The impact of cost stickiness on income smoothing: evidence from employment protection regulations

IF 2 4区 管理学 Q2 BUSINESS, FINANCE Accounting and Business Research Pub Date : 2023-11-07 DOI:10.1080/00014788.2023.2266803
Andrei Filip, Junqi Liu, Daphne Lui
{"title":"The impact of cost stickiness on income smoothing: evidence from employment protection regulations","authors":"Andrei Filip, Junqi Liu, Daphne Lui","doi":"10.1080/00014788.2023.2266803","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"AbstractPrior literature suggests that cost stickiness increases the ex-ante volatility and reduces the predictability of earnings. We examine whether managers intentionally undo such consequences by dampening earnings volatility. Exploiting the staggered adoption of wrongful discharge laws as an exogenous instrument for cost stickiness, we document that cost stickiness increases managers’ income-smoothing activities. This response is more pronounced in firms whose earnings are more sensitive to labour costs than their industry peers are and in firms with stronger information-provision incentives. Additional analyses indicate that income smoothing improves sticky-cost firms’ earnings informativeness and that the identified impact of cost stickiness is primarily driven by labour costs. Our results suggest that labour regulations can influence managers’ financial reporting incentives via cost behaviour.Keywords: cost stickinessincome smoothingemployment protectionearnings informativeness AcknowledgmentsWe are heavily indebted to the associated editor Stefano Cascino and two anonymous reviewers for their constructive and thoughtful guidance. We thank Beatriz García-Osma, Thomas Jeanjean, Anne Jeny, Sanjay Kallapur, Itay Kama, Reuven Lehavy, Andreea Moraru-Arfire, Naomi Soderstrom, Samuel Tan (discussant), and workshop participants at ESSEC Business School and the EAA Annual Congress 2019 in Paphos for their helpful comments and suggestions. Junqi Liu also gratefully acknowledges the financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC), grant number 72202190, from the Social Science Foundation of Fujian Province, grant number FJ2022C034, from the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities, grant number 20720221042, and from the Association Francophone de Comptabilité (AFC). All remaining errors are our own.Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 Cost stickiness arises primarily from the asymmetry in managers’ real resource commitment. When activity levels increase, managers add resources to meet growing demand; when activity levels fall, they retain some of their underutilized resources, because they perceive the adjustment costs of reducing the resources as higher than the costs of holding them (Anderson et al. Citation2003). In this sense, cost stickiness is distinct from managers’ financial reporting choice.2 In this study, we focus on accrual-based income smoothing, which reflects managerial effort to reduce earnings volatility through accounting methods (in contrast to real activities); see Section 2.2 for more detail. We do not discuss income smoothing through real activities such as discretionary adjustments of R&D or marketing expenditures because such activities are likely detrimental to firm performance in the long run.3 For example, if each employee uses a truck or a software license (i.e. complements to labour), then greater labour cost stickiness will lead to greater stickiness in the associated truck or software costs. Alternatively, if the firm uses temporarily idle employees to perform tasks that are normally outsourced to external contractors (substitutes to in-house labour), then greater labour cost stickiness could lead to lower stickiness for these external costs. To this end, operating costs properly capture these cross-resource effects.4 Recent literature also identifies conditions under which costs exhibit anti-stickiness (e.g. Kama and Weiss Citation2013, Banker et al. Citation2014, Chen et al. Citation2019). We focus our discussion on cost stickiness because this is a significantly more common phenomenon, and our setting of WDL adoptions primarily increases the adjustment costs of labour and therefore lead to stronger operating cost stickiness.5 Untabulated analyses show that cost stickiness is negatively associated with earnings persistence and