丹麦:创新主义 "的缩影?

IF 1 Q3 ECONOMICS ECONOMIC AFFAIRS Pub Date : 2024-06-09 DOI:10.1111/ecaf.12652
Stefan Kirkegaard Sløk-Madsen, Henrik Mogensen Nielsen
{"title":"丹麦:创新主义 \"的缩影?","authors":"Stefan Kirkegaard Sløk-Madsen,&nbsp;Henrik Mogensen Nielsen","doi":"10.1111/ecaf.12652","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>Why do some societies go from poverty to prosperity? This question should occupy all socially conscious social scientists, particularly as we have seen successful societies experience unprecedented growth in living standards all over the world, beginning in the West roughly around 1750 (McCloskey, <span>2010</span>, <span>2021</span>; Mokyr, <span>2008</span>, <span>2016</span>). This development has been called the ‘great enrichment’ and Denmark is a prime example of this (McCloskey, <span>2021</span>). GDP per capita grew from $2,031 in 1820 to $52,133 in 2022 (in 2011 dollars; Bolt &amp; van Zanden, <span>2020</span>).</p><p>Why did the great enrichment occur when and where it did? Several explanations exist. Institutionalists such as Nobel laureate Douglass North (<span>1990</span>) hold good institutions to be the main explanation. Other theories emphasise exploitation of people and resources, both domestic and foreign. Modern trade theorists argue that free trade can create wealth, which can lead to liberty which again leads to further innovation. In Denmark, population homogeneity has been argued to explain it too. Recently, though, a new explanation, that of ‘innovism’, has gained momentum. This concept, coined by the economic historian Deirdre McCloskey, suggests that the root cause of the wealth of nations is creativity fostered by classical liberal ideas about dignity and liberty, rather than simply accumulation of capital.</p><p>McCloskey claims that while institutional arrangements similar to what can be described as capitalistic can be observed through time, the sheer magnitude of improvement observed in the period from approximately 1750 onwards, and particularly, in north-western Europe, calls for a new explanation: innovism. She highlights the implementation of ideals fostering human action with incentives for idea dissemination and entrepreneurship as the key explainer of the great enrichment, more so than materialism or state design. As she concludes: “Innovism, that is, is a matter of creativity, which depends on liberty” (McCloskey, <span>2023</span>, p. 29). In other words, the accumulation of ideas, rather than capital, becomes the key factor. This article investigates whether Denmark's impressive enrichment is indeed best explained by innovism, especially when coupled with Paul Romer-style thinking about technological ideas as infinite resources (Jones, <span>2019</span>), or by competing theories such as exploitation or institutional design.</p><p>Our article is based mainly on the research behind the book <i>Danish Capitalism in the 20th Century: A Business History of an Innovistic Mixed Economy</i> (Sløk-Madsen, <span>2022</span>). We think that this piece is a necessary add-on to help better understand Denmark's narrative of economic development, but it is necessary for another reason too. If, as we argue, Denmark's remarkable success is indeed explained by policy choices supporting innovism, with very few pre-existing assets or advantages, there is potentially much to learn for other nations too.</p><p>At the end of the Napoleonic Wars in 1815, the kingdom of Denmark was in a desperate state. Betting on the wrong (French) horse, a state bankruptcy, and the seizure of the navy by the British put the once-proud Danish empire in real danger of ceasing to exist. Despite the loss of Norway, the kingdom was still spread very thinly over a vast distance spanning from India to the West Indies and containing dozens of languages and dialects. The only real assets the kingdom had were relatively high literacy rates from 300 years devoted to Lutheranism, a strong trading tradition, and a relatively stable state organisation.</p><p>The nation was under absolutist government and economically stuck in a mixture of feudalism and mercantilism. However, since the 1780s a growing enlightenment debate had taken hold (Bang et al., <span>1984</span>). While originally focused on freedom of speech, the debate would mature over the following century to include free market principles and nationalism infused with inspiration from German romantic ideas, particularly in saloons such as those held at Bakkehuset (Sørensen, <span>2020</span>), the residence of the Rahbek couple<sup>1</sup> who brought together the intellectuals of the time from science, literature and politics.</p><p>In the decades after the Napoleonic Wars new government reforms were initiated to incorporate and centralise Danish landholdings, especially in northern Germany, where the duchies of Schleswig and Holstein had been linked to the Danish monarch rather than the Danish realm since the late Middle Ages (Busck et al., <span>2011</span>). The efforts to reorganise Denmark from a feudal vassal state to a centralised collective state are exemplified by some of the first truly democratic institutions in Denmark, namely the local estate assemblies, which managed to increase their political influence throughout the 1830s and 1840s, often by demanding revisions to Danish mercantilist trade policies and liberalising trade reforms, despite still being within the framework of a nominally absolutist state.</p><p>Danish efforts to further centralise and tighten Denmark's grip on the Danish German-speaking duchies inevitably provoked increased nationalist sentiment in the German Confederation, leading to the First Schleswig War in 1848. What had begun as the reluctant democratisation efforts of an absolutist regime to centralise its possessions had suddenly plunged Denmark into war with Prussia and Austria (Bjørn, <span>1999</span>). While the war resulted in a reversion to the status quo after the intervention of Russia, France, and the United Kingdom in 1851, the immediate crisis led to a regime change from absolute monarchy to constitutional monarchy controlled by a democratically elected government led by the National Liberal Movement, which succeeded in adopting a national constitution in 1849 (Vammen, <span>1988</span>).</p><p>The key political victory of the new constitution was the National Liberals' amendment to change the institutional framework for Danish trade, production, and manufacturing, which was finally implemented by the Freedom of Trade Act of 1857. The Act, in practice implemented in successive rounds of reform over four years, was a radical, fundamental, and rapid switch from guild-led mercantilism to a market-economy society. Historians have often overlooked the significance of the changes brought about by these reforms. However, their importance for Denmark's later economic success cannot be overestimated. The Act changed the conditions for merchants and craftsmen, who had enjoyed extensive privileges in Danish market towns since the Middle Ages through their guilds and associations. While in principle all citizens were entitled to trade, the privileges of the guilds had in practice restricted the ability to compete and innovate (Dübeck, <span>1983</span>).</p><p>The reforms effectively abolished feudal mercantilism in Danish market towns and replaced it with free trade and competition, which in subsequent decades spurred much-needed innovation and entrepreneurship. However, the Conservatives' price for agreeing with the National Liberals was the introduction of national taxation (while the conservative aim was defence spending, they also inadvertently laid the foundations of later welfare spending growth). The national spirit was high, but it also ultimately led to a fatal underestimation of Prussia and the defeat in the Second Schleswig War in 1864, resulting in the National Liberals' loss of influence while the state apparatus was taken over by the Conservatives to the point of dictatorship. Furthermore, the populace in the cities increasingly turned to socialism in various forms. Despite political turmoil, the liberal reforms resulted in a booming economy, creating a group of urban, highly financialised global entrepreneurs like N. F. Tietgen and J. C. Jacobsen. These people used the fact, later pointed out by Paul Romer (Jones, <span>2019</span>), that ideas are a truly infinite resource: good ideas could be taken from abroad and implemented at home in global scale, a strategy which successful modern Danish companies such as Lego, Maersk, and Novo Nordisk would also eventually follow.</p><p>Building on the economic and political reforms of the mid-nineteenth century, Denmark experienced a period of relative economic prosperity in the first few decades of the twentieth century. Some of this can be attributed to the aforementioned reform efforts of the National Liberal movement. But other global trends, such as industrialisation, also found a distinctive Danish expression. One example is the Danish cooperative movement, Andelsbevægelsen. It emerged in the early 1880s as a response to the challenges posed by liberalised market forces. Danish agriculture, as in most of Western and Central Europe, was faced with the threat of cheap American grain flooding European markets (Andresen &amp; Agersnap, <span>1989</span>). Danish farmers quickly realised that they could not compete with American production or prices and instead shifted their focus from arable farming to dairy production, which was less vulnerable to American competition.</p><p>To further increase their competitiveness, Danish farmers formed small cooperatives. These cooperatives collected milk production from the surrounding area and processed it together in communal dairies. Through the sharing of production costs, the cooperatives were able to reduce costs for local dairy farmers, who could then concentrate on the quality of their products. At the same time, the pooling of resources for processing had the effect of reducing costs, which in turn both lowered prices for consumers and increased profits for farmers; thus the movement was in the spirit of a commercial society. The Danish cooperative of dairy farmers, Andelsmejerier, quickly became a success and conquered the Danish domestic market within a few years (Christensen, <span>1997</span>). The innovative organisational model in the form of cooperatives not only provided a competitive advantage in agriculture, but also quickly spread to a wide range of Danish industries, including retail and banking.