themselves as actors in a strictly international system composed of nation-states, political elites as much as their private peers observe, leverage, and exploit the complex structures of financial markets, value chains, currency hierarchies, energy systems, the internet, and patterns of political loyalty and adversary. Those in control of certain hubs can exercise coercive and infrastructural power over and with others. Farrell and Newman (<span>2019</span>), concentrating on the coercive side, have theorized this situation as “weaponized interdependence,” in which controllers of hubs can coerce others, for example, by withdrawing vital resources from them (think of Putin's geopolitics of gas). My own work demonstrates that central banks in the key financial centers (the United States, Britain) have leveraged globalized money and capital markets to pursue domestic/in-group-focused monetary, macroeconomic, and financial stability policies (e.g., the Federal Reserve's quantitative easing, enabled by global dollar liquidity), often to the detriment of other countries (e.g., through the devastating global liquidity cycles) (Wansleben, <span>2023</span>).</p><p>Under the (sometimes misleading) labels of “postcolonialism” and “political ecology,” scholars in recent years have increasingly rendered visible the enabling, often exploitative conditions of capitalist modernity of which “all-purpose money” is one aspect. Following this path, such money has never been a pure social convention or expression of collective trust among members of a national community. Instead, every national currency is nested in an international stratified order and is predicated on natural resource–exploiting growth that allows the fulfillment of debt promises whose issuance creates money in the first place. As Geoffrey Ingham has aptly put it, modern money is capitalist credit money and as such deeply entangled with exploitative, unsustainable global-political and ecological conditions. The dilemma that is at the heart of Hart's article, and reflected in his own ambiguous stance, is that we have a hard time imagining any other formula for coordinating, if not harmonizing, the demands for democracy and welfare with the forces of capitalism. No other significant political project of the past decades, springing from this crisis of Western national capitalisms, gives much hope. China's authoritarian, growth-focused control state does not, nor do Bitcoin or global social movements that, instead of building robust foundations of their own, are parasitic to the very institutions and infrastructures of capitalist democracies, whose crises give them force. I therefore fully understand Hart's pessimism that many of us share. Perhaps it is inevitable that things get worse before they can get better. The alternative to that is, I fear, to remain an enlightened reformist who tries to create more sustainable, equitable foundations for national capitalism.</p>\",\"PeriodicalId\":45372,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Economic Anthropology\",\"volume\":null,\"pages\":null},\"PeriodicalIF\":1.2000,\"publicationDate\":\"2024-01-15\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1002/sea2.12302\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Economic Anthropology\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"90\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1002/sea2.12302\",\"RegionNum\":4,\"RegionCategory\":\"社会学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q2\",\"JCRName\":\"ANTHROPOLOGY\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Economic Anthropology","FirstCategoryId":"90","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1002/sea2.12302","RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"ANTHROPOLOGY","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

