{"title":"收获水平变化对密西西比州碳积累和木材立木价格的影响","authors":"P. Nepal, Robert K Grala, D. Grebner, R. Abt","doi":"10.5849/SJAF.12-020","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"increased demand for carbon offsets leading to higher carbon prices and, therefore, encourage forest landowners to enter into forest carbon offset contracts. As a result, qualifying forest tracts might be withdrawn from harvest during the contract leading to decreased timber supply in the short term. Timber markets will respond to such a situation with increased timber stumpage prices (Sohngen and Mendelsohn 2003, Stainback and Alavalapati 2002). However, in the long term, timber harvests might increase as carbon contracts are completed allowing landowners to harvest their forests. Consequently, timber stumpage prices would then decrease (Sohngen et al. 2008) assuming that other factors related to timber supply remain unchanged. Potential impacts of implementing carbon policies and programs on timber supply and timber stumpage prices were demonstrated by several studies. Sohngen et al. (2008) analyzed the effect of carbon policy on carbon accumulation and timber supply at the global level using the Dynamic Timber Supply Model. They showed that carbon policy would induce owners of hardwood forests in the southern United States to withhold their forests from harvest in the short term, which would result in increased timber prices. However, they also showed that additional land supply, longer rotations, and improved forest management would increase timber supply in the long term, causing timber prices eventually to fall. In another study, Sohngen and Mendelsohn (2003) indicated that implementation of the least cost strategy (minimizing the present value of the total costs of greenhouse gas damage and its abatement) to control greenhouse gases would result in global carbon sequestration of 102 billion metric tons. During the same time, global timber supply would increase by up to 785 million cubic meters (m) resulting in lower global timber prices in the long term. Other studies indicated that payments for carbon sequestered by forests will lead to longer forest rotations (Nepal et al. 2009, Sohngen et al. 2008, Gutrich and Howarth 2007, Stainback and Alavalapati 2002, van Kooten et al. 1995) and reduced timber supply in the short term (Sohngen et al. 2008, Sohngen and Mendelsohn 2003, Stainback and Alavalapati 2002). Several studies have indicated that current US carbon prices do not pay enough to make forest-based carbon sequestration financially viable (Nepal et al. 2012, Latta et al. 2011, Malmsheimer et al. 2008). Consequently, under current carbon market conditions, landowners are more likely to retain their right to sell timber rather than enroll their forest stands into carbon contracts. However, if the United States implements a mandatory carbon policy, it is expected that demand for carbon will increase leading to higher carbon prices (Green Assets 2012, US EPA 2009) and improved financial viability of forestry-based carbon sequestration strategies (Malmsheimer et al. 2008). This study investigated how future carbon accumulation in Mississippi’s forests and harvested wood products will be impacted by changes in future harvest levels during 2006–2051. In addition, the study examined the impact of such changes in harvest levels on timber stumpage prices and quantified the resulting changes in timber and carbon revenues in Mississippi. Mississippi was selected as the study area because it is considered to have a great potential to increase carbon sequestration both in standing trees and harvested wood products due to its large area under timberland (8 million ha) and a large quantity of annual timber harvest (30 million m) (USDA Forest Service 2010). Other neighboring states in the southern United States, including Alabama, Arkansas, and Louisiana, share similar forest sector characteristics such as timberland area and ownership, timber inventory, harvest levels, and timber products output (Smith et al. 2009). Therefore, we expect that our analysis of statewide impacts of harvest-level changes in Mississippi can provide useful benchmark information, not only for Mississippi, but also for these neighboring states as well as other states in the southern United States. Methods and Materials The Model The Subregional Timber Supply (SRTS) model (Abt et al. 2009) was used