</p><p>Another characteristic of Danish business in the early twentieth century, which lasted until the end of World War II, was both the idea and the practical implementation of what can be described as a kind of ‘patriotic’ corporate governance and trade, pioneered by entrepreneurs such as aforementioned Tietgen and Jacobsen (Sløk-Madsen, <span>2022</span>). It was patriotic because Danish business in the first half of the twentieth century influenced, and to some extent replaced, the Danish government in key policy areas traditionally considered nation-state concerns, such as education, public housing, social welfare, trade, and even foreign policy.</p><p>After the end of World War II, new – and fundamentally foreign – ideas took hold. Ideas of redistribution inspired by Anglo-Saxon Keynesian and Bismarckian state ideas took hold across the political spectrum, fuelled by special interest groups from both the agricultural sector and the labour movement and a population seeking a new national identity akin to what Hobsbawm and Ranger (<span>2012</span>) describe. From the 1960s public sector, tax rates, and redistribution grew enormously, made possible by the 1956 abolition of the upper house of parliament (Landstinget) and a mandatory fully implemented social security system (CPR).</p><p>The system almost broke under its own weight by the very early 1980s, summarised by the notorious statement by the Social Democratic Minister of Budget Knud Heinesen that Denmark was looking into the (economic) abyss. This dismal prospect gave rise to a period of welfare state reform led by a Conservative–Liberal government and then a coalition of the Social Democratic Party and various small centre parties. For the purpose of this article, it is important to stress two things. The right wing in this reform episode never sought to fundamentally abolish or change the universal welfare state, only to make it more efficient. At the same time the Social Democrat Party accepted the market as the only means to prosperity.</p><p>The reform agenda was pursued into the new millennium until the outbreak of Covid-19, again by both sides of the political divide. Denmark rose from the rank of 12th highest per capita GDP in OECD countries in 2000 to sixth in 2022. Today, state finances are solid. In Denmark a significant and increasing part of the economy is made up by global but old companies, while new successful companies leave. Immigration was for decades a hotly contested issue between the left and the right, but the new divide seems to be about life's purpose: do you owe the welfare state your life and body, or are they yours? A fundamentally ideological divide has hence re-emerged.</p><p>In this rapid survey of Danish economic history, we can see that many things changed. Living standards grew tremendously, and institutions were transformed, including the whole political system. Ideas emerged; some took hold and some were pushed back – communism and fascism, for instance, never had a wide appeal in Denmark. To various degrees, universalism and classical liberal ideas such as property rights, freedom of association, speech, religion and trade remained as a constant. As we indicated earlier, we will now review the five explanations and the arguments for and against them in the Danish case. Table 1 sets out our analysis.</p><p>We do not doubt the importance of institutions for enrichment. But rather than being themselves causes, they are, in the case of Denmark as in the theory of innovism, more a manifestation of prevailing rooted political ideas. The fact that institutions changed and evolved in response to changing ideas in Denmark should be seen as testimony to this understanding. We should, however, note that it is crucial to remember the importance of trust as a potential institution or norm in itself. Danes trusted that ideas and motives could be pure and not just expressions of group interests or even lies. An example would be freedom of religious organisation – including largely within the state church itself from 1856 – which was widely seen as an ideal in itself, not a desire for special rules for a specific group. Therefore, trust levels probably grew as a result of the type of ideas innovism highlights as growth enhancers, but a good base level was likely present at the outset (Bergh &amp; Bjørnskov, <span>2011</span>).</p><p>The least likely explanation for Danish prosperity remains the exploitation of the less privileged, whether at home or aboard. The working class prospered mainly from growth, not redistribution. Today, the extensive pension systems are so successful that 2 per cent of the Danish population are dollar millionaires, compared with a world average of 0.3 per cent; and 1.6 million Danes are Danish krone millionaires (CEPOS, <span>2021b</span>). As for colonies, it is questionable how much Denmark profited from these, especially if viewed as pure exploitation rather than trade. Ironically the current welfare state model arguably exploits the most productive, as 59 per cent of Danes are net recipients of transfers with 1 per cent of taxpayers paying for 10.2 per cent of public spending, and the top 10 per cent paying 31.8 per cent (CEPOS, <span>2021a</span>). Furthermore, almost two-thirds of the voters are primarily paid from public transfers from either welfare or due to employment in the public sector (CEPOS, <span>2024</span>).</p><p>Without free trade Denmark would not be rich. It is, for instance, uniquely placed to be a shipping nation and even a global top-ten shipping nation (Branch &amp; Stopford, <span>2013</span>). Denmark is a small open economy and the large successful companies, except public IT-vendors, banks and insurance, are all export- oriented. However, Denmark has been a trading region since the Stone Age (van der Sluis et al., <span>2020</span>) and this alone cannot explain the enrichment. But liberalisation of trade to a high degree can, as with the 1857 Freedom of Trade Act. Yet market liberalisation was driven to a degree by classical liberal ideals, although it was also a response to increasing spontaneous commercial activity. But both the class of urban entrepreneurs and the farm side of the cooperative movement shared classical liberal ideas which motivated them in both business and politics.</p><p>Innovism therefore stands out to us as holding the greatest explanatory power. Denmark was blessed with high literacy rates and indeed promoted this extensively until the 1970s. An early, persistent and deep-rooted liberal debate around universal rights pre-dates both institutions and prosperity quite clearly in the history of modern Denmark (Bang et al., <span>1984</span>). Liberal ideas inspired reforms which incentivised entrepreneurs to import and propagate business ideas with surprising success along the lines suggested by Romer.</p><p>Universalism also carried over into the design of the Danish welfare state. The argument for the welfare state did not purely relate to the needy, but was rather a statement that all should benefit. In that sense, Denmark also shows a less attractive side of innovism in that if ideas pre-date change, weak ideas can lead to unfortunate changes, and that might be part of the explanation of the sudden birth of the welfare state; weak but superficially attractive ideas were imported in a climate accustomed to listening to and implementing new ideas.</p><p>Finally, the last theory, the idea of a homogeneous population, is more difficult to disentangle. On some levels the population has been homogeneous, almost all being Lutheran for instance, but in terms of culture and language the picture is muddier. The Danish welfare state in its design certainly has elements of attempting to force sameness on people, as Hayek (<span>2008</span>) argued such systems would. However, today's heterogeneity in the Danish population has come from guest workers, immigrants, and refugees, and has occurred increasingly from the 1980s onward; and much of what is currently Denmark was created with the reforms after this date.</p><p>In this short essay our aim has been to present Denmark as a case to inspire. Denmark indeed appears the ideal type, the epitome of innovism. Denmark was not a consistently rich nation before a commitment was made to innovism. The country has barely any national resources, yet today it is one of the richest nations in the world. If the measure of innovism should be the accumulation of ideas, Denmark is very rich indeed; global Danish companies, such as Novo Nordisk, Lego, Carlsberg and others are all built on adapting and executing imported technological ideas. The richness of Denmark is the result of a dedication to universal ideas of human dignity and economic freedom. As such Denmark can also be a hopeful lesson for other nations. If you invest in human capital and conduct government while importing classical liberal ideas, there is precious little stopping a nation and its people from themselves setting out on the road to the ‘great enrichment’.</p><p>Denmark is not the only nation to outdo expectations; other nations like Botswana, South Korea, and Singapore also share a story of comparatively higher-than-expected riches. What such nations share is a degree of dedication to universal ideas of human dignity and economic freedom. This can be a lesson: if you invest in human capital, particularly basic reading skills, and conduct government trustingly while importing classical liberal ideas, there is precious little stopping a nation and people proceeding on the path to great enrichment.</p>","PeriodicalId":44825,"journal":{"name":"ECONOMIC AFFAIRS","volume":"44 2","pages":"394-401"},"PeriodicalIF":1.0000,"publicationDate":"2024-06-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/ecaf.12652","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Denmark: The epitome of ‘innovism’?