预先包装破产的经济学

Pub Date : 2023-04-24 DOI:10.1111/jacf.12536
John J. McConnell, Henri Servaes
{"title":"预先包装破产的经济学","authors":"John J. McConnell,&nbsp;Henri Servaes","doi":"10.1111/jacf.12536","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>A new kind of bankruptcy has emerged in the last few years. It can be thought of as a “hybrid” form—one that attempts to combine the advantages (and exclude the disadvantages) of the two customary methods of reorganizing troubled companies: workouts and bankruptcy.</p><p>In a workout, a debtor that has already violated its debt covenants (or is about to do so) negotiates a relaxation or restructuring of those covenants with its creditors. In many cases, the restructuring includes an exchange of old debt securities for a package of new claims that can include debt, equity, or cash. Informal reorganizations take place outside the court system, but typically involve corporate officers, lenders, lawyers, and investment bankers. And though such negotiations are often contentious and protracted, informal workouts are widely held to be less damaging, less expensive, and, perhaps, less stressful than reorganizations under Chapter 11.1</p><p>Recently, however, a number of firms that have had most or all of the ingredients in place for a successful workout outside the courtroom have filed for bankruptcy anyway. In such cases, the distressed firms file a plan of reorganization along with their filing for bankruptcy. And largely because most creditors have agreed to the terms of the reorganization plan prior to the Chapter 11 filing, the time (and presumably the money) actually spent in Chapter 11 has been significantly reduced.2</p><p>Kroy, Inc., an Arizona-based maker of low-tech office labeling equipment, is a good example. After undergoing a leveraged buyout in 1986, the company suffered a slump in sales and profit margins that left it unable to meet its debt obligations. The company's primary lenders were the Minneapolis First Bank and Quest Equities Corporation. Both were receptive to a pre-negotiated bankruptcy reorganization. With a pre-negotiated plan in place, the company filed its plan of reorganization along with its bankruptcy petition on May 15, 1990. The company emerged from bankruptcy proceedings 89 days later. Such an untraditional reorganization has been dubbed “prepackaged bankruptcy.”3</p><p>The appearance of this new mechanism for corporate reorganization gives rise to a number of questions: How are they structured? Are they motivated by real economic gains and, if so, what are the sources of such gain? What are the particular circumstances in which a prepackaged bankruptcy is more sensible than an informal reorganization outside the courts? What does the future hold for prepackaged bankruptcy reorganizations?</p><p>The first major corporation to undergo a prepackaged bankruptcy reorganization was Crystal Oil Company, an independent crude oil and natural gas exploration and production company headquartered in Louisiana. The company filed for bankruptcy on October 1, 1986 and emerged less than three months later, its capital structure completely reorganized. The total indebtedness of the firm was reduced from $277 million to $129 million. In exchange for giving up their debt claims, debtholders received a combination of common stock, convertible notes, convertible preferred stock, and warrants to purchase common stock. Little time was spent in Chapter 11 because most major creditors had already agreed to the plan of reorganization.</p><p>The original reorganization proposal had been presented to creditors three months before the Chapter 11 filing. It was accepted by all classes of public debtholders. Within each class, more than half of the debtholders, representing more than two thirds in value of the outstanding debt, accepted the proposal. The initial plan was not accepted, however, by Crystal Oil's most senior creditors: Bankers Trust and Halliburton Company. Both of these creditors’ claims were securitized by a lien on the company's oil and gas properties. Bankers Trust accepted a revised plan, but Halliburton never gave in.4 Eventually, the bankruptcy court “crammed down” the revised plan on Halliburton.</p><p>Since its reorganization, Crystal Oil has returned to profitability and it has been able to further reduce its debt burden and continue its operations on a smaller scale.</p><p>One potential problem that can arise when a firm initiates a prepackaged bankruptcy can be illustrated with the case of Southland Corporation. In 1987, Southland, the firm that operates the 7-Eleven convenience stores, underwent a leveraged buyout to thwart a hostile takeover attempt by Samuel Belzberg. By 1989, the company could not service its $4 billion of debt and sought to restructure these claims. After 9 months of unsuccessful negotiations with creditors, Southland management concluded that the company would have to reorganize through the bankruptcy process. A prepackaged bankruptcy was proposed to resolve the impasse and Southland sent solicitations to its debtholders in early October. The bankruptcy petition was filed on October 24. Southland claimed that a sufficient number of debtholders had accepted the plan for confirmation by the court. The voting procedure, however, was challenged by a number of debtholders who were not satisfied with the outcome. Three basic objections to the voting process were raised: (1) the debtholders did not have sufficient time to cast their votes; (2) brokers often voted for their customers; (3) votes were not counted properly. The judge ruled in favor of the dissidents and the voting process was invalidated.