Comparing Fundamentals of Additive and Multiplicative Aggregation in Ratio Scale Multi-Criteria Decision Making

E. U. Choo, W. Wedley
{"title":"Comparing Fundamentals of Additive and Multiplicative Aggregation in Ratio Scale Multi-Criteria Decision Making","authors":"E. U. Choo, W. Wedley","doi":"10.2174/1874243200802010001","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Additive and multiplicative aggregations of ratio scale preferences are frequently used in multi-criteria decision making models. In this paper, we compare the advantages and limitations of these two aggregation rules by exploring only their fundamental properties after ratio scaled local priorities and criteria weights have been successfully generated from the decision maker. The comparisons of these properties are therefore independent of ancillary procedures such as interac- tive elicitations from decision makers, pairwise comparisons and calculations of local priorities and criteria weights. We compare six fundamental properties of the two aggregation rules. The criteria weights used in the multiplicative aggrega- tion have complicated meanings which are not well understood and often mixed up in the ambiguous notion of \"criteria importance\". As the scaling factors of the local preference values do not appear explicitly in the computations of the rela- tive ratios of the overall preferences in the multiplicative aggregation model, the relative ratios remain unchanged when the scaling factors are changed or an alternative is added or deleted. Furthermore, the relative ratios in the multiplicative aggregation do not depend on similar local preference values which cancel each other out mathematically. It is quite evi- dent that the additive aggregation model is superior and easier for decision makers to use and understand. We recommend the additive aggregation rule over the multiplicative aggregation rule. Fundamental basic elements of the MCDM framework are first depicted without any specific interpretations im- posed on these elements. It is assumed that no relevant crite- rion is missed and each criterion is autonomous. In section 3, the measures of criteria weight, local and overall preferences are assumed to be in ratio scale. Some necessary conditions and the role of normalization are discussed. We then give a brief literature review, with particular attention to the differ- ent ancillary procedures and contradicting opinions in model interpretations. Additive and multiplicative aggregation rules are formally introduced in Section 5. In Section 6, we elabo- rate and compare the fundamental properties of these aggre- gation rules. Finally, we summarize and give some conclu- sions. 2. BASIC ELEMENTS OF MCDM MODEL The basic elements of a typical MCDM model include a set A={A1,A2,…,An} of n alternatives A1,A2,…,An and a set C={C1,C2,…,Cm} of m criteria C1,C2,…,Cm. The effect of the criteria C1,C2,…,Cm in C is represented by positive num- bers w1,w2,…,wm respectively. The vector w=(w1,w2,…,wm) is called the criteria weight vector of the criteria C1,C2,…,Cm in C. The criteria weight vector w is derived from question- ing the DM. The alternatives A1,A2,…,An can be evaluated under each individual criterion Cp, p=1,2,…,m. For each criterion Cp (p=1,2,…,m), the local preference of the alterna- tives A1,A2,…,An in A with respect to Cp is represented by positive numbers x1p,x2p,…,xnp, respectively. The vector xp=(x1p,x2p,…,xnp) is called the local preference vector of the alternatives A1,A2,…,An in A with respect to Cp. The local preference vectors x1,x2,…,xm are derived from questioning the DM.","PeriodicalId":337071,"journal":{"name":"The Open Operational Research Journal","volume":"54 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2008-02-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"34","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"The Open Operational Research Journal","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2174/1874243200802010001","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 34