to examine a business-as-usual (BAU) and four alternative timber-harvest scenarios in terms of carbon accumulation, timber stumpage prices, and timber and carbon revenues in Mississippi during 2006–2051. The year 2006 was selected as a starting point for the analysis because it was the most recent year for which forest inventory data were available for Mississippi, whereas the year 2051 represents the end of harvest projection available for the BAU scenario. The SRTS is a partial market equilibrium model that combines economic and forest inventory information to determine impacts of changes in timber demand and supply on timber inventory and timber stumpage markets (Abt et al. 2009). The original version of the model was designed to simulate market for only one single product of two species groups and estimating the total timber volume for softwoods and hardwoods. The model has been updated and can be used to project timber supply for multiple products and subregions (Abt et al. 2009). The earlier versions of this timber market model were used to project timber supply in the US South and Northeast (e.g., Bingham et al. 2003, Sendak et al. 2003, Prestemon and Abt 2002, Abt et al. 2000, Pacheco et al. 1997, Abt et al. 1993). The model has also been used to project impacts of climate change on timber supply in the US South (Abt and Murray 2001) and analyze impacts of nonmarket forest values on timber supply decisions of nonindustrial private forestland (NIPF) landowners (Pattanayak et al. 2002). Modeling Timber Demand and Supply Demand for timber was modeled as a function of stumpage price and a demand shifter, whereas supply of timber was modeled as a function of stumpage price, forest inventory, and a supply shifter using the SRTS market module. The statewide equilibrium harvest in year t was determined by interaction of the following timber demand and supply functions (Abt et al. 2000):","PeriodicalId":51154,"journal":{"name":"Southern Journal of Applied Forestry","volume":"37 1","pages":"160-168"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2013-08-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.5849/SJAF.12-020","citationCount":"5","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Impact of Harvest-Level Changes on Carbon Accumulation and Timber Stumpage Prices in Mississippi\",\"authors\":\"P. Nepal, Robert K Grala, D. Grebner, R. Abt\",\"doi\":\"10.5849/SJAF.12-020\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"increased demand for carbon offsets leading to higher carbon prices and, therefore, encourage forest landowners to enter into forest carbon offset contracts. As a result, qualifying forest tracts might be withdrawn from harvest during the contract leading to decreased timber supply in the short term. Timber markets will respond to such a situation with increased timber stumpage prices (Sohngen and Mendelsohn 2003, Stainback and Alavalapati 2002). However, in the long term, timber harvests might increase as carbon contracts are completed allowing landowners to harvest their forests. Consequently, timber stumpage prices would then decrease (Sohngen et al. 2008) assuming that other factors related to timber supply remain unchanged. Potential impacts of implementing carbon policies and programs on timber supply and timber stumpage prices were demonstrated by several studies. Sohngen et al. (2008) analyzed the effect of carbon policy on carbon accumulation and timber supply at the global level using the Dynamic Timber Supply Model. They showed that carbon policy would induce owners of hardwood forests in the southern United States to withhold their forests from harvest in the short term, which would result in increased timber prices. However, they also showed that additional land supply, longer rotations, and improved forest management would increase timber supply in the long term, causing timber prices eventually to fall. In another study, Sohngen and Mendelsohn (2003) indicated that implementation of the least cost strategy (minimizing the present value of the total costs of greenhouse gas damage and its abatement) to control greenhouse gases would result in global carbon sequestration of 102 billion metric tons. During the same time, global timber supply would increase by up to 785 million cubic meters (m) resulting in lower global timber prices in the long term. Other studies indicated that payments for