\",\"authors\":\"Stefan Kirkegaard Sløk-Madsen,&nbsp;Henrik Mogensen Nielsen\",\"doi\":\"10.1111/ecaf.12652\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"<p>Why do some societies go from poverty to prosperity? This question should occupy all socially conscious social scientists, particularly as we have seen successful societies experience unprecedented growth in living standards all over the world, beginning in the West roughly around 1750 (McCloskey, <span>2010</span>, <span>2021</span>; Mokyr, <span>2008</span>, <span>2016</span>). This development has been called the ‘great enrichment’ and Denmark is a prime example of this (McCloskey, <span>2021</span>). GDP per capita grew from $2,031 in 1820 to $52,133 in 2022 (in 2011 dollars; Bolt &amp; van Zanden, <span>2020</span>).</p><p>Why did the great enrichment occur when and where it did? Several explanations exist. Institutionalists such as Nobel laureate Douglass North (<span>1990</span>) hold good institutions to be the main explanation. Other theories emphasise exploitation of people and resources, both domestic and foreign. Modern trade theorists argue that free trade can create wealth, which can lead to liberty which again leads to further innovation. In Denmark, population homogeneity has been argued to explain it too. Recently, though, a new explanation, that of ‘innovism’, has gained momentum. This concept, coined by the economic historian Deirdre McCloskey, suggests that the root cause of the wealth of nations is creativity fostered by classical liberal ideas about dignity and liberty, rather than simply accumulation of capital.</p><p>McCloskey claims that while institutional arrangements similar to what can be described as capitalistic can be observed through time, the sheer magnitude of improvement observed in the period from approximately 1750 onwards, and particularly, in north-western Europe, calls for a new explanation: innovism. She highlights the implementation of ideals fostering human action with incentives for idea dissemination and entrepreneurship as the key explainer of the great enrichment, more so than materialism or state design. As she concludes: “Innovism, that is, is a matter of creativity, which depends on liberty” (McCloskey, <span>2023</span>, p. 29). In other words, the accumulation of ideas, rather than capital, becomes the key factor. This article investigates whether Denmark's impressive enrichment is indeed best explained by innovism, especially when coupled with Paul Romer-style thinking about technological ideas as infinite resources (Jones, <span>2019</span>), or by competing theories such as exploitation or institutional design.</p><p>Our article is based mainly on the research behind the book <i>Danish Capitalism in the 20th Century: A Business History of an Innovistic Mixed Economy</i> (Sløk-Madsen, <span>2022</span>). We think that this piece is a necessary add-on to help better understand Denmark's narrative of economic development, but it is necessary for another reason too. If, as we argue, Denmark's remarkable success is indeed explained by policy choices supporting innovism, with very few pre-existing assets or advantages, there is potentially much to learn for other nations too.</p><p>At the end of the Napoleonic Wars in 1815, the kingdom of Denmark was in a desperate state. Betting on the wrong (French) horse, a state bankruptcy, and the seizure of the navy by the British put the once-proud Danish empire in real danger of ceasing to exist. Despite the loss of Norway, the kingdom was still spread very thinly over a vast distance spanning from India to the West Indies and containing dozens of languages and dialects. The only real assets the kingdom had were relatively high literacy rates from 300 years devoted to Lutheranism, a strong trading tradition, and a relatively stable state organisation.</p><p>The nation was under absolutist government and economically stuck in a mixture of feudalism and mercantilism. However, since the 1780s a growing enlightenment debate had taken hold (Bang et al., <span>1984</span>). While originally focused on freedom of speech, the debate would mature over the following century to include free market principles and nationalism infused with inspiration from German romantic ideas, particularly in saloons such as those held at Bakkehuset (Sørensen, <span>2020</span>), the residence of the Rahbek couple<sup>1</sup> who brought together the intellectuals of the time from science, literature and politics.</p><p>In the decades after the Napoleonic Wars new government reforms were initiated to incorporate and centralise Danish landholdings, especially in northern Germany, where the duchies of Schleswig and Holstein had been linked to the Danish monarch rather than the Danish realm since the late Middle Ages (Busck et al., <span>2011</span>). The efforts to reorganise Denmark from a feudal vassal state to a centralised collective state are exemplified by some of the first truly democratic institutions in Denmark, namely the local estate assemblies, which managed to increase their political influence throughout the 1830s and 1840s, often by demanding revisions to Danish mercantilist trade policies and liberalising trade reforms, despite still being within the framework of a nominally absolutist state.</p><p>Danish efforts to further centralise and tighten Denmark's grip on the Danish German-speaking duchies inevitably provoked increased nationalist sentiment in the German Confederation, leading to the First Schleswig War in 1848. What had begun as the reluctant democratisation efforts of an absolutist regime to centralise its possessions had suddenly plunged Denmark into war with Prussia and Austria (Bjørn, <span>1999</span>). While the war resulted in a reversion to the status quo after the intervention of Russia, France, and the United Kingdom in 1851, the immediate crisis led to a regime change from absolute monarchy to constitutional monarchy controlled by a democratically elected government led by the National Liberal Movement, which succeeded in adopting a national constitution in 1849 (Vammen, <span>1988</span>).</p><p>The key political victory of the new constitution was the National Liberals' amendment to change the institutional framework for Danish trade, production, and manufacturing, which was finally implemented by the Freedom of Trade Act of 1857. The Act, in practice implemented in successive rounds of reform over four years, was a radical, fundamental, and rapid switch from guild-led mercantilism to a market-economy society. Historians have often overlooked the significance of the changes brought about by these reforms. However, their importance for Denmark's later economic success cannot be overestimated. The Act changed the conditions for merchants and craftsmen, who had enjoyed extensive privileges in Danish market towns since the Middle Ages through their guilds and associations. While in principle all citizens were entitled to trade, the privileges of the guilds had in practice restricted the ability to compete and innovate (Dübeck, <span>1983</span>).</p><p>The reforms effectively abolished feudal mercantilism in Danish market towns and replaced it with free trade and competition, which in subsequent decades spurred much-needed innovation and entrepreneurship. However, the Conservatives' price for agreeing with the National Liberals was the introduction of national taxation (while the conservative aim was defence spending, they also inadvertently laid the foundations of later welfare spending growth). The national spirit was high, but it also ultimately led to a fatal underestimation of Prussia and the defeat in the Second Schleswig War in 1864, resulting in the National Liberals' loss of influence while the state apparatus was taken over by the Conservatives to the point of dictatorship. Furthermore, the populace in the cities increasingly turned to socialism in various forms. Despite political turmoil, the liberal reforms resulted in a booming economy, creating a group of urban, highly financialised global entrepreneurs like N. F. Tietgen and J. C. Jacobsen. These people used the fact, later pointed out by Paul Romer (Jones, <span>2019</span>), that ideas are a truly infinite resource: good ideas could be taken from abroad and implemented at home in global scale, a strategy which successful modern Danish companies such as Lego, Maersk, and Novo Nordisk would also eventually follow.</p><p>Building on the economic and political reforms of the mid-nineteenth century, Denmark experienced a period of relative economic prosperity in the first few decades of the twentieth century. Some of this can be attributed to the aforementioned reform efforts of the National Liberal movement. But other global trends, such as industrialisation, also found a distinctive Danish expression. One example is the Danish cooperative movement, Andelsbevægelsen. It emerged in the early 1880s as a response to the challenges posed by liberalised market forces. Danish agriculture, as in most of Western and Central Europe, was faced with the threat of cheap American grain flooding European markets (Andresen &amp; Agersnap, <span>1989</span>). Danish farmers quickly realised that they could not compete with American production or prices and instead shifted their focus from arable farming to dairy production, which was less vulnerable to American competition.</p><p>To further increase their competitiveness, Danish farmers formed small cooperatives. These cooperatives collected milk production from the surrounding area and processed it together in communal dairies. Through the sharing of production costs, the cooperatives were able to reduce costs for local dairy farmers, who could then concentrate on the quality of their products. At the same time, the pooling of resources for processing had the effect of reducing costs, which in turn both lowered prices for consumers and increased profits for farmers; thus the movement was in the spirit of a commercial society. The Danish cooperative of dairy farmers, Andelsmejerier, quickly became a success and conquered the Danish domestic market within a few years (Christensen, <span>1997</span>). The innovative organisational model in the form of cooperatives not only provided a competitive advantage in agriculture, but also quickly spread to a wide range of Danish industries, including retail and banking.