{"title":"Offer money, they will accept: linkages between authoritarian tendencies and clientelist targeting in Africa","authors":"Nemanja Stankov","doi":"10.1080/13510347.2023.2267453","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"ABSTRACTUnderstanding clientelist practices is one of the core issues to unravel to ensure the proper functioning of electoral institutions. This article focuses on the decision of patrons/brokers on who to target, introducing a new norm into the picture – authoritarianism. Building on the theories of norm-based compliance, I argued that authoritarian individuals should be more frequently targeted, as they should be more likely to comply with brokers demands without external monitoring. I posit that this is true because authoritarian individuals should be more willing to submit to the will and demands of authorities (brokers), and because they are likely to evaluate clientelism as morally acceptable and a legitimate electoral strategy. Furthermore, the rate of authoritarian targeting should be higher in institutional settings that limit the overall reach of clientelism. Utilizing Afrobarometer (2011-2013) data for 34 countries, through multilevel regression modelling I show that authoritarian individuals do have a higher chance of being targeted with the strength of this association increasing as the district magnitude rises. This article opens a new avenue of research that introduces individual level authoritarianism into the literature on clientelist targeting and complements the norm-based compliance approach with a focus on a new and potentially influential norm.KEYWORDS: ClientelismtargetingauthoritarianismAfricadistrict magnitude Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 Kitschelt and Wilkinson, “Citizen-Political linkages.”2 Stokes, “A formal model of machine politics.”3 Stokes et al., Brokers, voters, and clientelism.4 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”5 Carlin and Moseley, “Good democrats, bad targets” and Carlin and Moseley, “When Clientelism Backfires.”6 Robinson and Verdier, “The political economy.”7 Dal Bó, “Bribing voters.”8 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”9 see Van de Walle, “Meet the new boss.”10 Cohrs et al., “Effects of right-wing” and Crowson, “Authoritarianism, perceived threat.”11 Arlin, “Right-wing authoritarianism.”12 Almond and Verba, The Civic Culture in Lawson and Greene, “Making clientelism work.”13 Chang and Golden, “Electoral systems.”14 Pellicer and Wegner, “Electoral rules.”15 see Mares, From open secrets, for XIX century German elections.16 Hicken, “Clientelism”17 Kitschelt and Wilkinson, “Citizen-Political linkages.”18 Yildirim and Kitschelt, “Analytical perspectives” and Berenschot and Aspinall, “How clientelism varies.”19 Stokes et al., Brokers, voters, and clientelism.20 Note that this conceptualization of clientelism implicitly excludes negative clientelist strategies, such as threats, the withdrawal of benefits and ultimately violence. While I recognize that these can also constitute clientelist exchanges, this paper will focus only on those strategies that “promise” some sort of directly transferable benefits for future electoral support.21 Mares and Young, “Buying, expropriating.”22 Stokes, “A formal model of machine politics” and Stokes et al., Brokers, voters, and clientelism.23 see Mares and Young, “Buying, expropriating” for an extensive review.24 Calvo and Murillo, “Who Delivers?”25 Gans-Morse et al., “Varieties of clientelism.”26 Mares and Young, “Buying, expropriating.”27 Stokes, “A formal model of machine politics,” Stokes et al., Brokers, voters, and clientelism, and Calvo and Murillo, “Who Delivers?”28 Calvo and Murillo, “Who Delivers?” Stokes, “A formal model of machine politics” and Stokes et al., Brokers, voters, and clientelism.29 Gonzales-Ocantos et al., “Vote buying.”30 Bratton “Vote buying”31 Kitschelt and Altamirano, “Clientelism in Latin America.”32 Kitschelt and Wilkinson, “Citizen-Political linkages.”33 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”34 