carbon sequestered by forests will lead to longer forest rotations (Nepal et al. 2009, Sohngen et al. 2008, Gutrich and Howarth 2007, Stainback and Alavalapati 2002, van Kooten et al. 1995) and reduced timber supply in the short term (Sohngen et al. 2008, Sohngen and Mendelsohn 2003, Stainback and Alavalapati 2002). Several studies have indicated that current US carbon prices do not pay enough to make forest-based carbon sequestration financially viable (Nepal et al. 2012, Latta et al. 2011, Malmsheimer et al. 2008). Consequently, under current carbon market conditions, landowners are more likely to retain their right to sell timber rather than enroll their forest stands into carbon contracts. However, if the United States implements a mandatory carbon policy, it is expected that demand for carbon will increase leading to higher carbon prices (Green Assets 2012, US EPA 2009) and improved financial viability of forestry-based carbon sequestration strategies (Malmsheimer et al. 2008). This study investigated how future carbon accumulation in Mississippi’s forests and harvested wood products will be impacted by changes in future harvest levels during 2006–2051. In addition, the study examined the impact of such changes in harvest levels on timber stumpage prices and quantified the resulting changes in timber and carbon revenues in Mississippi. Mississippi was selected as the study area because it is considered to have a great potential to increase carbon sequestration both in standing trees and harvested wood products due to its large area under timberland (8 million ha) and a large quantity of annual timber harvest (30 million m) (USDA Forest Service 2010). Other neighboring states in the southern United States, including Alabama, Arkansas, and Louisiana, share similar forest sector characteristics such as timberland area and ownership, timber inventory, harvest levels, and timber products output (Smith et al. 2009). Therefore, we expect that our analysis of statewide impacts of harvest-level changes in Mississippi can provide useful benchmark information, not only for Mississippi, but also for these neighboring states as well as other states in the southern United States. Methods and Materials The Model The Subregional Timber Supply (SRTS) model (Abt et al. 2009) was used to examine a business-as-usual (BAU) and four alternative timber-harvest scenarios in terms of carbon accumulation, timber stumpage prices, and timber and carbon revenues in Mississippi during 2006–2051. The year 2006 was selected as a starting point for the analysis because it was the most recent year for which forest inventory data were available for Mississippi, whereas the year 2051 represents the end of harvest projection available for the BAU scenario. The SRTS is a partial market equilibrium model that combines economic and forest inventory information to determine impacts of changes in timber demand and supply on timber inventory and timber stumpage markets (Abt et al. 2009). The original version of the model was designed to simulate market for only one single product of two species groups and estimating the total timber volume for softwoods and hardwoods. The model has been updated and can be used to project timber supply for multiple products and subregions (Abt et al. 2009). The earlier versions of this timber market model were used to project timber supply in the US South and Northeast (e.g., Bingham et al. 2003, Sendak et al. 2003, Prestemon and Abt 2002, Abt et al. 2000, Pacheco et al. 1997, Abt et al. 1993). The model has also been used to project impacts of climate change on timber supply in the US South (Abt and Murray 2001) and analyze impacts of nonmarket forest values on timber supply decisions of nonindustrial private forestland (NIPF) landowners (Pattanayak et al. 2002). Modeling Timber Demand and Supply Demand for timber was modeled as a function of stumpage price and a demand shifter, whereas supply of timber was modeled as a function of stumpage price, forest inventory, and a supply shifter using the SRTS market module. The statewide equilibrium harvest in year t was determined by interaction of the following timber demand and supply functions (Abt et al. 2000):\",\"PeriodicalId\":51154,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Southern Journal of Applied Forestry\",\"volume\":\"37 1\",\"pages\":\"160-168\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2013-08-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.5849/SJAF.12-020\",\"citationCount\":\"5\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Southern Journal of Applied Forestry\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.5849/SJAF.12-020\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Southern Journal of Applied Forestry","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.5849/SJAF.12-020","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