</p><p>Another characteristic of Danish business in the early twentieth century, which lasted until the end of World War II, was both the idea and the practical implementation of what can be described as a kind of ‘patriotic’ corporate governance and trade, pioneered by entrepreneurs such as aforementioned Tietgen and Jacobsen (Sløk-Madsen, <span>2022</span>). It was patriotic because Danish business in the first half of the twentieth century influenced, and to some extent replaced, the Danish government in key policy areas traditionally considered nation-state concerns, such as education, public housing, social welfare, trade, and even foreign policy.</p><p>After the end of World War II, new – and fundamentally foreign – ideas took hold. Ideas of redistribution inspired by Anglo-Saxon Keynesian and Bismarckian state ideas took hold across the political spectrum, fuelled by special interest groups from both the agricultural sector and the labour movement and a population seeking a new national identity akin to what Hobsbawm and Ranger (<span>2012</span>) describe. From the 1960s public sector, tax rates, and redistribution grew enormously, made possible by the 1956 abolition of the upper house of parliament (Landstinget) and a mandatory fully implemented social security system (CPR).</p><p>The system almost broke under its own weight by the very early 1980s, summarised by the notorious statement by the Social Democratic Minister of Budget Knud Heinesen that Denmark was looking into the (economic) abyss. This dismal prospect gave rise to a period of welfare state reform led by a Conservative–Liberal government and then a coalition of the Social Democratic Party and various small centre parties. For the purpose of this article, it is important to stress two things. The right wing in this reform episode never sought to fundamentally abolish or change the universal welfare state, only to make it more efficient. At the same time the Social Democrat Party accepted the market as the only means to prosperity.</p><p>The reform agenda was pursued into the new millennium until the outbreak of Covid-19, again by both sides of the political divide. Denmark rose from the rank of 12th highest per capita GDP in OECD countries in 2000 to sixth in 2022. Today, state finances are solid. In Denmark a significant and increasing part of the economy is made up by global but old companies, while new successful companies leave. Immigration was for decades a hotly contested issue between the left and the right, but the new divide seems to be about life's purpose: do you owe the welfare state your life and body, or are they yours? A fundamentally ideological divide has hence re-emerged.</p><p>In this rapid survey of Danish economic history, we can see that many things changed. Living standards grew tremendously, and institutions were transformed, including the whole political system. Ideas emerged; some took hold and some were pushed back – communism and fascism, for instance, never had a wide appeal in Denmark. To various degrees, universalism and classical liberal ideas such as property rights, freedom of association, speech, religion and trade remained as a constant. As we indicated earlier, we will now review the five explanations and the arguments for and against them in the Danish case. Table 1 sets out our analysis.</p><p>We do not doubt the importance of institutions for enrichment. But rather than being themselves causes, they are, in the case of Denmark as in the theory of innovism, more a manifestation of prevailing rooted political ideas. The fact that institutions changed and evolved in response to changing ideas in Denmark should be seen as testimony to this understanding. We should, however, note that it is crucial to remember the importance of trust as a potential institution or norm in itself. Danes trusted that ideas and motives could be pure and not just expressions of group interests or even lies. An example would be freedom of religious organisation – including largely within the state church itself from 1856 – which was widely seen as an ideal in itself, not a desire for special rules for a specific group. Therefore, trust levels probably grew as a result of the type of ideas innovism highlights as growth enhancers, but a good base level was likely present at the outset (Bergh &amp; Bjørnskov, <span>2011</span>).</p><p>The least likely explanation for Danish prosperity remains the exploitation of the less privileged, whether at home or aboard. The working class prospered mainly from growth, not redistribution. Today, the extensive pension systems are so successful that 2 per cent of the Danish population are dollar millionaires, compared with a world average of 0.3 per cent; and 1.6 million Danes are Danish krone millionaires (CEPOS, <span>2021b</span>). As for colonies, it is questionable how much Denmark profited from these, especially if viewed as pure exploitation rather than trade. Ironically the current welfare state model arguably exploits the most productive, as 59 per cent of Danes are net recipients of transfers with 1 per cent of taxpayers paying for 10.2 per cent of public spending, and the top 10 per cent paying 31.8 per cent (CEPOS, <span>2021a</span>). Furthermore, almost two-thirds of the voters are primarily paid from public transfers from either welfare or due to employment in the public sector (CEPOS, <span>2024</span>).</p><p>Without free trade Denmark would not be rich. It is, for instance, uniquely placed to be a shipping nation and even a global top-ten shipping nation (Branch &amp; Stopford, <span>2013</span>). Denmark is a small open economy and the large successful companies, except public IT-vendors, banks and insurance, are all export- oriented. However, Denmark has been a trading region since the Stone Age (van der Sluis et al., <span>2020</span>) and this alone cannot explain the enrichment. But liberalisation of trade to a high degree can, as with the 1857 Freedom of Trade Act. Yet market liberalisation was driven to a degree by classical liberal ideals, although it was also a response to increasing spontaneous commercial activity. But both the class of urban entrepreneurs and the farm side of the cooperative movement shared classical liberal ideas which motivated them in both business and politics.</p><p>Innovism therefore stands out to us as holding the greatest explanatory power. Denmark was blessed with high literacy rates and indeed promoted this extensively until the 1970s. An early, persistent and deep-rooted liberal debate around universal rights pre-dates both institutions and prosperity quite clearly in the history of modern Denmark (Bang et al., <span>1984</span>). Liberal ideas inspired reforms which incentivised entrepreneurs to import and propagate business ideas with surprising success along the lines suggested by Romer.</p><p>Universalism also carried over into the design of the Danish welfare state. The argument for the welfare state did not purely relate to the needy, but was rather a statement that all should benefit. In that sense, Denmark also shows a less attractive side of innovism in that if ideas pre-date change, weak ideas can lead to unfortunate changes, and that might be part of the explanation of the sudden birth of the welfare state; weak but superficially attractive ideas were imported in a climate accustomed to listening to and implementing new ideas.</p><p>Finally, the last theory, the idea of a homogeneous population, is more difficult to disentangle. On some levels the population has been homogeneous, almost all being Lutheran for instance, but in terms of culture and language the picture is muddier. The Danish welfare state in its design certainly has elements of attempting to force sameness on people, as Hayek (<span>2008</span>) argued such systems would. However, today's heterogeneity in the Danish population has come from guest workers, immigrants, and refugees, and has occurred increasingly from the 1980s onward; and much of what is currently Denmark was created with the reforms after this date.</p><p>In this short essay our aim has been to present Denmark as a case to inspire. Denmark indeed appears the ideal type, the epitome of innovism. Denmark was not a consistently rich nation before a commitment was made to innovism. The country has barely any national resources, yet today it is one of the richest nations in the world. If the measure of innovism should be the accumulation of ideas, Denmark is very rich indeed; global Danish companies, such as Novo Nordisk, Lego, Carlsberg and others are all built on adapting and executing imported technological ideas. The richness of Denmark is the result of a dedication to universal ideas of human dignity and economic freedom. As such Denmark can also be a hopeful lesson for other nations. If you invest in human capital and conduct government while importing classical liberal ideas, there is precious little stopping a nation and its people from themselves setting out on the road to the ‘great enrichment’.</p><p>Denmark is not the only nation to outdo expectations; other nations like Botswana, South Korea, and Singapore also share a story of comparatively higher-than-expected riches. What such nations share is a degree of dedication to universal ideas of human dignity and economic freedom. This can be a lesson: if you invest in human capital, particularly basic reading skills, and conduct government trustingly while importing classical liberal ideas, there is precious little stopping a nation and people proceeding on the path to great enrichment.</p>\",\"PeriodicalId\":44825,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"ECONOMIC AFFAIRS\",\"volume\":\"44 2\",\"pages\":\"394-401\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":1.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2024-06-09\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/ecaf.12652\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"ECONOMIC AFFAIRS\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"91\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/ecaf.12652\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q3\",\"JCRName\":\"ECONOMICS\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"ECONOMIC AFFAIRS","FirstCategoryId":"91","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/ecaf.12652","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q3","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