</p><p>The Southland case illustrates that a prepackaged bankruptcy always entails the risk that dissident creditors will challenge the legitimacy of the voting process. But such challenges are not necessarily a major obstacle to prepackaged bankruptcies. Southland later sweetened its offer, which was then accepted by the majority of the debtholders. The company ended up emerging from bankruptcy in March of 1991 after a stay of only four months.</p><p>Prepackaged bankruptcy can facilitate a successful, and relatively low-cost, reorganization by forcing holdouts to accept the plan of reorganization. It also provides a means of circumventing two relatively new obstacles that have substantially dampened out-of-court exchange offers: the LTV ruling and the change in the tax code penalizing debt forgiveness.</p><p>To make use of this new “hybrid” form of bankruptcy, however, a significant fraction of creditors must be able to reach agreement outside of the court. A prepackaged bankruptcy cannot be forced on a significant number of reluctant creditors. Nevertheless, given the possibility of a pre-negotiated bankruptcy reorganization, a greater fraction of creditors may be willing to agree to the plan precisely because holdouts can be forced to participate by filing Chapter 11.</p><p>This new development has in some sense been anticipated by financial economists. Reviving and expanding upon an argument presented by Robert Haugen and Lemma Senbet in the late 70s, Michael Jensen recently suggested that the bankruptcy process can be expected to undergo a “privatization.” According to this line of thought, because private reorganizations are likely to be much less expensive than formal bankruptcy, workouts can be expected to replace bankruptcies—that is, barring major tax and legal obstacles.</p><p>Although economists did not foresee the new obstacles to workouts, the rise of prepackaged bankruptcies can be viewed as evidence in support of this privatization argument. As we suggested earlier, firms that have succeeded in prepackaging their bankruptcies have most of the elements in place necessary to reorganize successfully outside of court. Indeed, several of the prepackaged bankruptcies, including those of Republic Health and JPS, were filed after first achieving considerable progress toward an out-of-court settlement. Based on these and a growing number of other “success stories,” it seems likely that prepackaged bankruptcies will significantly speed up the process of reorganization— but, again, provided that a reasonable degree of creditor consensus can be reached informally.</p>","PeriodicalId":0,"journal":{"name":"","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-04-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/jacf.12536","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"The economics of prepackaged bankruptcy\",\"authors\":\"John J. McConnell,&nbsp;Henri Servaes\",\"doi\":\"10.1111/jacf.12536\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"<p>A new kind of bankruptcy has emerged in the last few years. It can be thought of as a “hybrid” form—one that attempts to combine the advantages (and exclude the disadvantages) of the two customary methods of reorganizing troubled companies: workouts and bankruptcy.</p><p>In a workout, a debtor that has already violated its debt covenants (or is about to do so) negotiates a relaxation or restructuring of those covenants with its creditors. In many cases, the restructuring includes an exchange of old debt securities for a package of new claims that can include debt, equity, or cash. Informal reorganizations take place outside the court system, but typically involve corporate officers, lenders, lawyers, and investment bankers. And though such negotiations are often contentious and protracted, informal workouts are widely held to be less damaging, less expensive, and, perhaps, less stressful than reorganizations under Chapter 11.1</p><p>Recently, however, a number of firms that have had most or all of the ingredients in place for a successful workout outside the courtroom have filed for bankruptcy anyway. In such cases, the distressed firms file a plan of reorganization along with their filing for bankruptcy. And largely because most creditors have agreed to the terms of the reorganization plan prior to the Chapter 11 filing, the time (and presumably the money) actually spent in Chapter 11 has been significantly reduced.2</p><p>Kroy, Inc., an Arizona-based maker of low-tech office labeling equipment, is a good example. After undergoing a leveraged buyout in 1986, the company suffered a slump in sales and profit margins that left it unable to meet its debt obligations. The company's primary lenders were the Minneapolis First Bank and Quest Equities Corporation. Both were receptive to a pre-negotiated bankruptcy reorganization. With a pre-negotiated plan in place, the company filed its plan of reorganization along with its bankruptcy petition on May 15, 1990. The company emerged from bankruptcy proceedings 89 days later. Such an untraditional reorganization has been dubbed “prepackaged bankruptcy.”3</p><p>The appearance of this new mechanism for corporate reorganization gives rise to a number of questions: How are they structured? Are they motivated by real economic gains and, if so, what are the sources of such gain? What are the particular circumstances in which a prepackaged bankruptcy is more sensible than an informal reorganization outside the courts? What does the future hold for prepackaged bankruptcy reorganizations?