Kramon, “Electoral handouts as information.”35 Ibid.36 Vicente and Wantchekon, “Clientelism and vote buying.”37 Kramon, “Electoral handouts as information,” 456.38 Muno, “Conceptualizing and measuring clientelism.”39 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”40 Kitschelt and Wilkinson, “Citizen-Political linkages.”41 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work,” Chang, “A behavioural model,” and Finan and Schechter, “Vote buying and reciprocity.”42 Finan and Schester, “Vote buying and reciprocity.”43 Ibid.44 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”45 Hicken, “Clientelism.”46 Ibid.47 Ravanilla et al., “Brokers, social networks, reciprocity.”48 Finan and Schester, “Vote buying and reciprocity”49 Duarte et al., “Brokering votes with information.”50 Vilchez et al., “A systemic framework.”51 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”52 Fox, “The difficult transition.”53 Carlin and Moseley, “When Clientelism Backfires.”54 Carlin and Moseley, “Good democrats, bad targets.”55 Gonzales-Ocantos et al., “Vote buying.”56 Altemeyer, “The other “authoritarian personality”.”57 Ibid, 52.58 Ibid, 48.59 Finan and Schester, “Vote buying and reciprocity.”60 Ibid.61 Ibid.62 Bratton, “Vote Buying.”63 Taylor, “Ethnic politics and election campaigns.”64 See Koter, “King makers.”65 Ibid.66 Yildirim and Kitschelt, “Analytical perspectives” and Berenschot and Aspinall, “How clientelism varies.”67 Ibid, 192.68 Ibid.69 Ibid.70 Finan and Schester, “Vote buying and reciprocity.”71 Duarte et al., “Brokering votes with information.”72 Ravanilla et al., “Brokers, social networks, reciprocity.”73 Lande, “The Dyadic Basis.”74 Hicken, “Clientelism.”75 Yildirim and Kitchelt, “Analytical perspectives.”76 see Altemeyer, The authoritarian specter.77 see McKee and Feather, “Revenge, retribution.”78 Ibid.79 Schwartz, “Universals in the content”80 For example, Bratton (Citation2008) reported that most of Nigerian voters view vote buying as an infraction against public morality.81 Altemeyer, The authoritarians.82 Altemeyer, “The other “authoritarian personality”,” 48.83 Cohrs et al., “Effects of right-wing”84 see also Crowson, “Authoritarianism, perceived threat.”85 Dunwoody and Plane, “The influence of authoritarianism.”86 Arlin, “Right-wing authoritarianism.”87 Markowski, Creating authoritarian Clientelism, 125.88 see Mares and Young, “Buying, expropriating.”89 Ibid.90 Chang and Golden, “Electoral systems.”91 Pellicer and Wegner, “Electoral rules.”92 Chang and Golden, “Electoral systems.”93 Ibid.94 Mares and Young, “Buying, expropriating.”95 Carey and Shugart, “Incentives to cultivate.”96 Chang and Golden, “Electoral systems”97 Gonzales-Ocantos et al., “Vote buying” and Carlin and Moseley, “Good democrats, bad targets.”98 Country level data for Sierra Leone and Nigeria, that are a part of currently unpublished Afrobarometer Round 8 (2019-2021) was used for additional robustness analysis presented in Appendix.99 Possible validity issues regarding this measurement and the subsequent analysis lies in the fact that it may be that authoritarian individuals are systematically different than the rest of the sample in reporting clientelist targeting. While this may be a valid criticism of the approach taken here, I would argue it does not reduce the validity of the findings. Admitting to being offered voting incentives is not an automatic admittance of accepting the offer, and, in itself, it does not constitute wrongdoing on part of the respondent. If it was an actual measure of the criminal behaviour of the respondents, it would be a much more serious shortcoming.100 Altemeyer, “The other “authoritarian personality”.”101 Item 1 – The established authorities generally turn out to be right about things, while the radicals and protestors are usually just “loud mouths” showing off their ignorance; Item 5 – It is always better to trust the judgment of the proper authorities in government and religion than to listen to the noisy rabblerousers in our society who are trying to create doubt in people”s