为什么有些社会会从贫穷走向繁荣?所有具有社会意识的社会科学家都应该思考这个问题,尤其是我们已经看到世界各地的成功社会经历了前所未有的生活水平增长,大约从 1750 年左右的西方国家开始(McCloskey, 2010, 2021; Mokyr, 2008, 2016)。这种发展被称为 "大富裕",丹麦就是一个典型的例子(麦克洛斯基,2021 年)。人均 GDP 从 1820 年的 2,031 美元增长到 2022 年的 52,133 美元(按 2011 年美元计算;Bolt &amp; van Zanden, 2020)。有几种解释。诺贝尔奖得主道格拉斯-诺斯(Douglass North,1990 年)等制度学家认为,良好的制度是主要的解释。其他理论则强调对国内外人口和资源的开发。现代贸易理论家认为,自由贸易可以创造财富,而财富可以带来自由,自由又会带来进一步的创新。在丹麦,人口同质性也被认为可以解释这一现象。最近,一种新的解释--"创新主义"--开始流行起来。这一概念由经济史学家迪尔德丽-麦克洛斯基(Deirdre McCloskey)提出,她认为国家富裕的根本原因是古典自由主义关于尊严和自由的思想所促进的创造力,而不仅仅是资本积累。麦克洛斯基称,虽然可以通过时间观察到类似于资本主义的制度安排,但在大约 1750 年以后的时期,特别是在欧洲西北部,观察到的进步幅度之大,需要一种新的解释:创新主义。她强调,与物质主义或国家设计相比,实施促进人类行动的理想,激励思想传播和创业精神,是极大丰富的主要原因。她总结道她总结道:"创新,即创造力问题,而创造力取决于自由"(麦克洛斯基,2023 年,第 29 页)。换言之,思想的积累而非资本的积累成为关键因素。本文将探讨丹麦令人印象深刻的富裕是否真的可以用创新主义(尤其是与保罗-罗默式的将技术思想视为无限资源的思想相结合时),或者用剥削或制度设计等竞争性理论来解释:我们的文章主要基于《20 世纪的丹麦资本主义:创新型混合经济的商业史》(Sløk-Madsen,2022 年)一书背后的研究。我们认为,为了帮助更好地理解丹麦的经济发展叙事,这篇文章是必要的补充,但它之所以必要,还有另一个原因。如果正如我们所言,丹麦的非凡成功确实是由支持创新的政策选择造成的,而事先存在的资产或优势极少,那么其他国家也有很多值得学习的地方。押错(法国)马、国家破产以及海军被英国夺取,使曾经骄傲的丹麦王国面临着不复存在的真正危险。尽管失去了挪威,丹麦王国的版图仍然十分狭小,从印度一直延伸到西印度群岛,并包含数十种语言和方言。该王国唯一真正的资产是300多年来信奉路德教所带来的相对较高的识字率、强大的贸易传统和相对稳定的国家组织。然而,自 17 世纪 80 年代起,一场日益激烈的启蒙运动辩论开始占据上风(Bang 等人,1984 年)。这场争论最初集中在言论自由上,但在随后的一个世纪中逐渐发展到自由市场原则和民族主义,并从德国浪漫主义思想中汲取灵感,尤其是在沙龙中,例如在拉赫贝克夫妇1的住所巴克胡赛特(Bakkehuset)(索伦森,2020 年)举办的沙龙,他们将当时的科学、文学和政治知识分子聚集在一起。拿破仑战争后的几十年间,丹麦政府开始进行新的改革,以合并和集中丹麦的土地所有权,尤其是在德国北部,那里的石勒苏益格公国和荷尔斯泰因公国自中世纪晚期以来一直与丹麦君主而非丹麦王国保持着联系(Busck 等人,2011 年)、2011).丹麦最早的一些真正民主的机构,即地方庄园议会,体现了丹麦从封建附庸国向中央集权集体国家重组的努力,尽管这些机构仍处于名义上的专制主义国家框架内,但它们在整个 19 世纪 30 年代和 40 年代成功地提高了自己的政治影响力,通常是通过要求修改丹麦的重商主义贸易政策和进行自由化贸易改革。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
Denmark: The epitome of ‘innovism’?