</p><p>The first major corporation to undergo a prepackaged bankruptcy reorganization was Crystal Oil Company, an independent crude oil and natural gas exploration and production company headquartered in Louisiana. The company filed for bankruptcy on October 1, 1986 and emerged less than three months later, its capital structure completely reorganized. The total indebtedness of the firm was reduced from $277 million to $129 million. In exchange for giving up their debt claims, debtholders received a combination of common stock, convertible notes, convertible preferred stock, and warrants to purchase common stock. Little time was spent in Chapter 11 because most major creditors had already agreed to the plan of reorganization.</p><p>The original reorganization proposal had been presented to creditors three months before the Chapter 11 filing. It was accepted by all classes of public debtholders. Within each class, more than half of the debtholders, representing more than two thirds in value of the outstanding debt, accepted the proposal. The initial plan was not accepted, however, by Crystal Oil's most senior creditors: Bankers Trust and Halliburton Company. Both of these creditors’ claims were securitized by a lien on the company's oil and gas properties. Bankers Trust accepted a revised plan, but Halliburton never gave in.4 Eventually, the bankruptcy court “crammed down” the revised plan on Halliburton.</p><p>Since its reorganization, Crystal Oil has returned to profitability and it has been able to further reduce its debt burden and continue its operations on a smaller scale.</p><p>One potential problem that can arise when a firm initiates a prepackaged bankruptcy can be illustrated with the case of Southland Corporation. In 1987, Southland, the firm that operates the 7-Eleven convenience stores, underwent a leveraged buyout to thwart a hostile takeover attempt by Samuel Belzberg. By 1989, the company could not service its $4 billion of debt and sought to restructure these claims. After 9 months of unsuccessful negotiations with creditors, Southland management concluded that the company would have to reorganize through the bankruptcy process. A prepackaged bankruptcy was proposed to resolve the impasse and Southland sent solicitations to its debtholders in early October. The bankruptcy petition was filed on October 24. Southland claimed that a sufficient number of debtholders had accepted the plan for confirmation by the court. The voting procedure, however, was challenged by a number of debtholders who were not satisfied with the outcome. Three basic objections to the voting process were raised: (1) the debtholders did not have sufficient time to cast their votes; (2) brokers often voted for their customers; (3) votes were not counted properly. The judge ruled in favor of the dissidents and the voting process was invalidated.</p><p>The Southland case illustrates that a prepackaged bankruptcy always entails the risk that dissident creditors will challenge the legitimacy of the voting process. But such challenges are not necessarily a major obstacle to prepackaged bankruptcies. Southland later sweetened its offer, which was then accepted by the majority of the debtholders. The company ended up emerging from bankruptcy in March of 1991 after a stay of only four months.</p><p>Prepackaged bankruptcy can facilitate a successful, and relatively low-cost, reorganization by forcing holdouts to accept the plan of reorganization. It also provides a means of circumventing two relatively new obstacles that have substantially dampened out-of-court exchange offers: the LTV ruling and the change in the tax code penalizing debt forgiveness.</p><p>To make use of this new “hybrid” form of bankruptcy, however, a significant fraction of creditors must be able to reach agreement outside of the court. A prepackaged bankruptcy cannot be forced on a significant number of reluctant creditors. Nevertheless, given the possibility of a pre-negotiated bankruptcy reorganization, a greater fraction of creditors may be willing to agree to the plan precisely because holdouts can be forced to participate by filing Chapter 11.</p><p>This new development has in some sense been anticipated by financial economists. Reviving and expanding upon an argument presented by Robert Haugen and Lemma Senbet in the late 70s, Michael Jensen recently suggested that the bankruptcy process can be expected to undergo a “privatization.” According to this line of thought, because private reorganizations are likely to be much less expensive than formal bankruptcy, workouts can be expected to replace bankruptcies—that is, barring major tax and legal obstacles.</p><p>Although economists did not foresee the new obstacles to workouts, the rise of prepackaged bankruptcies can be viewed as evidence in support of this privatization argument. As we suggested earlier, firms that have succeeded in prepackaging their bankruptcies have most of the elements in place necessary to reorganize successfully outside of court. Indeed, several of the prepackaged bankruptcies, including those of Republic Health and JPS, were filed after first achieving considerable progress toward an out-of-court settlement. Based on these and a growing number of other “success stories,” it seems likely that prepackaged bankruptcies will significantly speed up the process of reorganization— but, again, provided that a reasonable degree of creditor consensus can be reached informally.</p>\",\"PeriodicalId\":0,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"\",\"volume\":null,\"pages\":null},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0,\"publicationDate\":\"2023-04-24\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/jacf.12536\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jacf.12536\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jacf.12536","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

