Socially Useless? The Crucial Contribution of Finance to Economic Life

P. Booth, Diego Zuluaga
{"title":"Socially Useless? The Crucial Contribution of Finance to Economic Life","authors":"P. Booth, Diego Zuluaga","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3853681","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Animosity towards the business of finance is ancient and persistent. Because finance creates intangible value, its contribution to society is still invisible to many observers – including former regulator Lord Turner, who described large swathes of the sector as ‘socially useless’. \n \nSuch claims are unfounded and dangerous. Not only that, but the often-proposed remedy – increased statutory regulation – may heighten rather than mitigate the exposure of taxpayers and households to recessions and speculative bubbles. \n \nFinancial firms serve many useful functions which individuals and households could scarcely undertake on their own. These functions include maturity transformation, matching lenders and borrowers at low cost, facilitating the transfer of risk and consumption across time and between people, monitoring, and diversification of investments. \n \nThe best analogy for the financial sector is probably supermarkets. It would be possible to prepare dinner by visiting a chicken farmer to buy a chicken, a market gardener to buy a cabbage, and so on. But such a process would be very time-consuming and involve high opportunity costs. Banks reduce the transaction costs of financial activity, enabling people to spend their time more productively. \n \nGross value added (GVA) by the UK financial sector amounted to £124 billion in 2016. Of this, 50 per cent is exported. Contrary to the claims of critics, the sales and trading activity which is alleged to be self-serving accounts at most for 10 to 13 per cent of financial services business in Britain. \n \nIt is often argued that private-sector finance is short-term oriented. Whilst there is some evidence that shareholders may be heavily discounting distant profits, the reasons for this could be policy uncertainty and not irrationality as is commonly suggested. Moreover, the valuations of tech firms – whose positive cash flows lie far in the future – and low yields on corporate bonds suggest that investors are patient by historical standards. \n \nMuch financial regulation is based on the notion that, in a free market, providers ‘dupe’ consumers. But regulatory intervention is often grossly miscalculated. The Financial Conduct Authority’s recent interest cap on payday loans shrank the market by between three and five times more than the regulator expected. Markets are not perfect, but regulation is often a very poor substitute. \n \nThe much-cited literature linking financial growth and adverse economic outcomes is simply too crude to warrant drawing clear policy conclusions. Studies linking financialisation with inequality are similarly ambiguous: \nthe top ten countries for their share of finance in GDP are a mixture of high-, medium- and low-inequality countries. \n \nComplex financial instruments and speculation, both unpopular in the wake of the 2008 crash, are not harmful on their own. In fact they help to transfer risks to those who can best bear it, whilst giving greater income certainty to vulnerable people. Until and unless the value of finance is properly understood, public policy will fail to harness its benefits and may well endanger public welfare.","PeriodicalId":174628,"journal":{"name":"English Law: Business (Topic)","volume":"9 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2018-02-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"1","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"English Law: Business (Topic)","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3853681","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