minds; Item 25 – What our country needs most is discipline, with everyone following our leaders in unity.102 Stokes et al., Brokers, voters, and clientelism.103 See Koter, “King makers.”104 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”105 Mares and Young, “Buying, expropriating.”106 Koter, “King makers.”107 Corstrange, “Clientelism in competitive” and Dawson et al., “Electoral competition, political parties and clientelism.”108 For a review see Hicken, “Clientelism”109 Allen, “Clientelism and the personal.”110 Hicken, “Clientelism.”111 See adapted CVELI index – measure of the association between ethnic identity and vote choice by country in Koter, “King makers,” 189.112 Chang and Golden, “Electoral systems”113 Carlin and Moseley, “When Clientelism Backfires.”114 see Altemeyer, The authoritarians.115 Koter, “King makers.”116 Batty, “Do Ethnic Groups.”Additional informationNotes on contributorsNemanja StankovNemanja Stankov is a teaching associate at the Faculty of Political Science, University of Montenegro. In his work, he focuses on political behavior and patterns of right-wing electoral support, mostly from a political psychology perspective.","PeriodicalId":47953,"journal":{"name":"Democratization","volume":"30 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":3.7000,"publicationDate":"2023-10-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Democratization","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/13510347.2023.2267453","RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"POLITICAL SCIENCE","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Abstract
ABSTRACTUnderstanding clientelist practices is one of the core issues to unravel to ensure the proper functioning of electoral institutions. This article focuses on the decision of patrons/brokers on who to target, introducing a new norm into the picture – authoritarianism. Building on the theories of norm-based compliance, I argued that authoritarian individuals should be more frequently targeted, as they should be more likely to comply with brokers demands without external monitoring. I posit that this is true because authoritarian individuals should be more willing to submit to the will and demands of authorities (brokers), and because they are likely to evaluate clientelism as morally acceptable and a legitimate electoral strategy. Furthermore, the rate of authoritarian targeting should be higher in institutional settings that limit the overall reach of clientelism. Utilizing Afrobarometer (2011-2013) data for 34 countries, through multilevel regression modelling I show that authoritarian individuals do have a higher chance of being targeted with the strength of this association increasing as the district magnitude rises. This article opens a new avenue of research that introduces individual level authoritarianism into the literature on clientelist targeting and complements the norm-based compliance approach with a focus on a new and potentially influential norm.KEYWORDS: ClientelismtargetingauthoritarianismAfricadistrict magnitude Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 Kitschelt and Wilkinson, “Citizen-Political linkages.”2 Stokes, “A formal model of machine politics.”3 Stokes et al., Brokers, voters, and clientelism.4 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”5 Carlin and Moseley, “Good democrats, bad targets” and Carlin and Moseley, “When Clientelism Backfires.”6 Robinson and Verdier, “The political economy.”7 Dal Bó, “Bribing voters.”8 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”9 see Van de Walle, “Meet the new boss.”10 Cohrs et al., “Effects of right-wing” and Crowson, “Authoritarianism, perceived threat.”11 Arlin, “Right-wing authoritarianism.”12 Almond and Verba, The Civic Culture in Lawson and Greene, “Making clientelism work.”13 Chang and Golden, “Electoral systems.”14 Pellicer and Wegner, “Electoral rules.”15 see Mares, From open secrets, for XIX century German elections.16 Hicken, “Clientelism”17 Kitschelt and Wilkinson, “Citizen-Political linkages.”18 Yildirim