最近几年出现了一种新的破产形式。它可以被认为是一种“混合”形式——一种试图结合重组陷入困境的公司的两种传统方法的优点(并排除缺点)的形式:锻炼和破产。在解决方案中,已经违反(或即将违反)其债务契约的债务人与其债权人协商放宽或重组这些契约。在许多情况下,重组包括用旧的债务证券换取一系列新的债权,其中可能包括债务、股权或现金。非正式重组发生在法院系统之外,但通常涉及公司高管、贷款人、律师和投资银行家。尽管这种谈判往往是有争议的和旷日持久的,但人们普遍认为,非正式的解决方案比第十一章下的重组破坏性更小、成本更低,压力也更小。然而,最近,一些已经具备了在法庭外成功解决方案的大部分或全部要素的公司已经申请破产。在这种情况下,陷入困境的公司会在申请破产的同时提交重组计划。主要是因为大多数债权人在提交第11章之前就同意了重组计划的条款,所以在第11章中实际花费的时间(以及可能的资金)已经大大减少。总部位于亚利桑那州的低技术办公标签设备制造商股份有限公司2Kroy就是一个很好的例子。1986年进行杠杆收购后,该公司的销售额和利润率大幅下降,无法偿还债务。该公司的主要贷款人是明尼阿波利斯第一银行和Quest Equities Corporation。双方都接受了事先协商好的破产重组。在预先协商好的计划后,该公司于1990年5月15日提交了重组计划和破产申请。89天后,该公司摆脱了破产程序。这种非传统的重组被称为“预先打包破产”。3这种新的公司重组机制的出现引发了许多问题:它们是如何构建的?他们的动机是真正的经济收益吗?如果是,这种收益的来源是什么?在哪些特殊情况下,预先打包破产比法院外的非正式重组更明智?预先打包的破产重组的未来会怎样?第一家进行预先打包破产重组的大公司是水晶石油公司,这是一家总部位于路易斯安那州的独立原油和天然气勘探与生产公司。该公司于1986年10月1日申请破产,不到三个月后,其资本结构彻底重组。该公司的总负债从2.77亿美元减少到1.29亿美元。作为放弃债务主张的交换,债券持有人获得了普通股、可转换票据、可转换优先股和购买普通股的认股权证的组合。在第11章中花费的时间很少,因为大多数主要债权人已经同意了重组计划。最初的重组提案是在提交第11章之前三个月提交给债权人的。它被所有类别的公共债券持有人所接受。在每一类债券中,超过一半的债券持有人(占未偿债务价值的三分之二以上)接受了这一提议。然而,最初的计划没有被水晶石油最资深的债权人银行家信托和哈里伯顿公司接受。这两位债权人的债权都通过对该公司石油和天然气财产的留置权进行了证券化。Bankers Trust接受了修订后的计划,但哈里伯顿从未让步。4最终,破产法院将修订后的方案“压在”哈里伯顿身上。自重组以来,水晶石油公司已恢复盈利,并能够进一步减轻债务负担,继续小规模运营。当一家公司启动预先打包破产时可能出现的一个潜在问题可以用Southland公司的案例来说明。1987年,经营7-Eleven便利店的Southland公司进行了杠杆收购,以挫败Samuel Belzberg的恶意收购企图。到1989年,该公司无法偿还40亿美元的债务,并寻求重组这些债权。在与债权人进行了9个月的谈判后,Southland管理层得出结论,公司将不得不通过破产程序进行重组。有人提议提前打包破产以解决僵局,Southland在10月初向其债券持有人发出了邀请。破产申请于10月24日提交。Southland声称,有足够数量的债券持有人接受了该计划,以供法院确认。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
The economics of prepackaged bankruptcy