哈特部分认可的传统说法是,在美国推动的市场原教旨主义的意识形态保护下,占主导地位的企业和/或其首席执行官和所有者基本上主导着当今的世界。但哈特的文章也允许另一种我认为更有趣、更准确的解释。在第二个版本中,我们假定不仅跨国公司和银行在利用分散的全球化机遇,政治行为体,尤其是(专制)政府也在利用这种机遇。政治精英们并不把自己看作是由民族国家组成的严格国际体系中的行为者,而是像他们的私人同僚一样,观察、利用并开发金融市场、价值链、货币等级制度、能源系统、互联网以及政治忠诚和敌对模式等复杂结构。控制某些枢纽的人可以对其他枢纽行使胁迫和基础设施权力。法雷尔和纽曼(2019)将这种情况理论化为 "武器化的相互依存",即枢纽的控制者可以胁迫其他枢纽,例如,从它们那里撤回重要资源(想想普京的天然气地缘政治)。我自己的研究表明,主要金融中心(美国、英国)的中央银行利用全球化的货币和资本市场,推行以国内/集团为中心的货币、宏观经济和金融稳定政策(例如,美联储的量化宽松政策,通过全球美元流动性得以实现),这往往会损害其他国家的利益(例如,通过破坏性的全球流动性周期)、近年来,在 "后殖民主义 "和 "政治生态学"(有时具有误导性)的标签下,学者们越来越多地揭示了资本主义现代性的有利条件,这些条件往往是剥削性的,而 "万能货币 "就是其中的一个方面。沿着这条道路,这种货币从来都不是一种纯粹的社会习俗,也不是一个国家社会成员之间集体信任的表达。相反,每个国家的货币都嵌套在一个国际分层秩序中,并以自然资源开发性增长为前提,这种增长使得债务承诺得以实现,而债务承诺的发行首先创造了货币。正如杰弗里-英格汉姆(Geoffrey Ingham)所说,现代货币是资本主义的信用货币,因此与剥削性的、不可持续的全球政治和生态条件紧密相连。哈特文章的核心,也是他自己模棱两可的立场所反映出的困境是,我们很难想象还有什么其他方案可以协调民主和福利要求与资本主义力量之间的关系。在过去几十年中,没有任何一个重要的政治项目能在西方国家资本主义危机的背景下带来希望。中国的专制、以增长为中心的控制型国家没有,比特币或全球社会运动也没有,它们没有建立自己的稳固基础,而是寄生于资本主义民主国家的机构和基础设施,而资本主义民主国家的危机给了它们力量。因此,我完全理解哈特的悲观情绪,我们中的许多人也有同感。也许,在情况好转之前,恶化是不可避免的。我担心,除此之外的选择就是继续做一个开明的改革派,努力为国家资本主义创造更可持续、更公平的基础。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
Rethinking economic sovereignty

In his broad and compelling essay “The Rise and Fall of National Capitalism,” Keith Hart offers an alternative interpretation and periodization of global capitalist order that diverges from standard distinctions into prewar, postwar (Keynesian/progressive), and neoliberal eras. Hart's core claim is that, in the Second Industrial Revolution, a strong nexus between mass industrial capitalism and state power was forged. This nexus gradually loosened and now dissolves. Sovereign all-purpose money—money that links the financial sector with public debt and taxation, as well as national payment infrastructures—has been an important building block of “national capitalisms,” and its diminishing role indicates the latter's demise. The essay does not present one concise explanation of this development but rather engages with diverse themes, from neoliberal policies and ideology to “lawless global money circuits” to the power of transnational corporations to the digital revolution to secular stagnation in advanced economies (with a concomitant shift from productivist to rent-extracting capital accumulation). I have difficulties at times following Hart's precise argument with regard to each of the causal drivers. In many cases, the essay relies on explanations developed in more depth elsewhere in the author's work. For these reasons, I take the liberty to focus solely on the main descriptive claim, namely, that we have been living in national capitalisms that are about to disappear, with potentially catastrophic consequences.

A significant first question left unanswered by this essay concerns the linkage between national capitalisms, to the extent that they have come into existence, and the global order. Clearly, Hart sees this order as imperialist, with the United States as the hegemon since the turn of the 20th century. Indeed, as other authors have stressed, global monetary and financial structures, even more so than military and security structures, support this empire. The dollar is by far the globally dominant currency, used not only in most trade but even more so in financial transactions. The collapse of Bretton Woods institutions, and again the financial crisis of 2008, have not challenged but rather reinforced this hegemony. But if we have been living in imperialist global orders all the way through, this raises interesting questions about national capitalism. Clearly American imperialism has supported such capitalisms in some regions and some periods. In particular, dollar hegemony has facilitated the reemergence of national capitalisms in Europe after the Second World War by generating the institutions, necessary demand, and liquidity for capital formation and sustained growth. However, the very same dollar hegemony has undermined or inhibited attempts to build national capitalisms in most of South America and Africa, exposing these countries to resource-extraction logics and to financial cycles that destabilize exchange rates, purchasing power, and sovereign debt. Precisely because these countries could not develop monetary sovereignty within the larger imperialist context, mature industrializations have by and large failed.