Why do some societies go from poverty to prosperity? This question should occupy all socially conscious social scientists, particularly as we have seen successful societies experience unprecedented growth in living standards all over the world, beginning in the West roughly around 1750 (McCloskey, 2010, 2021; Mokyr, 2008, 2016). This development has been called the ‘great enrichment’ and Denmark is a prime example of this (McCloskey, 2021). GDP per capita grew from $2,031 in 1820 to $52,133 in 2022 (in 2011 dollars; Bolt & van Zanden, 2020).

Why did the great enrichment occur when and where it did? Several explanations exist. Institutionalists such as Nobel laureate Douglass North (1990) hold good institutions to be the main explanation. Other theories emphasise exploitation of people and resources, both domestic and foreign. Modern trade theorists argue that free trade can create wealth, which can lead to liberty which again leads to further innovation. In Denmark, population homogeneity has been argued to explain it too. Recently, though, a new explanation, that of ‘innovism’, has gained momentum. This concept, coined by the economic historian Deirdre McCloskey, suggests that the root cause of the wealth of nations is creativity fostered by classical liberal ideas about dignity and liberty, rather than simply accumulation of capital.

McCloskey claims that while institutional arrangements similar to what can be described as capitalistic can be observed through time, the sheer magnitude of improvement observed in the period from approximately 1750 onwards, and particularly, in north-western Europe, calls for a new explanation: innovism. She highlights the implementation of ideals fostering human action with incentives for idea dissemination and entrepreneurship as the key explainer of the great enrichment, more so than materialism or state design. As she concludes: “Innovism, that is, is a matter of creativity, which depends on liberty” (McCloskey, 2023, p. 29). In other words, the accumulation of ideas, rather than capital, becomes the key factor. This article investigates whether Denmark's impressive enrichment is indeed best explained by innovism, especially when coupled with Paul Romer-style thinking about technological ideas as infinite resources (Jones, 2019), or by competing theories such as exploitation or institutional design.

Our article is based mainly on the research behind the book Danish Capitalism in the 20th Century: A Business History of an Innovistic Mixed Economy (Sløk-Madsen, 2022). We think that this piece is a necessary add-on to help better understand Denmark's narrative of economic development, but it is necessary for another reason too. If, as we argue, Denmark's remarkable success is indeed explained by policy choices supporting innovism, with very few pre-existing assets or advantages, there is potentially much to learn for other nations too.

At the end of the Napoleonic Wars in 1815, the kingdom of Denmark was in a desperate state. Betting on the wrong (French) horse, a state bankruptcy, and the seizure of the navy by the British put the once-proud Danish empire in real danger of ceasing to exist. Despite the loss of Norway, the kingdom was still spread very thinly over a vast distance spanning from India to the West Indies and containing dozens of languages and dialects. The only real assets the kingdom had were relatively high literacy rates from 300 years devoted to Lutheranism, a strong trading tradition, and a relatively stable state organisation.

The nation was under absolutist government and economically stuck in a mixture of feudalism and mercantilism. However, since the 1780s a growing enlightenment debate had taken hold (Bang et al., 1984). While originally focused on freedom of speech, the debate would mature over the following century to include free market principles and nationalism infused with inspiration from German romantic ideas, particularly in saloons such as those held at Bakkehuset (Sørensen, 2020), the residence of the Rahbek couple1 who brought together the intellectuals of the time from science, literature and politics.