摘要
对碳补偿的需求增加导致碳价格上涨,因此鼓励森林土地所有者签订森林碳补偿合同。因此,符合条件的林区可能在合同期间停止采伐,导致短期内木材供应减少。木材市场将对这种情况作出反应,增加木材立木价格(Sohngen和Mendelsohn 2003年,Stainback和Alavalapati 2002年)。然而,从长远来看,随着碳合同的完成,允许土地所有者采伐他们的森林,木材采伐可能会增加。因此,假设与木材供应相关的其他因素保持不变,那么木材立木价格将会下降(Sohngen et al. 2008)。几项研究证明了实施碳政策和计划对木材供应和木材立木价格的潜在影响。Sohngen等人(2008)利用动态木材供应模型分析了碳政策对全球碳积累和木材供应的影响。他们表明,碳政策将诱使美国南部阔叶林的所有者在短期内停止砍伐他们的森林,这将导致木材价格上涨。但是,它们也表明,从长远来看,增加土地供应、延长轮伐时间和改善森林管理将增加木材供应,导致木材价格最终下降。在另一项研究中,Sohngen和Mendelsohn(2003)指出,实施最低成本策略(使温室气体损害及其减排的总成本的现值最小化)来控制温室气体将导致全球碳封存1020亿公吨。与此同时,全球木材供应将增加7.85亿立方米,导致全球木材价格长期下降。其他研究表明,对森林固碳的支付将导致更长的森林轮作(Nepal et al. 2009, Sohngen et al. 2008, Gutrich and Howarth 2007, Stainback and Alavalapati 2002, van Kooten et al. 1995),并在短期内减少木材供应(Sohngen et al. 2008, Sohngen and Mendelsohn 2003, Stainback and Alavalapati 2002)。几项研究表明,目前美国的碳价格不足以使基于森林的碳封存在经济上可行(Nepal et al. 2012, Latta et al. 2011, Malmsheimer et al. 2008)。因此,在目前的碳市场条件下,土地所有者更有可能保留其出售木材的权利,而不是将其林分纳入碳合同。然而,如果美国实施强制性碳政策,预计碳需求将增加,导致碳价格上涨(Green Assets 2012, US EPA 2009),并提高基于林业的碳封存战略的财务可行性(Malmsheimer et al. 2008)。本研究调查了2006-2051年间未来采伐水平的变化如何影响密西西比州森林和采伐木材产品的未来碳积累。此外,该研究还调查了采伐水平的变化对树桩价格的影响,并量化了密西西比州木材和碳收入的变化。密西西比州之所以被选为研究区域,是因为由于其林地面积大(800万公顷),年木材采伐量大(3000万平方米),因此被认为具有增加直立树木和采伐木材产品碳固存的巨大潜力(美国农业部林业局2010年)。美国南部的其他邻近州,包括阿拉巴马州、阿肯色州和路易斯安那州,也具有类似的森林部门特征,如林地面积和所有权、木材库存、采伐水平和木材产品产量(Smith et al. 2009)。因此,我们期望我们对密西西比州收获水平变化的全州影响的分析不仅可以为密西西比州,而且可以为这些邻近州以及美国南部的其他州提供有用的基准信息。本研究采用分区域木材供应(SRTS)模型(Abt et al. 2009),从2006-2051年密西西比州的碳积累、木材立木价格以及木材和碳收入等方面考察了照常经营(BAU)和四种替代木材采伐情景。选择2006年作为分析的起点,因为这是密西西比州可获得森林清查数据的最近一年,而2051年代表BAU情景中可获得的收获预测的结束。SRTS是一个部分市场均衡模型,它结合了经济和森林清查信息,以确定木材需求和供应变化对木材清查和木材立木市场的影响(Abt et al. 2009)。 该模型的最初版本是为了模拟两个物种组中单一产品的市场,并估计软木和硬木的总材积。该模型已经更新,可用于预测多种产品和分区域的木材供应(Abt等人,2009)。该木材市场模型的早期版本被用于预测美国南部和东北部的木材供应(例如,Bingham等人,2003年,Sendak等人,2003年,Prestemon和Abt 2002年,Abt等人,2000年,Pacheco等人,1997年,Abt等人,1993年)。该模型还被用于预测气候变化对美国南部木材供应的影响(Abt and Murray 2001),并分析非市场森林价值对非工业私有林地(NIPF)土地所有者木材供应决策的影响(Pattanayak et al. 2002)。木材需求和供给建模木材需求建模为立木价格和需求转移函数的函数,而木材供应建模为立木价格、森林库存和使用SRTS市场模块的供应转移函数。第t年的全州平衡收获是由以下木材需求和供应函数的相互作用决定的(Abt et al. 2000):
Impact of Harvest-Level Changes on Carbon Accumulation and Timber Stumpage Prices in Mississippi
increased demand for carbon offsets leading to higher carbon prices and, therefore, encourage forest landowners to enter into forest carbon offset contracts. As a result, qualifying forest tracts might be withdrawn from harvest during the contract leading to decreased timber supply in the short term. Timber markets will respond to such a situation with increased timber stumpage prices (Sohngen and Mendelsohn 2003, Stainback and Alavalapati 2002). However, in the long term, timber harvests might increase as carbon contracts are completed allowing landowners to harvest their forests. Consequently, timber stumpage prices would then decrease (Sohngen et al. 2008) assuming that other factors related to timber supply remain unchanged. Potential impacts of implementing carbon policies and programs on timber supply and timber stumpage prices were demonstrated by several studies. Sohngen et al. (2008) analyzed the effect of carbon policy on carbon accumulation and timber supply at the global level using the Dynamic Timber Supply Model. They showed that carbon policy would induce owners of hardwood forests in the southern United States to withhold their forests from harvest in the short term, which would result in increased timber prices. However, they also showed that additional land supply, longer rotations, and improved forest management would increase timber supply in the long term, causing timber prices eventually to fall. In another study, Sohngen and Mendelsohn (2003) indicated that implementation of the least cost strategy (minimizing the present value of the total costs of greenhouse gas damage and its abatement) to control greenhouse gases would result in global carbon sequestration of 102 billion metric tons. During