positively associated with pre-managed earnings volatility and operating cash flow volatility, providing further evidence that cost stickiness likely reduces earnings informativeness and increases ex-ante earnings volatility. Our definition of pre-managed earnings is outlined in Appendix B.6 Theoretically, low cost elasticity (i.e. the symmetric response of costs to activity increases and decreases) may as well lead to high earnings volatility. However, the symmetric pattern of cost changes in response to changes in activity can be anticipated by investors (Banker and Chen Citation2006). Therefore, unlike high cost stickiness, low cost elasticity exhibit no impact on the predictability of earnings (Hutton et al. Citation2012), as it does not hinder investors from correctly evaluating negative shocks.7 When retaining unused resources during a sales decrease, managers sacrifice current earnings but save on expected future adjustment costs, which leads to a future economic benefit. However, unsmoothed reported earnings for the current period do not incorporate such a future benefit. Managers who are privately informed of this benefit could smooth earnings to communicate this information and reflect the “true economic performance” of the firm.8 The legal profession distinguishes three types of WDLs: the good-faith exception, the public-policy exception, and the implied-contract exception. For a detailed discussion of the WDL adoption, see Walsh and Schwarz (Citation1996), Miles (Citation2000), Kugler and Saint-Paul (Citation2004), and Autor et al. (Citation2006).9 Serfling (Citation2016) shows through a survival analysis that the adoption of WDLs is effectively unpredictable.10 WDLs may have real effects on firms, such as increased innovation (Acharya et al. Citation2013) and share repurchases (Dang et al. Citation2021), and decreased profitability (Bird and Knopf Citation2009), financial leverage (Serfling, Citation2016), firm growth (Bai et al. Citation2020), and tax aggressiveness (Fairhurst et al. Citation2020). The latter set of channels are associated with lower, rather than higher, income smoothing (see Carlson and Bathala Citation1997, Mayberry et al. Citation2013). Hence, if the adoption of WDL exceptions affected income smoothing through a real activities channel, our instrumented diff-in-diff results would be more prone to showing a negative, rather than positive, impact of cost stickiness on income smoothing. Despite potential underestimation, we still find a positive impact, which validates the adoption of WDL exceptions as an instrument for cost stickiness.11 We thank an anonymous reviewer for suggesting this method to address the mechanical link between sticky costs and accruals.12 We also used linear and quadratic spline corrections, and the results remain qualitatively similar.13 Weiss (Citation2010) constructs an alternative measure of cost stickiness, which is premised on quarterly data but conceptualized to generate firm-year observations. This measure constructs a standalone variable of cost stickiness at the firm-year level, simplifying the regression analyses. However, this procedure is, by construction, more likely to retain observations with more volatile earnings, leading to a potential selection bias (Banker and Byzalov Citation2014), and the validity of this procedure is also econometrically unwarranted. Hence, we follow the majority of cost-stickiness studies and capture this construct using a cross-sectional regression. Our untabulated results remain qualitatively similar when we apply the Weiss (Citation2010) measure of cost stickiness.14 Industry (or firm) fixed effects are not included in the first-stage regression, because doing so would lead to prohibitively too many coefficients for interaction terms to be estimated and included in the construction of the variable STICKYt. Our results remain qualitatively similar if we do not control for industry (or firm) fixed effects in the second-stage estimation.15 There is a slight discrepancy in the WDL adoption dates in the literature. Utah is not considered as having adopted the good-faith exception in Autor et al. (Citation2006), but other works (e.g. Walsh and Schwarz Citation1996, Serfling Citation2016) code Utah as having adopted the good-faith exception in 1989. Our results are robust to the different versions of coding.16 A