Abstract

Animosity towards the business of finance is ancient and persistent. Because finance creates intangible value, its contribution to society is still invisible to many observers – including former regulator Lord Turner, who described large swathes of the sector as ‘socially useless’. Such claims are unfounded and dangerous. Not only that, but the often-proposed remedy – increased statutory regulation – may heighten rather than mitigate the exposure of taxpayers and households to recessions and speculative bubbles. Financial firms serve many useful functions which individuals and households could scarcely undertake on their own. These functions include maturity transformation, matching lenders and borrowers at low cost, facilitating the transfer of risk and consumption across time and between people, monitoring, and diversification of investments. The best analogy for the financial sector is probably supermarkets. It would be possible to prepare dinner by visiting a chicken farmer to buy a chicken, a market gardener to buy a cabbage, and so on. But such a process would be very time-consuming and involve high opportunity costs. Banks reduce the transaction costs of financial activity, enabling people to spend their time more productively. Gross value added (GVA) by the UK financial sector amounted to £124 billion in 2016. Of this, 50 per cent is exported. Contrary to the claims of critics, the sales and trading activity which is alleged to be self-serving accounts at most for 10 to 13 per cent of financial services business in Britain. It is often argued that private-sector finance is short-term oriented. Whilst there is some evidence that shareholders may be heavily discounting distant profits, the reasons for this could be policy uncertainty and not irrationality as is commonly suggested. Moreover, the valuations of tech firms – whose positive cash flows lie far in the future – and low yields on corporate bonds suggest that investors are patient by historical standards. Much financial regulation is based on the notion that, in a free market, providers ‘dupe’ consumers. But regulatory intervention is often grossly miscalculated. The Financial Conduct Authority’s recent interest cap on payday loans shrank the market by between three and five times more than the regulator expected. Markets are not perfect, but regulation is often a very poor substitute. The much-cited literature linking financial growth and adverse economic outcomes is simply too crude to warrant drawing clear policy conclusions. Studies linking financialisation with inequality are similarly ambiguous: the top ten countries for their share of finance in GDP are a mixture of high-, medium- and low-inequality countries. Complex financial instruments and speculation, both unpopular in the wake of the 2008 crash, are not harmful on their own. In fact they help to transfer risks to those who can best bear it, whilst giving greater income certainty to vulnerable people. Until and unless the value of finance is properly understood, public policy will fail to harness its benefits and may well endanger public welfare.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
对社会无益?金融对经济生活的重要贡献
对金融业的敌意由来已久。由于金融创造了无形的价值,它对社会的贡献对许多观察者来说仍然是不可见的——包括前监管机构特纳勋爵(Lord Turner),他将该行业的大片领域描述为“对社会无用”。这种说法毫无根据,而且很危险。不仅如此,经常提出的补救措施——加强法定监管——可能会加重而不是减轻纳税人和家庭在衰退和投机泡沫中的风险敞口。金融公司提供了许多个人和家庭几乎无法独自承担的有用功能。这些功能包括期限转换,以低成本匹配贷方和借款人,促进风险和消费的跨时间和人与人之间的转移,监测和多样化投资。对金融部门来说,最好的类比可能是超市。准备晚餐时,可以去拜访养鸡场买一只鸡,去市场园丁买一棵卷心菜,等等。但这一过程将非常耗时,并且涉及很高的机会成本。银行降低了金融活动的交易成本,使人们能够更有效地利用时间。2016年,英国金融部门的总增加值(GVA)达到1240亿英镑。其中,50%用于出口。与批评人士的说法相反,被指为自私自利的销售和交易活动至多占英国金融服务业务的10%至13%。人们常常认为,私营部门的融资是短期导向的。虽然有一些证据表明,股东可能会严重低估远期利润,但其原因可能是政策的不确定性,而不是通常认为的非理性。此外,科技公司的估值——它们的正现金流是遥远的未来——和公司债券的低收益率表明,以历史标准衡量,投资者是有耐心的。许多金融监管都是基于这样一种观念:在自由市场中,供应商会“欺骗”消费者。但监管干预往往被严重误判。英国金融市场行为监管局(Financial Conduct Authority)最近对发薪日贷款设定的利息上限,令市场萎缩的幅度是该监管机构预期的3至5倍。市场并不完美,但监管往往是一个非常糟糕的替代品。那些被广泛引用的将金融增长与不利经济结果联系在一起的文献过于粗糙,不足以得出明确的政策结论。将金融化与不平等联系起来的研究同样含糊不清:金融在GDP中所占份额最高的10个国家,既有高不平等国家,也有中等不平等国家和低不平等国家。复杂的金融工具和投机在2008年金融危机之后都不受欢迎,但它们本身并没有害处。事实上,它们有助于将风险转移给最能承受风险的人,同时为弱势群体提供更大的收入确定性。除非人们正确理解金融的价值,否则公共政策将无法利用金融带来的好处,而且很可能危及公共福利。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
COVID-19: Assessing Some Potential Global Economic, Business and Legal Impacts The Pursuit to Defeat Underwriter Opportunism: A Comparative Analysis of Combating Misconduct in the Claims Process The Impact of Case Law on the Duty of Trust and Confidence in the English Legal System Parent Company Direct Liability for Overseas Human Rights Violations: Lessons from the UK Supreme Court Applying Economics to the Internet: Can Regulators and Competition Authorities Keep Pace?
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1