{"title":"Trade Arrangements and Interlinked Credit in the Philippines","authors":"M. Hendriks, F. Bouman, O. Hospes","doi":"10.4324/9780429038891-13","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Land reforms and the Green Revolution with its capital-intensive agricultural technology have increased the importance of informal lenders in many low-income countries, including traders of food products, input dealers, rich farmer-lenders, rice millers and store owners. As a result, informal financial intermediaries have received growing attention from researchers and policymakers, particularly in the Philippines (Agabin et al. 1989; Lamberte and Lim 1987; TBAC 1989). However, in spite of the growing number of (predominantly economic) studies, evaluations of the role of the new financiers still lack detailed, empirical data on their methods of working, their relationships with borrowers, and the different socio-economic and cultural contexts in which they operate. This chapter wants to contribute to a better understanding of these methods, relationships and contexts. For this purpose, I describe credit relations in the production and marketing of vegetables in the central Philippines, taking into account their diversity and contexts. My analysis provides insights into the interdependency of lenders and borrowers, the interweaving of trade and credit transactions, and the cultural and economic backgrounds of the combined strategy of spreading of risks and profit-seeking. It highlights personalized relations of exchange in vegetable marketing, called suki, and the flexible ways in which vegetable traders make use of these relations. Socio-economic factors, the normative environment, specific features of commodities and power conflicts affect opportunities and constraints in the vegetable market, and consequently, suki as a normative construct of individual traders and farmers, has different meanings. High risks are common to credit extension in the production and marketing of agricultural products in the Philippines. While neither the commercial banks nor the Philippines’ cooperative sector have proved wellequipped for lending to small farmers, the need for production capital has increased considerably due to the introduction of new HYV technology. With the failure of government programs and the withdrawal of landlords from the credit sphere, the informal finance circuit has extended and diversified since the mid 1970s. Traders and processors of farm produce, dealers in farm inputs, and rich farmers, offer production loans, together with a host of local middlemen in the credit chain from village to city and back, replacing patron-client relations with landlords (Sacay et al. 1985; TBAC 1981). Peasant agriculture faces further risks and uncertainty because of climatic factors, seasonality of production, changes in consumer preferences, and dependency in land use relations. Trade in agricultural products is similarly risky, and costs of transportation, storage, processing and information are high. Earlier studies show that informal lenders reduce risks and costs by operating in more than one market through interlinked deals (Floro 1987; Geron 1989). For instance, a person engages in the sale of farm inputs, the milling of rice, the purchase of farm products, the finance of production, all with the same farmer. The literature on India is particularly extensive (Bharadway 1985; Bhaduri 1983; Braverman and Stiglitz 1982). Vertical integration appears as a profit strategy and a way of extracting surplus from poor farmers, since the conditions and asymmetry in one transaction are transferred to the other transactions with the same person. One of the few who have analyzed the interlinkage of credit and marketing in the Philippines is Floro (1987), focussing on the strategies and motives of trader-lenders and rich farmer lenders. She argues that the interlinkage is meant not only to reduce the risk of defaults by replacing the collateral, but also to control the market channels of food commodities and to make profits at the expense of small farmers. In return for the production credit, a trader makes a claim on the produce, and at a lower price than the prevailing market price. Mark-ups on farm inputs and low prices for farm produce (also labor services are sometimes included), contain hidden forms of interest, as opposed to high nominal interest rates common to other forms of informal moneylending in low-income countries (Floro 1987; Geron 1989). Although these studies on market interlinkage give valuable insights into the lending strategies of traders, they leave many questions unanswered, such as those regarding the influence of the socio-economic context on the interlinkage mechanisms and the long-term and short-term credit relationships, not only between traders and farmers, but also between the various traders in the market chain. In the Philippines these relations are institutionalized in the form of sukis, personalized socio-economic relations through which transactions are interlinked, providing the elements of trust and patronage on which the linkages are based and enforced.","PeriodicalId":115960,"journal":{"name":"Financial Landscapes Reconstructed","volume":"35 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"3","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Financial Landscapes Reconstructed","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.4324/9780429038891-13","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Abstract