firm may operate in multiple states, and its employees are protected by WDLs only if they work in the state in which WDLs are in force. Given that the information about employee location is not available on Compustat, we follow the extant research to capture each firm’s primary location of operations through its headquarters state. Another issue is that the headquarters state recorded on Compustat is the firm’s most recent headquarters location. Nonetheless, if a firm relocated to another state during the sample period, the measurement error will bias against finding our hypothesized results.17 New Hampshire (adopted the good-faith exception in 1974) and Oklahoma (adopted the good-faith exception in 1985) reversed the passage of the good-faith law in 1980 and 1989, respectively. The 11-year window excludes post-reversal observations from the sample.18 We retain all observations within the full 35-year sample period for the control firms. Since control firms do not have an adoption date, we cannot drop observations following the same criteria applied to treated firms. Furthermore, since all control firm observations lie in the 10-year window for at least one treated firm, we cannot drop any control observations due to the lack of a treated counterpart. Even though the number of observations differs significantly between treated and control firms, it should not bias our inference as each treated observation has its (possibly multiple) control counterparts, and each control observation has its treated counterpart.19 In untabulated tests, we remove the 11-year window restriction and keep all observations within the full 35-year sample period for the treated sample, and our inferences remain qualitatively similar.20 The descriptive statistics for the income smoothing measure (SMOOTHt+1) is similar to those reported in other studies such as Hamm et al. (Citation2018) and Tucker and Zarowin (Citation2006).21 We caution that our regression models differ from Heath et al.’s (2022) standard specifications, and the difference might lead to different critical values for a statistic inference purpose.22 We do not control for state fixed effects in columns (1) and (2), as state fixed effects become effectively redundant after controlling for firm fixed effects. Untabulated results show that our results in columns (1) and (2) do not change after adding state fixed effects.23 Relative to the standard error in an estimation without the bootstrapping adjustment (0.035), the standard error for STICKYt more than doubles with the bootstrapping adjustment (0.074).24 Firms could self-select to relocate into/out of a state if they are for/against a forthcoming WDL adoption. To alleviate this concern about firms’ self-selection being associated with the observable variables, we replicate our tests of both stages in an entropy balanced sample in an untabulated test. The qualitatively similar results alleviate the concern that firms’ self-selection of location drives our results.25 We caveat that discretionary revenues consist only part of firms’ discretionary accruals. An income-smoothing measure based on discretionary accruals might omit other accrual components that managers use to smooth earnings, leading to potentially biased findings. As such, we do not use this measure in our main analyses.26 We obtain the same inference by replacing ROAt-1 with CFOt-1, and by excluding ROAt-1, following equation (3) and footnote 17 in Baik et al. (Citation2020).27 The data and methodology for calculating different versions of EPL scores are available on www.oecd.org/employment/protection. We use the first version of EPL scores since it covers the whole sample period. Version 2 has only scores for regular contracts, whereas version 3 starts coverage from 2008, which would significantly reduce our sample size. In untabulated tests, we also use the scores in versions 2 and 3 as alternatives to capture the strictness of EPL, and the results are qualitatively similar.28 Untabulated results show that EPL scores are not associated with other components of operating costs than labour costs (i.e. operating costs minus labour costs), indicating that the results for operating costs primarily reflect the effect for labour costs.Additional informationFundingJunqi Liu gratefully acknowledges the financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC), grant