the same time, global timber supply would increase by up to 785 million cubic meters (m) resulting in lower global timber prices in the long term. Other studies indicated that payments for carbon sequestered by forests will lead to longer forest rotations (Nepal et al. 2009, Sohngen et al. 2008, Gutrich and Howarth 2007, Stainback and Alavalapati 2002, van Kooten et al. 1995) and reduced timber supply in the short term (Sohngen et al. 2008, Sohngen and Mendelsohn 2003, Stainback and Alavalapati 2002). Several studies have indicated that current US carbon prices do not pay enough to make forest-based carbon sequestration financially viable (Nepal et al. 2012, Latta et al. 2011, Malmsheimer et al. 2008). Consequently, under current carbon market conditions, landowners are more likely to retain their right to sell timber rather than enroll their forest stands into carbon contracts. However, if the United States implements a mandatory carbon policy, it is expected that demand for carbon will increase leading to higher carbon prices (Green Assets 2012, US EPA 2009) and improved financial viability of forestry-based carbon sequestration strategies (Malmsheimer et al. 2008). This study investigated how future carbon accumulation in Mississippi’s forests and harvested wood products will be impacted by changes in future harvest levels during 2006–2051. In addition, the study examined the impact of such changes in harvest levels on timber stumpage prices and quantified the resulting changes in timber and carbon revenues in Mississippi. Mississippi was selected as the study area because it is considered to have a great potential to increase carbon sequestration both in standing trees and harvested wood products due to its large area under timberland (8 million ha) and a large quantity of annual timber harvest (30 million m) (USDA Forest Service 2010). Other neighboring states in the southern United States, including Alabama, Arkansas, and Louisiana, share similar forest sector characteristics such as timberland area and ownership, timber inventory, harvest levels, and timber products output (Smith et al. 2009). Therefore, we expect that our analysis of statewide impacts of harvest-level changes in Mississippi can provide useful benchmark information, not only for Mississippi, but also for these neighboring states as well as other states in the southern United States. Methods and Materials The Model The Subregional Timber Supply (SRTS) model (Abt et al. 2009) was used to examine a business-as-usual (BAU) and four alternative timber-harvest scenarios in terms of carbon accumulation, timber stumpage prices, and timber and carbon revenues in Mississippi during 2006–2051. The year 2006 was selected as a starting point for the analysis because it was the most recent year for which forest inventory data were available for Mississippi, whereas the year 2051 represents the end of harvest projection available for the BAU scenario. The SRTS is a partial market equilibrium model that combines economic and forest inventory information to determine impacts of changes in timber demand and supply on timber inventory and timber stumpage markets (Abt et al. 2009). The original version of the model was designed to simulate market for only one single product of two species groups and estimating the total timber volume for softwoods and hardwoods. The model has been updated and can be used to project timber supply for multiple products and subregions (Abt et al. 2009). The earlier versions of this timber market model were used to project timber supply in the US South and Northeast (e.g., Bingham et al. 2003, Sendak et al. 2003, Prestemon and Abt 2002, Abt et al. 2000, Pacheco et al. 1997, Abt et al. 1993). The model has also been used to project impacts of climate change on timber supply in the US South (Abt and Murray 2001) and analyze impacts of nonmarket forest values on timber supply decisions of nonindustrial private forestland (NIPF) landowners (Pattanayak et al. 2002). Modeling Timber Demand and Supply Demand for timber was modeled as a function of stumpage price and a demand shifter, whereas supply of timber was modeled as a function of stumpage price, forest inventory, and a supply shifter using the SRTS market module. The statewide equilibrium harvest in year t was determined by interaction of the following timber demand and supply functions (Abt et al. 2000):