and Kitschelt, “Analytical perspectives” and Berenschot and Aspinall, “How clientelism varies.”19 Stokes et al., Brokers, voters, and clientelism.20 Note that this conceptualization of clientelism implicitly excludes negative clientelist strategies, such as threats, the withdrawal of benefits and ultimately violence. While I recognize that these can also constitute clientelist exchanges, this paper will focus only on those strategies that “promise” some sort of directly transferable benefits for future electoral support.21 Mares and Young, “Buying, expropriating.”22 Stokes, “A formal model of machine politics” and Stokes et al., Brokers, voters, and clientelism.23 see Mares and Young, “Buying, expropriating” for an extensive review.24 Calvo and Murillo, “Who Delivers?”25 Gans-Morse et al., “Varieties of clientelism.”26 Mares and Young, “Buying, expropriating.”27 Stokes, “A formal model of machine politics,” Stokes et al., Brokers, voters, and clientelism, and Calvo and Murillo, “Who Delivers?”28 Calvo and Murillo, “Who Delivers?” Stokes, “A formal model of machine politics” and Stokes et al., Brokers, voters, and clientelism.29 Gonzales-Ocantos et al., “Vote buying.”30 Bratton “Vote buying”31 Kitschelt and Altamirano, “Clientelism in Latin America.”32 Kitschelt and Wilkinson, “Citizen-Political linkages.”33 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”34 Kramon, “Electoral handouts as information.”35 Ibid.36 Vicente and Wantchekon, “Clientelism and vote buying.”37 Kramon, “Electoral handouts as information,” 456.38 Muno, “Conceptualizing and measuring clientelism.”39 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”40 Kitschelt and Wilkinson, “Citizen-Political linkages.”41 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work,” Chang, “A behavioural model,” and Finan and Schechter, “Vote buying and reciprocity.”42 Finan and Schester, “Vote buying and reciprocity.”43 Ibid.44 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”45 Hicken, “Clientelism.”46 Ibid.47 Ravanilla et al., “Brokers, social networks, reciprocity.”48 Finan and Schester, “Vote buying and reciprocity”49 Duarte et al., “Brokering votes with information.”50 Vilchez et al., “A systemic framework.”51 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”52 Fox, “The difficult transition.”53 Carlin and Moseley, “When Clientelism Backfires.”54 Carlin and Moseley, “Good democrats, bad targets.”55 Gonzales-Ocantos et al., “Vote buying.”56 Altemeyer, “The other “authoritarian personality”.”57 Ibid, 52.58 Ibid, 48.59 Finan and Schester, “Vote buying and reciprocity.”60 Ibid.61 Ibid.62 Bratton, “Vote Buying.”63 Taylor, “Ethnic politics and election campaigns.”64 See Koter, “King makers.”65 Ibid.66 Yildirim and Kitschelt, “Analytical perspectives” and Berenschot and Aspinall, “How clientelism varies.”67 Ibid, 192.68 Ibid.69 Ibid.70 Finan and Schester, “Vote buying and reciprocity.”71 Duarte et al., “Brokering votes with information.”72 Ravanilla et al., “Brokers, social networks, reciprocity.”73 Lande, “The Dyadic Basis.”74 Hicken, “Clientelism.”75 Yildirim and Kitchelt, “Analytical perspectives.”76 see Altemeyer, The authoritarian specter.77 see McKee and Feather, “Revenge, retribution.”78 Ibid.79 Schwartz, “Universals in the content”80 For example, Bratton (Citation2008) reported that most of Nigerian voters view vote buying as an infraction against public morality.81 Altemeyer, The authoritarians.82 Altemeyer, “The other “authoritarian personality”,” 48.83 Cohrs et al., “Effects of right-wing”84 see also Crowson, “Authoritarianism, perceived threat.”85 Dunwoody and Plane, “The influence of authoritarianism.”86 Arlin, “Right-wing authoritarianism.”87 Markowski, Creating authoritarian Clientelism, 125.88 see Mares and Young, “Buying, expropriating.”89 Ibid.90 Chang and Golden, “Electoral systems.”91 Pellicer and Wegner, “Electoral rules.”92 Chang and Golden, “Electoral systems.”93 Ibid.94 Mares and Young, “Buying, expropriating.”95 Carey and Shugart, “Incentives to cultivate.”96 Chang and Golden, “Electoral systems”97 