In the decades after the Napoleonic Wars new government reforms were initiated to incorporate and centralise Danish landholdings, especially in northern Germany, where the duchies of Schleswig and Holstein had been linked to the Danish monarch rather than the Danish realm since the late Middle Ages (Busck et al., 2011). The efforts to reorganise Denmark from a feudal vassal state to a centralised collective state are exemplified by some of the first truly democratic institutions in Denmark, namely the local estate assemblies, which managed to increase their political influence throughout the 1830s and 1840s, often by demanding revisions to Danish mercantilist trade policies and liberalising trade reforms, despite still being within the framework of a nominally absolutist state.

Danish efforts to further centralise and tighten Denmark's grip on the Danish German-speaking duchies inevitably provoked increased nationalist sentiment in the German Confederation, leading to the First Schleswig War in 1848. What had begun as the reluctant democratisation efforts of an absolutist regime to centralise its possessions had suddenly plunged Denmark into war with Prussia and Austria (Bjørn, 1999). While the war resulted in a reversion to the status quo after the intervention of Russia, France, and the United Kingdom in 1851, the immediate crisis led to a regime change from absolute monarchy to constitutional monarchy controlled by a democratically elected government led by the National Liberal Movement, which succeeded in adopting a national constitution in 1849 (Vammen, 1988).

The key political victory of the new constitution was the National Liberals' amendment to change the institutional framework for Danish trade, production, and manufacturing, which was finally implemented by the Freedom of Trade Act of 1857. The Act, in practice implemented in successive rounds of reform over four years, was a radical, fundamental, and rapid switch from guild-led mercantilism to a market-economy society. Historians have often overlooked the significance of the changes brought about by these reforms. However, their importance for Denmark's later economic success cannot be overestimated. The Act changed the conditions for merchants and craftsmen, who had enjoyed extensive privileges in Danish market towns since the Middle Ages through their guilds and associations. While in principle all citizens were entitled to trade, the privileges of the guilds had in practice restricted the ability to compete and innovate (Dübeck, 1983).

The reforms effectively abolished feudal mercantilism in Danish market towns and replaced it with free trade and competition, which in subsequent decades spurred much-needed innovation and entrepreneurship. However, the Conservatives' price for agreeing with the National Liberals was the introduction of national taxation (while the conservative aim was defence spending, they also inadvertently laid the foundations of later welfare spending growth). The national spirit was high, but it also ultimately led to a fatal underestimation of Prussia and the defeat in the Second Schleswig War in 1864, resulting in the National Liberals' loss of influence while the state apparatus was taken over by the Conservatives to the point of dictatorship. Furthermore, the populace in the cities increasingly turned to socialism in various forms. Despite political turmoil, the liberal reforms resulted in a booming economy, creating a group of urban, highly financialised global entrepreneurs like N. F. Tietgen and J. C. Jacobsen. These people used the fact, later pointed out by Paul Romer (Jones, 2019), that ideas are a truly infinite resource: good ideas could be taken from abroad and implemented at home in global scale, a strategy which successful modern Danish companies such as Lego, Maersk, and Novo Nordisk would also eventually follow.

Building on the economic and political reforms of the mid-nineteenth century, Denmark experienced a period of relative economic prosperity in the first few decades of the twentieth century. Some of this can be attributed to the aforementioned reform efforts of the National Liberal movement. But other global trends, such as industrialisation, also found a distinctive Danish expression. One example is the Danish cooperative movement, Andelsbevægelsen. It emerged in the early 1880s as a response to the challenges posed by liberalised market forces. Danish agriculture, as in most of Western and Central Europe, was faced with the threat of cheap American grain flooding European markets (Andresen & Agersnap, 1989). Danish farmers quickly realised that they could not compete with American production or prices and instead shifted their focus from arable farming to dairy production, which was less vulnerable to American competition.

To further increase their competitiveness, Danish farmers formed small cooperatives. These cooperatives collected milk production from the surrounding area and processed it together in communal dairies. Through the sharing of production costs, the cooperatives were able to reduce costs for local dairy farmers, who could then concentrate on the quality of their products. At the same time, the pooling of resources for processing had the effect of reducing costs, which in turn both lowered prices for consumers and increased profits for farmers; thus the movement was in the spirit of a commercial society. The Danish cooperative of dairy farmers, Andelsmejerier, quickly became a success and conquered the Danish domestic market within a few years (Christensen, 1997). The innovative organisational model in the form of cooperatives not only provided a competitive advantage in agriculture, but also quickly spread to a wide range of Danish industries, including retail and banking.

Another characteristic of Danish business in the early twentieth century, which lasted until the end of World War II, was both the idea and the practical implementation of what can be described as a kind of ‘patriotic’ corporate governance and trade, pioneered by entrepreneurs such as aforementioned Tietgen and Jacobsen (Sløk-Madsen, 2022). It was patriotic because Danish business in the first half of the twentieth century influenced, and to some extent replaced, the Danish government in key policy areas traditionally considered nation-state concerns, such as education, public housing, social welfare, trade, and even foreign policy.

After the end of World War II, new – and fundamentally foreign – ideas took hold. Ideas of redistribution inspired by Anglo-Saxon Keynesian and Bismarckian state ideas took hold across the political spectrum, fuelled by special interest groups from both the agricultural sector and the labour movement and a population seeking a new national identity akin to what Hobsbawm and Ranger (2012) describe. From the 1960s public sector, tax rates, and redistribution grew enormously, made possible by the 1956 abolition of the upper house of parliament (Landstinget) and a mandatory fully implemented social security system (CPR).

The system almost broke under its own weight by the very early 1980s, summarised by the notorious statement by the Social Democratic Minister of Budget Knud Heinesen that Denmark was looking into the (economic) abyss. This dismal prospect gave rise to a period of welfare state reform led by a Conservative–Liberal government and then a coalition of the Social Democratic Party and various small centre parties. For the purpose of this article, it is important to stress two things. The right wing in this reform episode never sought to fundamentally abolish or change the universal welfare state, only to make it more efficient. At the same time the Social Democrat Party accepted the market as the only means to prosperity.

The reform agenda was pursued into the new millennium until the outbreak of Covid-19, again by both sides of the political divide. Denmark rose from the rank of 12th highest per capita GDP in OECD countries in 2000 to sixth in 2022. Today, state finances are solid. In Denmark a significant and increasing part of the economy is made up by global but old companies, while new successful companies leave. Immigration was for decades a hotly contested issue between the left and the right, but the new divide seems to be about life's purpose: do you owe the welfare state your life and body, or are they yours? A fundamentally ideological divide has hence re-emerged.