A new kind of bankruptcy has emerged in the last few years. It can be thought of as a “hybrid” form—one that attempts to combine the advantages (and exclude the disadvantages) of the two customary methods of reorganizing troubled companies: workouts and bankruptcy.

In a workout, a debtor that has already violated its debt covenants (or is about to do so) negotiates a relaxation or restructuring of those covenants with its creditors. In many cases, the restructuring includes an exchange of old debt securities for a package of new claims that can include debt, equity, or cash. Informal reorganizations take place outside the court system, but typically involve corporate officers, lenders, lawyers, and investment bankers. And though such negotiations are often contentious and protracted, informal workouts are widely held to be less damaging, less expensive, and, perhaps, less stressful than reorganizations under Chapter 11.1

Recently, however, a number of firms that have had most or all of the ingredients in place for a successful workout outside the courtroom have filed for bankruptcy anyway. In such cases, the distressed firms file a plan of reorganization along with their filing for bankruptcy. And largely because most creditors have agreed to the terms of the reorganization plan prior to the Chapter 11 filing, the time (and presumably the money) actually spent in Chapter 11 has been significantly reduced.2

Kroy, Inc., an Arizona-based maker of low-tech office labeling equipment, is a good example. After undergoing a leveraged buyout in 1986, the company suffered a slump in sales and profit margins that left it unable to meet its debt obligations. The company's primary lenders were the Minneapolis First Bank and Quest Equities Corporation. Both were receptive to a pre-negotiated bankruptcy reorganization. With a pre-negotiated plan in place, the company filed its plan of reorganization along with its bankruptcy petition on May 15, 1990. The company emerged from bankruptcy proceedings 89 days later. Such an untraditional reorganization has been dubbed “prepackaged bankruptcy.”3

The appearance of this new mechanism for corporate reorganization gives rise to a number of questions: How are they structured? Are they motivated by real economic gains and, if so, what are the sources of such gain? What are the particular circumstances in which a prepackaged bankruptcy is more sensible than an informal reorganization outside the courts? What does the future hold for prepackaged bankruptcy reorganizations?

The first major corporation to undergo a prepackaged bankruptcy reorganization was Crystal Oil Company, an independent crude oil and natural gas exploration and production company headquartered in Louisiana. The company filed for bankruptcy on October 1, 1986 and emerged less than three months later, its capital structure completely reorganized. The total indebtedness of the firm was reduced from $277 million to $129 million. In exchange for giving up their debt claims, debtholders received a combination of common stock, convertible notes, convertible preferred stock, and warrants to purchase common stock. Little time was spent in Chapter 11 because most major creditors had already agreed to the plan of reorganization.

