讨论

IF 7.5 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Nber Macroeconomics Annual Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI:10.1086/707180
M. Gertler
{"title":"讨论","authors":"M. Gertler","doi":"10.1086/707180","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Mark Gertler and Martin Eichenbaum followed up on comments made by one of the discussants, BenBernanke. Gertler noted that the zero lower bound (ZLB) on the nominal interest rate might have played its biggest role from late 2008 to 2010, before quantitative easing and forward guidance produced their full effects. This period was also characterized by a rise in aggregate uncertainty, he argued, which might have interacted with the binding ZLB. Gertler identified two channels through which increaseduncertainty couldhave operated. First, increasedprecautionary savings further reduce the neutral interest rate, bringing it closer to the ZLB. Second, higher uncertainty raises the spread between shortand long-term interest rates, because the ZLB creates an option value by putting a lower bound on future short-term rates. Gertler encouraged the authors to quantify these channels using theirmodel. Eichenbaumpointed out that the binding ZLB took place during a period of large changes in fiscal spending.According to theHutchins Center Fiscal ImpactMeasure, fiscal policywas strongly expansionaryuntil 2011, he argued, before turning very contractionary until 2014. Eichenbaum wondered whether the authors could investigate the interplay between fiscal policy and the ZLB by repeating their empirical exercise using the preand post-2011 subsamples. He admitted that theremight be power issues with such a short sample. The authors acknowledged that strongly countercyclical fiscal policy could in theory explain the empirical irrelevance of the ZLB that they document in the paper. However, this explanation is hard to reconcile with their evidence on the response of long-term interest rates. Fiscal policy alone could not explain why the behavior of these rates did not change during the ZLBperiod, they argued. This is suggestive of a dominant role for monetary policy in the form of quantitative easing and forward guidance, according to the authors.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"34 1","pages":"194 - 197"},"PeriodicalIF":7.5000,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/707180","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Discussion\",\"authors\":\"M. Gertler\",\"doi\":\"10.1086/707180\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"Mark Gertler and Martin Eichenbaum followed up on comments made by one of the discussants, BenBernanke. Gertler noted that the zero lower bound (ZLB) on the nominal interest rate might have played its biggest role from late 2008 to 2010, before quantitative easing and forward guidance produced their full effects. This period was also characterized by a rise in aggregate uncertainty, he argued, which might have interacted with the binding ZLB. Gertler identified two channels through which increaseduncertainty couldhave operated. First, increasedprecautionary savings further reduce the neutral interest rate, bringing it closer to the ZLB. Second, higher uncertainty raises the spread between shortand long-term interest rates, because the ZLB creates an option value by putting a lower bound on future short-term rates. Gertler encouraged the authors to quantify these channels using theirmodel. Eichenbaumpointed out that the binding ZLB took place during a period of large changes in fiscal spending.According to theHutchins Center Fiscal ImpactMeasure, fiscal policywas strongly expansionaryuntil 2011, he argued, before turning very contractionary until 2014. Eichenbaum wondered whether the authors could investigate the interplay between fiscal policy and the ZLB by repeating their empirical exercise using the preand post-2011 subsamples. He admitted that theremight be power issues with such a short sample. The authors acknowledged that strongly countercyclical fiscal policy could in theory explain the empirical irrelevance of the ZLB that they document in the paper. However, this explanation is hard to reconcile with their evidence on the response of long-term interest rates. Fiscal policy alone could not explain why the behavior of these rates did not change during the ZLBperiod, they argued. This is suggestive of a dominant role for monetary policy in the form of quantitative easing and forward guidance, according to the authors.\",\"PeriodicalId\":51680,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Nber Macroeconomics Annual\",\"volume\":\"34 1\",\"pages\":\"194 - 197\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":7.5000,\"publicationDate\":\"2020-01-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/707180\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Nber Macroeconomics Annual\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"96\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.1086/707180\",\"RegionNum\":1,\"RegionCategory\":\"经济学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q1\",\"JCRName\":\"ECONOMICS\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1086/707180","RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

马克·格特勒和马丁·艾肯鲍姆接着讨论了其中一位讨论者本·伯南克的评论。格特勒指出,名义利率的零利率下限(ZLB)可能在2008年底至2010年期间发挥了最大作用,之后量化宽松和前瞻性指引才发挥了全部作用。他认为,这一时期的另一个特点是总体不确定性上升,这可能与结合的ZLB相互作用。格特勒指出,增加的不确定性可能通过两个渠道发挥作用。首先,预防性储蓄的增加进一步降低了中性利率,使其更接近ZLB。其次,更高的不确定性提高了短期和长期利率之间的价差,因为ZLB通过设定未来短期利率的下限来创造期权价值。格特勒鼓励作者使用他们的模型来量化这些渠道。艾肯鲍姆指出,具有约束力的ZLB是在财政支出发生重大变化的时期出台的。他认为,根据哈钦斯中心财政影响衡量标准,财政政策在2011年之前是强劲扩张性的,然后在2014年之前变得非常紧缩。Eichenbaum想知道作者是否可以通过使用2011年前和之后的子样本重复他们的经验练习来研究财政政策和ZLB之间的相互作用。他承认,这么短的样本可能存在功率问题。作者承认,强有力的反周期财政政策在理论上可以解释他们在论文中记录的ZLB的经验无关性。然而,这种解释很难与他们关于长期利率反应的证据相一致。他们认为,财政政策本身并不能解释为什么这些利率在zlb期间没有发生变化。这两位作者表示,这表明货币政策将以量化宽松和前瞻性指引的形式发挥主导作用。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
Discussion
Mark Gertler and Martin Eichenbaum followed up on comments made by one of the discussants, BenBernanke. Gertler noted that the zero lower bound (ZLB) on the nominal interest rate might have played its biggest role from late 2008 to 2010, before quantitative easing and forward guidance produced their full effects. This period was also characterized by a rise in aggregate uncertainty, he argued, which might have interacted with the binding ZLB. Gertler identified two channels through which increaseduncertainty couldhave operated. First, increasedprecautionary savings further reduce the neutral interest rate, bringing it closer to the ZLB. Second, higher uncertainty raises the spread between shortand long-term interest rates, because the ZLB creates an option value by putting a lower bound on future short-term rates. Gertler encouraged the authors to quantify these channels using theirmodel. Eichenbaumpointed out that the binding ZLB took place during a period of large changes in fiscal spending.According to theHutchins Center Fiscal ImpactMeasure, fiscal policywas strongly expansionaryuntil 2011, he argued, before turning very contractionary until 2014. Eichenbaum wondered whether the authors could investigate the interplay between fiscal policy and the ZLB by repeating their empirical exercise using the preand post-2011 subsamples. He admitted that theremight be power issues with such a short sample. The authors acknowledged that strongly countercyclical fiscal policy could in theory explain the empirical irrelevance of the ZLB that they document in the paper. However, this explanation is hard to reconcile with their evidence on the response of long-term interest rates. Fiscal policy alone could not explain why the behavior of these rates did not change during the ZLBperiod, they argued. This is suggestive of a dominant role for monetary policy in the form of quantitative easing and forward guidance, according to the authors.
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
5.10
自引率
0.00%
发文量
23
期刊介绍: The Nber Macroeconomics Annual provides a forum for important debates in contemporary macroeconomics and major developments in the theory of macroeconomic analysis and policy that include leading economists from a variety of fields.
期刊最新文献
Front Matter Comment Comment Comment Comment
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1