number 72202190, from the Social Science Foundation of Fujian Province, grant number FJ2022C034, from the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities, grant number 20720221042, and from the Association Francophone de Comptabilité (AFC). All remaining errors are our own.","PeriodicalId":7054,"journal":{"name":"Accounting and Business Research","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.0000,"publicationDate":"2023-11-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Accounting and Business Research","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/00014788.2023.2266803","RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"BUSINESS, FINANCE","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

AbstractPrior literature suggests that cost stickiness increases the ex-ante volatility and reduces the predictability of earnings. We examine whether managers intentionally undo such consequences by dampening earnings volatility. Exploiting the staggered adoption of wrongful discharge laws as an exogenous instrument for cost stickiness, we document that cost stickiness increases managers’ income-smoothing activities. This response is more pronounced in firms whose earnings are more sensitive to labour costs than their industry peers are and in firms with stronger information-provision incentives. Additional analyses indicate that income smoothing improves sticky-cost firms’ earnings informativeness and that the identified impact of cost stickiness is primarily driven by labour costs. Our results suggest that labour regulations can influence managers’ financial reporting incentives via cost behaviour.Keywords: cost stickinessincome smoothingemployment protectionearnings informativeness AcknowledgmentsWe are heavily indebted to the associated editor Stefano Cascino and two anonymous reviewers for their constructive and thoughtful guidance. We thank Beatriz García-Osma, Thomas Jeanjean, Anne Jeny, Sanjay Kallapur, Itay Kama, Reuven Lehavy, Andreea Moraru-Arfire, Naomi Soderstrom, Samuel Tan (discussant), and workshop participants at ESSEC Business School and the EAA Annual Congress 2019 in Paphos for their helpful comments and suggestions. Junqi Liu also gratefully acknowledges the financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC), grant number 72202190, from the Social Science Foundation of Fujian Province, grant number FJ2022C034, from the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities, grant number 20720221042, and from the Association Francophone de Comptabilité (AFC). All remaining errors are our own.Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 Cost stickiness arises primarily from the asymmetry in managers’ real resource commitment. When activity levels increase, managers add resources to meet growing demand; when activity levels fall, they retain some of their underutilized resources, because they perceive the adjustment costs of reducing the resources as higher than the costs of holding them (Anderson et al. Citation2003). In this sense, cost stickiness is distinct from managers’ financial reporting choice.2 In this study, we focus on accrual-based income smoothing, which reflects managerial effort to reduce earnings volatility through accounting methods (in contrast to real activities); see Section 2.2 for more detail. We do not discuss income smoothing through real activities such as discretionary adjustments of R&D or marketing expenditures because such activities are likely detrimental to firm performance in the long run.3 For example, if each employee uses a truck or a software license (i.e. complements to labour), then greater labour cost stickiness will lead to greater stickiness in the associated truck or software costs. Alternatively, if the firm uses temporarily idle employees to perform tasks that are normally outsourced to external contractors (substitutes to in-house labour), then greater labour cost stickiness could lead to lower stickiness for these external costs. To this end, operating costs properly capture these cross-resource effects.4 Recent literature also identifies conditions under which costs exhibit anti-stickiness (e.g. Kama and Weiss Citation2013, Banker et al. Citation2014, Chen et al. Citation2019). We focus our discussion on cost stickiness because this is a significantly more common phenomenon, and