Abstract

Additive and multiplicative aggregations of ratio scale preferences are frequently used in multi-criteria decision making models. In this paper, we compare the advantages and limitations of these two aggregation rules by exploring only their fundamental properties after ratio scaled local priorities and criteria weights have been successfully generated from the decision maker. The comparisons of these properties are therefore independent of ancillary procedures such as interac- tive elicitations from decision makers, pairwise comparisons and calculations of local priorities and criteria weights. We compare six fundamental properties of the two aggregation rules. The criteria weights used in the multiplicative aggrega- tion have complicated meanings which are not well understood and often mixed up in the ambiguous notion of "criteria importance". As the scaling factors of the local preference values do not appear explicitly in the computations of the rela- tive ratios of the overall preferences in the multiplicative aggregation model, the relative ratios remain unchanged when the scaling factors are changed or an alternative is added or deleted. Furthermore, the relative ratios in the multiplicative aggregation do not depend on similar local preference values which cancel each other out mathematically. It is quite evi- dent that the additive aggregation model is superior and easier for decision makers to use and understand. We recommend the additive aggregation rule over the multiplicative aggregation rule. Fundamental basic elements of the MCDM framework are first depicted without any specific interpretations im- posed on these elements. It is assumed that no relevant crite- rion is missed and each criterion is autonomous. In section 3, the measures of criteria weight, local and overall preferences are assumed to be in ratio scale. Some necessary conditions and the role of normalization are discussed. We then give a brief literature review, with particular attention to the differ- ent ancillary procedures and contradicting opinions in model interpretations. Additive and multiplicative aggregation rules are formally introduced in Section 5. In Section 6, we elabo- rate and compare the fundamental properties of these aggre- gation rules. Finally, we summarize and give some conclu- sions. 2. BASIC ELEMENTS OF MCDM MODEL The basic elements of a typical MCDM model include a set A={A1,A2,…,An} of n alternatives A1,A2,…,An and a set C={C1,C2,…,Cm} of m criteria C1,C2,…,Cm. The effect of the criteria C1,C2,…,Cm in C is represented by positive num- bers w1,w2,…,wm respectively. The vector w=(w1,w2,…,wm) is called the criteria weight vector of the criteria C1,C2,…,Cm in C. The criteria weight vector w is derived from question- ing the DM. The alternatives A1,A2,…,An can be evaluated under each individual criterion Cp, p=1,2,…,m. For each criterion Cp (p=1,2,…,m), the local preference of the alterna- tives A1,A2,…,An in A with respect to Cp is represented by positive numbers x1p,x2p,…,xnp, respectively. The vector xp=(x1p,x2p,…,xnp) is called the local preference vector of the alternatives A1,A2,…,An in A with respect to Cp. The local preference vectors x1,x2,…,xm are derived from questioning the DM.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
比率尺度多准则决策中加性聚合与乘性聚合的基础比较
比率尺度偏好的加性和乘性聚合在多准则决策模型中经常被使用。在本文中,我们通过对两种聚合规则的基本性质的研究,比较了这两种聚合规则的优点和局限性,并成功地从决策者那里生成了比例缩放的局部优先级和标准权重。因此,这些属性的比较是独立于辅助程序的,如决策者的交互引出,两两比较以及局部优先级和标准权重的计算。我们比较了这两种聚合规则的六个基本性质。在乘法聚合中使用的标准权重具有复杂的含义,这些含义不被很好地理解,并且经常混淆在“标准重要性”的模糊概念中。在乘法聚合模型中,由于局部偏好值的比例因子没有明确地出现在总体偏好相对比率的计算中,因此,当比例因子发生变化或增加或删除一个备选方案时,相对比率保持不变。此外,乘法聚合中的相对比率不依赖于相似的局部偏好值,这些偏好值在数学上相互抵消。结果表明,加性聚合模型具有较好的优越性,便于决策者使用和理解。我们建议使用加法聚合规则,而不是乘法聚合规则。首先描述了MCDM框架的基本元素,而没有对这些元素进行任何具体的解释。假设没有遗漏任何相关的准则,并且每个准则都是自治的。在第3节中,假定标准权重、局部偏好和总体偏好的度量为比例尺度。讨论了规范化的必要条件和作用。然后,我们给出了一个简短的文献综述,特别注意不同的辅助程序和矛盾的意见,在模型解释。第5节正式介绍了加法和乘法聚合规则。在第6节中,我们阐述并比较了这些聚合规则的基本性质。最后,对全文进行了总结,并给出了一些结论。2. 典型MCDM模型的基本元素包括n个备选项A1,A2,…,An的集合a ={A1,A2,…,An}和m个准则C1,C2,…,Cm的集合C={C1,C2,…,Cm}。标准C1,C2,…,Cm在C中的作用分别用正数w1,w2,…,wm表示。向量w=(w1,w2,…,wm)被称为c中标准C1,C2,…,Cm的标准权重向量。标准权重向量w来源于对DM的质疑。选择A1,A2,…,An可以在每个单独的标准Cp, p=1,2,…,m下进行评估。对于每个准则Cp (p=1,2,…,m), A中的备选方案A1,A2,…,An相对于Cp的局部偏好分别用正数x1p,x2p,…,xnp表示。向量xp=(x1p,x2p,…,xnp)称为A中A1,A2,…,An相对于Cp的局部偏好向量。局部偏好向量x1,x2,…,xm是通过对DM的质疑得到的。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
Modeling and Analysis of the Queue Dynamics in the Nigerian Voting System On Multiobjective Duality For Variational Problems Two-Machine Flow-Shop Scheduling with Job Delivery Coordination Mean Value Cross Decomposition for Two-Stage Stochastic Linear Programming with Recourse Fuzzy Ant Colony Paradigm for Virtual Pedestrian Simulation
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1