Land reforms and the Green Revolution with its capital-intensive agricultural technology have increased the importance of informal lenders in many low-income countries, including traders of food products, input dealers, rich farmer-lenders, rice millers and store owners. As a result, informal financial intermediaries have received growing attention from researchers and policymakers, particularly in the Philippines (Agabin et al. 1989; Lamberte and Lim 1987; TBAC 1989). However, in spite of the growing number of (predominantly economic) studies, evaluations of the role of the new financiers still lack detailed, empirical data on their methods of working, their relationships with borrowers, and the different socio-economic and cultural contexts in which they operate. This chapter wants to contribute to a better understanding of these methods, relationships and contexts. For this purpose, I describe credit relations in the production and marketing of vegetables in the central Philippines, taking into account their diversity and contexts. My analysis provides insights into the interdependency of lenders and borrowers, the interweaving of trade and credit transactions, and the cultural and economic backgrounds of the combined strategy of spreading of risks and profit-seeking. It highlights personalized relations of exchange in vegetable marketing, called suki, and the flexible ways in which vegetable traders make use of these relations. Socio-economic factors, the normative environment, specific features of commodities and power conflicts affect opportunities and constraints in the vegetable market, and consequently, suki as a normative construct of individual traders and farmers, has different meanings. High risks are common to credit extension in the production and marketing of agricultural products in the Philippines. While neither the commercial banks nor the Philippines’ cooperative sector have proved wellequipped for lending to small farmers, the need for production capital has increased considerably due to the introduction of new HYV technology. With the failure of government programs and the withdrawal of landlords from the credit sphere, the informal finance circuit has extended and diversified since the mid 1970s. Traders and processors of farm produce, dealers in farm inputs, and rich farmers, offer production loans, together with a host of local middlemen in the credit chain from village to city and back, replacing patron-client relations with landlords (Sacay et al. 1985; TBAC 1981). Peasant agriculture faces further risks and uncertainty because of climatic factors, seasonality of production, changes in consumer preferences, and dependency in land use relations. Trade in agricultural products is similarly risky, and costs of transportation, storage, processing and information are high. Earlier studies show that informal lenders reduce risks and costs by operating in more than one market through interlinked deals (Floro 1987; Geron 1989). For instance, a person engages in the sale of farm inputs, the milling of rice, the purchase of farm products, the finance of production, all with the same farmer. The literature on India is particularly extensive (Bharadway 1985; Bhaduri 1983; Braverman and Stiglitz 1982). Vertical integration appears as a profit strategy and a way of extracting surplus from poor farmers, since the conditions and asymmetry in one transaction are transferred to the other transactions with the same person. One of the few who have analyzed the interlinkage of credit and marketing in the Philippines is Floro (1987), focussing on the strategies and motives of trader-lenders and rich farmer lenders. She argues that the interlinkage is meant not only to reduce the risk of defaults by replacing the collateral, but also to control the market channels of food commodities and to make profits at the expense of small farmers. In return for the production credit, a trader makes a claim on the produce, and at a lower price than the prevailing market price. Mark-ups on farm inputs and low prices for farm produce (also labor services are sometimes included), contain hidden forms of interest, as opposed to high nominal interest rates common to other forms of informal moneylending in low-income countries (Floro 1987; Geron 1989). Although these studies on market interlinkage give valuable insights into the lending strategies of traders, they leave many questions unanswered, such as those regarding the influence of the socio-economic context on the interlinkage mechanisms and the long-term and short-term credit relationships, not only between traders and farmers, but also between the various traders in the market chain. In the Philippines these relations are institutionalized in the form of sukis, personalized socio-economic relations through which transactions are interlinked, providing the elements of trust and patronage on which the linkages are based and enforced.
土地改革和绿色革命及其资本密集型农业技术增加了许多低收入国家非正规贷款机构的重要性,包括食品贸易商、投入商、富裕农民贷款机构、碾米厂和商店老板。因此,非正式金融中介机构越来越受到研究人员和政策制定者的关注,特别是在菲律宾(Agabin et al. 1989;Lamberte and Lim 1987;1989年纪录)。然而,尽管有越来越多的研究(主要是经济方面的),对新金融家作用的评估仍然缺乏关于他们的工作方法、他们与借款人的关系以及他们所处的不同社会经济和文化背景的详细经验数据。本章希望有助于更好地理解这些方法、关系和上下文。为此,我描述了菲律宾中部蔬菜生产和销售中的信贷关系,考虑到它们的多样性和背景。我的分析提供了对借贷双方相互依赖、贸易和信贷交易交织、以及风险扩散和逐利联合策略的文化和经济背景的见解。它突出了蔬菜营销中的个性化交换关系,称为suki,以及蔬菜贸易商利用这些关系的灵活方式。社会经济因素、规范环境、商品特性和权力冲突影响着蔬菜市场的机会和约束,因此,作为个体交易者和农民的规范性建构,suki具有不同的意义。在菲律宾,农产品生产和销售的信贷扩展普遍存在高风险。虽然商业银行和菲律宾的合作社部门都不具备向小农提供贷款的能力,但由于采用了新的HYV技术,对生产资本的需求大大增加。随着政府项目的失败和房东退出信贷领域,自20世纪70年代中期以来,非正式金融循环得到了扩展和多样化。农产品的贸易商和加工商、农业投入品的经销商和富有的农民提供生产贷款,连同从农村到城市再到城市的信贷链上的大量当地中间商,取代了与地主的主顾关系(Sacay et al. 1985;1981年纪录)。由于气候因素、生产的季节性、消费者偏好的变化以及土地利用关系的依赖性,农民农业面临着进一步的风险和不确定性。农产品贸易同样存在风险,运输、储存、加工和信息的成本很高。早期的研究表明,非正规贷款机构通过相互关联的交易在一个以上的市场上开展业务,从而降低风险和成本(Floro 1987;Geron 1989)。例如,一个人从事农业投入的销售,碾米,购买农产品,生产融资,所有这些都是同一个农民。关于印度的文献尤其广泛(Bharadway 1985;报告1983;布雷弗曼和斯蒂格利茨1982)。垂直整合似乎是一种盈利策略,也是一种从贫困农民那里榨取剩余的方式,因为一笔交易中的条件和不对称被转移到与同一个人进行的其他交易中。Floro(1987)是为数不多的分析菲律宾信贷和营销相互联系的人之一,他关注的是商人贷款人和富裕农民贷款人的策略和动机。她认为,这种相互联系不仅意味着通过替换抵押品来降低违约风险,而且还意味着控制粮食商品的市场渠道,并以牺牲小农的利益为代价获取利润。作为对生产信用的回报,贸易商以低于现行市场价格的价格对产品提出索赔。农业投入的加价和农产品的低价(有时也包括劳务)包含了隐性的利息形式,这与低收入国家其他形式的非正式借贷常见的高名义利率不同(Floro 1987;Geron 1989)。虽然这些关于市场相互联系的研究为交易者的借贷策略提供了有价值的见解,但它们留下了许多未解决的问题,例如社会经济背景对相互联系机制和长期和短期信贷关系的影响,不仅在交易者和农民之间,而且在市场链上的各种交易者之间。在菲律宾,这些关系以sukis的形式制度化,这是一种个性化的社会经济关系,通过这种关系,交易相互联系,提供信任和赞助的要素,这种联系是建立和执行的。