The original reorganization proposal had been presented to creditors three months before the Chapter 11 filing. It was accepted by all classes of public debtholders. Within each class, more than half of the debtholders, representing more than two thirds in value of the outstanding debt, accepted the proposal. The initial plan was not accepted, however, by Crystal Oil's most senior creditors: Bankers Trust and Halliburton Company. Both of these creditors’ claims were securitized by a lien on the company's oil and gas properties. Bankers Trust accepted a revised plan, but Halliburton never gave in.4 Eventually, the bankruptcy court “crammed down” the revised plan on Halliburton.

Since its reorganization, Crystal Oil has returned to profitability and it has been able to further reduce its debt burden and continue its operations on a smaller scale.

One potential problem that can arise when a firm initiates a prepackaged bankruptcy can be illustrated with the case of Southland Corporation. In 1987, Southland, the firm that operates the 7-Eleven convenience stores, underwent a leveraged buyout to thwart a hostile takeover attempt by Samuel Belzberg. By 1989, the company could not service its $4 billion of debt and sought to restructure these claims. After 9 months of unsuccessful negotiations with creditors, Southland management concluded that the company would have to reorganize through the bankruptcy process. A prepackaged bankruptcy was proposed to resolve the impasse and Southland sent solicitations to its debtholders in early October. The bankruptcy petition was filed on October 24. Southland claimed that a sufficient number of debtholders had accepted the plan for confirmation by the court. The voting procedure, however, was challenged by a number of debtholders who were not satisfied with the outcome. Three basic objections to the voting process were raised: (1) the debtholders did not have sufficient time to cast their votes; (2) brokers often voted for their customers; (3) votes were not counted properly. The judge ruled in favor of the dissidents and the voting process was invalidated.

The Southland case illustrates that a prepackaged bankruptcy always entails the risk that dissident creditors will challenge the legitimacy of the voting process. But such challenges are not necessarily a major obstacle to prepackaged bankruptcies. Southland later sweetened its offer, which was then accepted by the majority of the debtholders. The company ended up emerging from bankruptcy in March of 1991 after a stay of only four months.

Prepackaged bankruptcy can facilitate a successful, and relatively low-cost, reorganization by forcing holdouts to accept the plan of reorganization. It also provides a means of circumventing two relatively new obstacles that have substantially dampened out-of-court exchange offers: the LTV ruling and the change in the tax code penalizing debt forgiveness.

To make use of this new “hybrid” form of bankruptcy, however, a significant fraction of creditors must be able to reach agreement outside of the court. A prepackaged bankruptcy cannot be forced on a significant number of reluctant creditors. Nevertheless, given the possibility of a pre-negotiated bankruptcy reorganization, a greater fraction of creditors may be willing to agree to the plan precisely because holdouts can be forced to participate by filing Chapter 11.

This new development has in some sense been anticipated by financial economists. Reviving and expanding upon an argument presented by Robert Haugen and Lemma Senbet in the late 70s, Michael Jensen recently suggested that the bankruptcy process can be expected to undergo a “privatization.” According to this line of thought, because private reorganizations are likely to be much less expensive than formal bankruptcy, workouts can be expected to replace bankruptcies—that is, barring major tax and legal obstacles.

Although economists did not foresee the new obstacles to workouts, the rise of prepackaged bankruptcies can be viewed as evidence in support of this privatization argument. As we suggested earlier, firms that have succeeded in prepackaging their bankruptcies have most of the elements in place necessary to reorganize successfully outside of court. Indeed, several of the prepackaged bankruptcies, including those of Republic Health and JPS, were filed after first achieving considerable progress toward an out-of-court settlement. Based on these and a growing number of other “success stories,” it seems likely that prepackaged bankruptcies will significantly speed up the process of reorganization— but, again, provided that a reasonable degree of creditor consensus can be reached informally.

求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1