On the other hand, even in the advanced economies of the West, the relationship between national capitalisms and dollar hegemony has been tenuous, and since 1970, these tensions have come to the fore. If it had been difficult to square the interests between surplus and deficit countries in the Bretton Woods system to start with, solutions became impossible to achieve under reinvigorated financial globalization, which was itself enabled chiefly by dollar hegemony. European monetary integration, perhaps the most striking turn away from national “monetary communities,” is Europe's (particularly France's) answer to these predicaments, with new monetary hierarchies (Northern vs. Southern Europe) and frictions of its own. More generally, the rise and fall of mass industrial production, associated forms of social organization (urbanization, unionization, party formation, etc.), and the attendant bureaucratization of public sectors and companies are only one part of the story in the development of national capitalisms. If these factors were all that mattered, you would wonder why so few countries have ever achieved economic sovereignty. A key reason for this, I believe, is that the few powerful countries at the apex of the system have ensured that global conditions support their own (Fordist and post-Fordist) national capitalist projects, often at the cost of blocking the rise of national capitalisms elsewhere and also increasingly leading to conflicts among those who pursue competing geoeconomic and geopolitical projects (especially after China entered the game).

A second intriguing question concerns the relationships between corporate, market, and state power in an increasingly fractured, imperialist world. The conventional story that Hart partly endorses is that the dominant corporations, and/or their CEOs and owners, essentially dominate today, with ideological protection from US-promoted market fundamentalism. But Hart's essay also allows for another interpretation that I deem more interesting and accurate. In this second version, we assume that not only do multinational corporations and banks exploit the opportunities of fragmented globalization; so do political actors, especially (authoritarian) governments. Rather than perceiving of themselves as actors in a strictly international system composed of nation-states, political elites as much as their private peers observe, leverage, and exploit the complex structures of financial markets, value chains, currency hierarchies, energy systems, the internet, and patterns of political loyalty and adversary. Those in control of certain hubs can exercise coercive and infrastructural power over and with others. Farrell and Newman (2019), concentrating on the coercive side, have theorized this situation as “weaponized interdependence,” in which controllers of hubs can coerce others, for example, by withdrawing vital resources from them (think of Putin's geopolitics of gas). My own work demonstrates that central banks in the key financial centers (the United States, Britain) have leveraged globalized money and capital markets to pursue domestic/in-group-focused monetary, macroeconomic, and financial stability policies (e.g., the Federal Reserve's quantitative easing, enabled by global dollar liquidity), often to the detriment of other countries (e.g., through the devastating global liquidity cycles) (Wansleben, 2023).

Under the (sometimes misleading) labels of “postcolonialism” and “political ecology,” scholars in recent years have increasingly rendered visible the enabling, often exploitative conditions of capitalist modernity of which “all-purpose money” is one aspect. Following this path, such money has never been a pure social convention or expression of collective trust among members of a national community. Instead, every national currency is nested in an international stratified order and is predicated on natural resource–exploiting growth that allows the fulfillment of debt promises whose issuance creates money in the first place. As Geoffrey Ingham has aptly put it, modern money is capitalist credit money and as such deeply entangled with exploitative, unsustainable global-political and ecological conditions. The dilemma that is at the heart of Hart's article, and reflected in his own ambiguous stance, is that we have a hard time imagining any other formula for coordinating, if not harmonizing, the demands for democracy and welfare with the forces of capitalism. No other significant political project of the past decades, springing from this crisis of Western national capitalisms, gives much hope. China's authoritarian, growth-focused control state does not, nor do Bitcoin or global social movements that, instead of building robust foundations of their own, are parasitic to the very institutions and infrastructures of capitalist democracies, whose crises give them force. I therefore fully understand Hart's pessimism that many of us share. Perhaps it is inevitable that things get worse before they can get better. The alternative to that is, I fear, to remain an enlightened reformist who tries to create more sustainable, equitable foundations for national capitalism.

求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
Economic Anthropology
Economic Anthropology ANTHROPOLOGY-
CiteScore
2.60
自引率
11.10%
发文量
42
期刊最新文献
“It all depends on the market”: Taste as an economic fact Reaching millions: Water, substitute infrastructure, and the politics of scale in Kenya Economic Anthropology How are you, anthropology? Reflections on well-being and the common good “Sometimes it looks fake”: Hiyal and contrivances as tools for exploring aspirations for radical social change
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1