In this rapid survey of Danish economic history, we can see that many things changed. Living standards grew tremendously, and institutions were transformed, including the whole political system. Ideas emerged; some took hold and some were pushed back – communism and fascism, for instance, never had a wide appeal in Denmark. To various degrees, universalism and classical liberal ideas such as property rights, freedom of association, speech, religion and trade remained as a constant. As we indicated earlier, we will now review the five explanations and the arguments for and against them in the Danish case. Table 1 sets out our analysis.

We do not doubt the importance of institutions for enrichment. But rather than being themselves causes, they are, in the case of Denmark as in the theory of innovism, more a manifestation of prevailing rooted political ideas. The fact that institutions changed and evolved in response to changing ideas in Denmark should be seen as testimony to this understanding. We should, however, note that it is crucial to remember the importance of trust as a potential institution or norm in itself. Danes trusted that ideas and motives could be pure and not just expressions of group interests or even lies. An example would be freedom of religious organisation – including largely within the state church itself from 1856 – which was widely seen as an ideal in itself, not a desire for special rules for a specific group. Therefore, trust levels probably grew as a result of the type of ideas innovism highlights as growth enhancers, but a good base level was likely present at the outset (Bergh & Bjørnskov, 2011).

The least likely explanation for Danish prosperity remains the exploitation of the less privileged, whether at home or aboard. The working class prospered mainly from growth, not redistribution. Today, the extensive pension systems are so successful that 2 per cent of the Danish population are dollar millionaires, compared with a world average of 0.3 per cent; and 1.6 million Danes are Danish krone millionaires (CEPOS, 2021b). As for colonies, it is questionable how much Denmark profited from these, especially if viewed as pure exploitation rather than trade. Ironically the current welfare state model arguably exploits the most productive, as 59 per cent of Danes are net recipients of transfers with 1 per cent of taxpayers paying for 10.2 per cent of public spending, and the top 10 per cent paying 31.8 per cent (CEPOS, 2021a). Furthermore, almost two-thirds of the voters are primarily paid from public transfers from either welfare or due to employment in the public sector (CEPOS, 2024).

Without free trade Denmark would not be rich. It is, for instance, uniquely placed to be a shipping nation and even a global top-ten shipping nation (Branch & Stopford, 2013). Denmark is a small open economy and the large successful companies, except public IT-vendors, banks and insurance, are all export- oriented. However, Denmark has been a trading region since the Stone Age (van der Sluis et al., 2020) and this alone cannot explain the enrichment. But liberalisation of trade to a high degree can, as with the 1857 Freedom of Trade Act. Yet market liberalisation was driven to a degree by classical liberal ideals, although it was also a response to increasing spontaneous commercial activity. But both the class of urban entrepreneurs and the farm side of the cooperative movement shared classical liberal ideas which motivated them in both business and politics.

Innovism therefore stands out to us as holding the greatest explanatory power. Denmark was blessed with high literacy rates and indeed promoted this extensively until the 1970s. An early, persistent and deep-rooted liberal debate around universal rights pre-dates both institutions and prosperity quite clearly in the history of modern Denmark (Bang et al., 1984). Liberal ideas inspired reforms which incentivised entrepreneurs to import and propagate business ideas with surprising success along the lines suggested by Romer.

Universalism also carried over into the design of the Danish welfare state. The argument for the welfare state did not purely relate to the needy, but was rather a statement that all should benefit. In that sense, Denmark also shows a less attractive side of innovism in that if ideas pre-date change, weak ideas can lead to unfortunate changes, and that might be part of the explanation of the sudden birth of the welfare state; weak but superficially attractive ideas were imported in a climate accustomed to listening to and implementing new ideas.

Finally, the last theory, the idea of a homogeneous population, is more difficult to disentangle. On some levels the population has been homogeneous, almost all being Lutheran for instance, but in terms of culture and language the picture is muddier. The Danish welfare state in its design certainly has elements of attempting to force sameness on people, as Hayek (2008) argued such systems would. However, today's heterogeneity in the Danish population has come from guest workers, immigrants, and refugees, and has occurred increasingly from the 1980s onward; and much of what is currently Denmark was created with the reforms after this date.

In this short essay our aim has been to present Denmark as a case to inspire. Denmark indeed appears the ideal type, the epitome of innovism. Denmark was not a consistently rich nation before a commitment was made to innovism. The country has barely any national resources, yet today it is one of the richest nations in the world. If the measure of innovism should be the accumulation of ideas, Denmark is very rich indeed; global Danish companies, such as Novo Nordisk, Lego, Carlsberg and others are all built on adapting and executing imported technological ideas. The richness of Denmark is the result of a dedication to universal ideas of human dignity and economic freedom. As such Denmark can also be a hopeful lesson for other nations. If you invest in human capital and conduct government while importing classical liberal ideas, there is precious little stopping a nation and its people from themselves setting out on the road to the ‘great enrichment’.

Denmark is not the only nation to outdo expectations; other nations like Botswana, South Korea, and Singapore also share a story of comparatively higher-than-expected riches. What such nations share is a degree of dedication to universal ideas of human dignity and economic freedom. This can be a lesson: if you invest in human capital, particularly basic reading skills, and conduct government trustingly while importing classical liberal ideas, there is precious little stopping a nation and people proceeding on the path to great enrichment.

求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
ECONOMIC AFFAIRS
ECONOMIC AFFAIRS ECONOMICS-
CiteScore
1.40
自引率
14.30%
发文量
0
期刊介绍: Economic Affairs is a journal for those interested in the application of economic principles to practical affairs. It aims to stimulate debate on economic and social problems by asking its authors, while analysing complex issues, to make their analysis and conclusions accessible to a wide audience. Each issue has a theme on which the main articles focus, providing a succinct and up-to-date review of a particular field of applied economics. Themes in 2008 included: New Perspectives on the Economics and Politics of Ageing, Housing for the Poor: the Role of Government, The Economic Analysis of Institutions, and Healthcare: State Failure. Academics are also invited to submit additional articles on subjects related to the coverage of the journal. There is section of double blind refereed articles and a section for shorter pieces that are reviewed by our Editorial Board (Economic Viewpoints). Please contact the editor for full submission details for both sections.
期刊最新文献
Introduction Issue Information Growth: A reckoning By Daniel Susskind. Allen Lane. 2024. pp. 368. £25.00 (hbk). ISBN: 978-0241542309. £10.99 (pbk). ISBN: 978-0141998718. £13.99 (ebk). ISBN: 978-0141998725 The shortest history of economics By Andrew Leigh. Old Street Publishing. 2024. pp. 228. £14.99 (hbk). ISBN: 978-1913083496. £4.99 (ebk). ISBN: 978-1913083502 The road to freedom: Economics and the good society By Joseph E Stiglitz. Allen Lane. 2024. pp. 356. £25.00 (hbk). ISBN: 978–0241687888. £13.99 (ebk). ISBN: 978-1802065367
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1