our setting of WDL adoptions primarily increases the adjustment costs of labour and therefore lead to stronger operating cost stickiness.5 Untabulated analyses show that cost stickiness is negatively associated with earnings persistence and positively associated with pre-managed earnings volatility and operating cash flow volatility, providing further evidence that cost stickiness likely reduces earnings informativeness and increases ex-ante earnings volatility. Our definition of pre-managed earnings is outlined in Appendix B.6 Theoretically, low cost elasticity (i.e. the symmetric response of costs to activity increases and decreases) may as well lead to high earnings volatility. However, the symmetric pattern of cost changes in response to changes in activity can be anticipated by investors (Banker and Chen Citation2006). Therefore, unlike high cost stickiness, low cost elasticity exhibit no impact on the predictability of earnings (Hutton et al. Citation2012), as it does not hinder investors from correctly evaluating negative shocks.7 When retaining unused resources during a sales decrease, managers sacrifice current earnings but save on expected future adjustment costs, which leads to a future economic benefit. However, unsmoothed reported earnings for the current period do not incorporate such a future benefit. Managers who are privately informed of this benefit could smooth earnings to communicate this information and reflect the “true economic performance” of the firm.8 The legal profession distinguishes three types of WDLs: the good-faith exception, the public-policy exception, and the implied-contract exception. For a detailed discussion of the WDL adoption, see Walsh and Schwarz (Citation1996), Miles (Citation2000), Kugler and Saint-Paul (Citation2004), and Autor et al. (Citation2006).9 Serfling (Citation2016) shows through a survival analysis that the adoption of WDLs is effectively unpredictable.10 WDLs may have real effects on firms, such as increased innovation (Acharya et al. Citation2013) and share repurchases (Dang et al. Citation2021), and decreased profitability (Bird and Knopf Citation2009), financial leverage (Serfling, Citation2016), firm growth (Bai et al. Citation2020), and tax aggressiveness (Fairhurst et al. Citation2020). The latter set of channels are associated with lower, rather than higher, income smoothing (see Carlson and Bathala Citation1997, Mayberry et al. Citation2013). Hence, if the adoption of WDL exceptions affected income smoothing through a real activities channel, our instrumented diff-in-diff results would be more prone to showing a negative, rather than positive, impact of cost stickiness on income smoothing. Despite potential underestimation, we still find a positive impact, which validates the adoption of WDL exceptions as an instrument for cost stickiness.11 We thank an anonymous reviewer for suggesting this method to address the mechanical link between sticky costs and accruals.12 We also used linear and quadratic spline corrections, and the results remain qualitatively similar.13 Weiss (Citation2010) constructs an alternative measure of cost stickiness, which is premised on quarterly data but conceptualized to generate firm-year observations. This measure constructs a standalone variable of cost stickiness at the firm-year level, simplifying the regression analyses. However, this procedure is, by construction, more likely to retain observations with more volatile earnings, leading to a potential selection bias (Banker and Byzalov Citation2014), and the validity of this procedure is also econometrically unwarranted. Hence, we follow the majority of cost-stickiness studies and capture this construct using a cross-sectional regression. Our untabulated results remain qualitatively similar when we apply the Weiss (Citation2010) measure of cost stickiness.14 Industry (or firm) fixed effects are not included in the first-stage regression, because doing so would lead to prohibitively too many coefficients for interaction terms to be estimated and included in the construction of the variable STICKYt. Our results remain qualitatively similar if we do not control for industry (or firm) fixed effects in the second-stage estimation.15 There is a slight discrepancy in the WDL adoption dates in the literature. Utah is not considered as having adopted the good-faith exception in Autor et al. (Citation2006), but other works (e.g. Walsh and Schwarz Citation1996, Serfling Citation2016) code Utah as having adopted the good-faith exception in 1989. Our results are robust to the different versions of coding.16 A firm may operate in multiple states, and its employees are protected by WDLs only if they work in the state in which WDLs are in force. Given that the information about employee location is not available on Compustat, we follow the extant research to capture each firm’s primary location of operations through its headquarters state. Another issue is that the headquarters state recorded on Compustat is the firm’s most recent headquarters location. Nonetheless, if a firm relocated to another state during the sample period, the measurement error will bias against finding our hypothesized results.17 New Hampshire (adopted the good-faith exception in 1974) and Oklahoma (adopted the good-faith exception in 1985) reversed the passage of the good-faith law in 1980 and 1989, respectively. The 11-year window excludes post-reversal observations from the sample.18 We retain all observations within the full 35-year sample period for the control firms. Since control firms do not have an adoption date, we cannot drop observations following the same criteria applied to treated firms. Furthermore, since all control firm observations lie in the 10-year window for at least one treated firm, we cannot drop any control observations due to the lack of a treated counterpart. Even though the number of observations differs significantly between treated and control firms, it should not bias our inference as each treated observation has its (possibly multiple) control counterparts, and each control observation has its treated counterpart.19 In untabulated tests, we remove the 11-year window restriction and keep all observations within the full 35-year sample period for the treated sample, and our inferences remain qualitatively similar.20 The descriptive statistics for the income smoothing measure (SMOOTHt+1) is similar to those reported in other studies such as Hamm et al. (Citation2018) and Tucker and Zarowin (Citation2006).21 We caution that our regression models differ from Heath et al.’s (2022) standard specifications, and the difference might lead to different critical values for a statistic inference purpose.22 We do not control for state fixed effects in columns (1) and (2), as state fixed effects become effectively redundant after controlling for firm fixed effects. Untabulated results show that our results in columns (1) and (2) do not change after adding state fixed effects.23 Relative to the standard error in an estimation without the bootstrapping adjustment (0.035), the standard error for STICKYt more than doubles with the bootstrapping adjustment (0.074).24 Firms could self-select to relocate into/out of a state if they are for/against a forthcoming WDL adoption. To alleviate this concern about firms’ self-selection being associated with the observable variables, we replicate our tests of both stages in an entropy balanced sample in an untabulated test. The qualitatively similar results alleviate the concern that firms’ self-selection of location drives our results.25 We caveat that discretionary revenues consist only part of firms’ discretionary accruals. An income-smoothing measure based on discretionary accruals might omit other accrual components that managers use to smooth earnings, leading to potentially biased findings. As such, we do not use this measure in our main analyses.26 We obtain the same inference by replacing ROAt-1 with CFOt-1, and by excluding ROAt-1, following equation (3) and footnote 17 in Baik et al. (Citation2020).27 The data and methodology for calculating different versions of EPL scores are available on www.oecd.org/employment/protection. We use the first version of EPL scores since it covers the whole sample period. Version 2 has only scores for regular contracts, whereas version 3 starts coverage from 2008, which would significantly reduce our sample size. In untabulated tests, we also use the scores in versions 2 and 3 as alternatives to capture the strictness of EPL, and the results are qualitatively similar.28 Untabulated results show that EPL scores are not associated with other components of operating costs than labour costs (i.e. operating costs minus labour costs), indicating that the results for operating costs primarily reflect the effect for labour costs.Additional informationFundingJunqi Liu gratefully acknowledges the financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC), grant number 72202190, from the Social Science Foundation of Fujian Province, grant number FJ2022C034, from the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities, grant number 20720221042, and from the Association Francophone de Comptabilité (AFC). All remaining errors are our own.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
成本粘性对收入平滑的影响:来自就业保护法规的证据
摘要已有文献表明,成本粘性增加了事前波动性,降低了收益的可预测性。我们考察了管理者是否有意通过抑制收益波动来消除这种后果。利用错误解雇法的交错采用作为成本粘性的外生工具,我们证明成本粘性增加了管理者的收入平滑活动。这种反应在收入对劳动力成本比同行更敏感的公司和信息提供激励更强的公司中更为明显。进一步的分析表明,收入平滑提高了粘性成本企业的收益信息,成本粘性的确定影响主要由劳动力成本驱动。我们的研究结果表明,劳动法规可以通过成本行为影响管理人员的财务报告激励。关键字:成本粘性收入平滑就业保护收入信息确认我们非常感谢联合编辑Stefano Cascino和两位匿名审稿人的建设性和周到的指导。我们感谢Beatriz García-Osma、Thomas Jeanjean、Anne Jeny、Sanjay Kallapur、Itay Kama、Reuven Lehavy、Andreea Moraru-Arfire、Naomi Soderstrom、Samuel Tan(讨教嘉宾)以及ESSEC商学院和2019年帕福斯EAA年会上的研讨会参与者提供的宝贵意见和建议。刘俊琪也感谢国家自然科学基金(基金号:72202190)、福建省社会科学基金(基金号:FJ2022C034)、中央高校基本科研业务费(基金号:20720221042)和法语国家计算机协会(AFC)的资助。所有剩下的错误都是我们自己的。披露声明作者未报告潜在的利益冲突。注1成本粘性主要源于管理者实际资源承诺的不对称。当活动水平提高时,管理者会增加资源以满足不断增长的需求;当活动水平下降时,他们会保留一些未充分利用的资源,因为他们认为减少资源的调整成本高于持有资源的成本(Anderson等)。Citation2003)。从这个意义上说,成本粘性不同于管理者的财务报告选择在本研究中,我们关注基于权责发生制的收入平滑,这反映了管理层通过会计方法减少盈余波动的努力(与实际活动相反);参见2.2节了解更多细节。我们不讨论通过实际活动(如研发或营销支出的酌情调整)实现的收入平滑,因为从长远来看,这些活动可能对公司绩效有害例如,如果每个员工都使用卡车或软件许可证(即对劳动力的补充),那么更大的劳动力成本粘性将导致相关卡车或软件成本的更大粘性。或者,如果公司使用暂时闲置的员工来执行通常外包给外部承包商的任务(内部劳动力的替代品),那么更大的劳动力成本粘性可能导致这些外部成本的粘性降低。为此,运营成本适当地反映了这些跨资源效应最近的文献也确定了成本表现出抗粘性的条件(如Kama和Weiss Citation2013, Banker等)。Citation2014, Chen等。Citation2019)。我们将讨论重点放在成本粘性上,因为这是一个明显更为普遍的现象,我们采用WDL的设置主要增加了劳动力的调整成本,因此导致更强的运营成本粘性未列表分析表明,成本粘性与盈余持续性呈负相关,与预管理盈余波动性和经营性现金流波动性呈正相关,进一步证明成本粘性可能会降低盈余信息性,增加事前盈余波动性。我们对预管理盈余的定义见附录B.6。从理论上讲,低成本弹性(即成本对活动增加和减少的对称反应)也可能导致高盈余波动性。然而,投资者可以预测到响应活动变化的成本变化的对称模式(Banker和Chen Citation2006)。因此,与高成本粘性不同,低成本弹性对收益的可预测性没有影响(Hutton等)。引文2012),因为它不会阻碍投资者正确评估负面冲击在销售下降期间保留未使用的资源时,管理者牺牲了当前的收益,但节省了预期的未来调整成本,从而产生了未来的经济效益。 19在未制表的试验中,我们取消了11年的窗口限制,并将处理样本的所有观察结果保持在整个35年的样本周期内,我们的推断在质量上保持相似收入平滑度量(smooth +1)的描述性统计数据与Hamm等人(Citation2018)和Tucker和Zarowin (Citation2006)等其他研究中报告的统计数据相似我们需要提醒的是,我们的回归模型与Heath等人(2022)的标准规范不同,这种差异可能会导致统计推断目的的不同临界值我们不控制列(1)和(2)中的状态固定效应,因为在控制了公司固定效应之后,状态固定效应实际上是多余的。未列示的结果表明(1)和(2)列的结果在加入状态固定效应后没有变化相对于没有自举调整的估计的标准误差(0.035),有自举调整的STICKYt的标准误差(0.074)增加了一倍以上如果公司支持或反对即将采用的WDL,他们可以自行选择迁入或迁出一个州。为了减轻这种对企业自我选择与可观察变量相关的担忧,我们在一个未制表的测试中,在熵平衡样本中重复了这两个阶段的测试。质量相似的结果减轻了企业的自我区位选择驱动我们的结果的担忧我们警告说,可自由支配的收入只包括公司可自由支配的应计利润的一部分。基于可自由支配应计利润的收入平滑度量可能会忽略管理人员用来平滑收益的其他应计利润组成部分,从而导致可能存在偏差的结果。因此,我们在主要分析中不使用这种度量我们通过将ROAt-1替换为cft -1,并根据Baik等人(Citation2020)的公式(3)和脚注17排除ROAt-1,获得了相同的推断计算不同版本EPL分数的数据和方法可在www.oecd.org/employment/protection上获得。我们使用第一个版本的EPL分数,因为它涵盖了整个样本时期。版本2只有常规合同的分数,而版本3从2008年开始覆盖,这将大大减少我们的样本量。在未制表的测试中,我们也使用版本2和3中的分数作为捕获EPL严格性的替代方法,结果在质量上是相似的未列表的结果表明,EPL分数与运营成本的其他组成部分(即运营成本减去劳动力成本)无关,这表明运营成本的结果主要反映了对劳动力成本的影响。刘俊奇感谢中国国家自然科学基金委员会(NSFC)资助,资助号为72202190,福建省社会科学基金资助,资助号为FJ2022C034,中央高校基本科研业务费资助,资助号为20720221042,以及法语国家计算机协会(AFC)的资助。所有剩下的错误都是我们自己的。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
3.40
自引率
11.80%
发文量
38
期刊介绍: Accounting and Business Research publishes papers containing a substantial and original contribution to knowledge. Papers may cover any area of accounting, broadly defined and including corporate governance, auditing and taxation. However the focus must be accounting, rather than (corporate) finance or general management. Authors may take a theoretical or an empirical approach, using either quantitative or qualitative methods. They may aim to contribute to developing and understanding the role of accounting in business. Papers should be rigorous but also written in a way that makes them intelligible to a wide range of academics and, where appropriate, practitioners.
期刊最新文献
Enhancing auditors’ professional skepticism through nudges: an eye-tracking experiment Taming the dragon: stock exchange comment letters and earnings volatility The predictive ability of share-based compensation expense Investor cognitive engagement with earnings information: evidence from pupillary response Using legitimacy strategies to secure organisational survival over time: the case of EFRAG
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1