Gonzales-Ocantos et al., “Vote buying” and Carlin and Moseley, “Good democrats, bad targets.”98 Country level data for Sierra Leone and Nigeria, that are a part of currently unpublished Afrobarometer Round 8 (2019-2021) was used for additional robustness analysis presented in Appendix.99 Possible validity issues regarding this measurement and the subsequent analysis lies in the fact that it may be that authoritarian individuals are systematically different than the rest of the sample in reporting clientelist targeting. While this may be a valid criticism of the approach taken here, I would argue it does not reduce the validity of the findings. Admitting to being offered voting incentives is not an automatic admittance of accepting the offer, and, in itself, it does not constitute wrongdoing on part of the respondent. If it was an actual measure of the criminal behaviour of the respondents, it would be a much more serious shortcoming.100 Altemeyer, “The other “authoritarian personality”.”101 Item 1 – The established authorities generally turn out to be right about things, while the radicals and protestors are usually just “loud mouths” showing off their ignorance; Item 5 – It is always better to trust the judgment of the proper authorities in government and religion than to listen to the noisy rabblerousers in our society who are trying to create doubt in people”s minds; Item 25 – What our country needs most is discipline, with everyone following our leaders in unity.102 Stokes et al., Brokers, voters, and clientelism.103 See Koter, “King makers.”104 Lawson and Green, “Making clientelism work.”105 Mares and Young, “Buying, expropriating.”106 Koter, “King makers.”107 Corstrange, “Clientelism in competitive” and Dawson et al., “Electoral competition, political parties and clientelism.”108 For a review see Hicken, “Clientelism”109 Allen, “Clientelism and the personal.”110 Hicken, “Clientelism.”111 See adapted CVELI index – measure of the association between ethnic identity and vote choice by country in Koter, “King makers,” 189.112 Chang and Golden, “Electoral systems”113 Carlin and Moseley, “When Clientelism Backfires.”114 see Altemeyer, The authoritarians.115 Koter, “King makers.”116 Batty, “Do Ethnic Groups.”Additional informationNotes on contributorsNemanja StankovNemanja Stankov is a teaching associate at the Faculty of Political Science, University of Montenegro. In his work, he focuses on political behavior and patterns of right-wing electoral support, mostly from a political psychology perspective.
摘要了解裙带主义行为是保障选举制度正常运行的核心问题之一。本文关注的是赞助人/经纪人对目标对象的决定,并引入了一种新的规范——威权主义。在基于规范的服从理论的基础上,我认为专制个人应该更频繁地成为目标,因为他们应该更有可能在没有外部监控的情况下服从经纪人的要求。我认为这是正确的,因为专制的个人应该更愿意服从当局(经纪人)的意志和要求,因为他们可能会认为庇护主义在道德上是可以接受的,是一种合法的选举策略。此外,在限制庇护主义总体影响范围的制度环境中,针对威权主义的比例应该更高。利用Afrobarometer(2011-2013) 34个国家的数据,通过多层次回归模型,我表明专制个人确实有更高的机会成为目标,随着地区规模的增加,这种关联的强度也在增加。本文开辟了一条新的研究途径,将个人层面的威权主义引入到针对客户的文献中,并通过关注一种新的、具有潜在影响力的规范来补充基于规范的合规方法。关键词:客户主义;针对威权主义;非洲;地区规模披露声明作者未报告潜在的利益冲突。注1 Kitschelt和Wilkinson,“公民-政治联系”。2 Stokes,机器政治的正式模型。3 Stokes et al.,经纪人、选民和客户主义劳森和格林,《让裙带关系发挥作用》。5卡林和莫斯利,“好的民主党人,坏的目标”和卡林和莫斯利,“当庇护主义适得其反。”6罗宾逊和维迪尔,《政治经济学》。“7 Dal Bó”,贿赂选民。劳森和格林,《让裙带关系发挥作用》9 .见Van de Walle,见新老板。10 Cohrs等人,“右翼的影响”和Crowson,“威权主义,感知威胁。”11 Arlin,右翼威权主义。12 Almond and Verba,《Lawson and Greene的公民文化》,《让裙带关系发挥作用》。13 Chang and Golden,《选举制度》14 Pellicer和Wegner,《选举规则》。15见马雷斯,从公开的秘密,为十九世纪的德国选举17 Kitschelt和Wilkinson,《公民与政治的联系》。18 Yildirim and Kitschelt,《分析视角》,Berenschot and Aspinall,《裙带关系如何变化》。[19] Stokes et al.,经纪人、选民和客户主义请注意,这种对庇护主义的概念化隐含地排除了消极的庇护主义策略,如威胁、撤回利益和最终的暴力。虽然我认识到这些也可以构成客户交换,但本文将只关注那些“承诺”为未来的选举支持提供某种直接转让利益的战略马和杨,购买,征用。22 Stokes,《机器政治的正式模型》,Stokes等人,《经纪人、选民和庇护主义》。23见马雷斯和杨,“购买,征用”的广泛评论卡尔沃和穆里略,《谁来交付?》25 gass - morse et al.,《各种各样的clientelism》。《26匹马与幼马》,购买,征用。27 Stokes,《机器政治的正式模型》,Stokes等人著,《经纪人、选民和clientelism》,Calvo和Murillo著,《谁交付?》28卡尔沃和穆里略,《谁来交付?》斯托克斯,《机器政治的正式模型》和斯托克斯等人,《经纪人、选民和clientism》Gonzales-Ocantos等人,"贿选。30布拉顿《贿选》31基切尔特和阿尔塔米拉诺《拉丁美洲的裙带主义》32 Kitschelt and Wilkinson, <公民-政治联系>。33劳森和格林,《让裙带关系发挥作用》。《34克拉蒙》,作为信息的选举讲义。35同上36 Vicente and Wantchekon, "裙带关系和贿选。"37 Kramon,“作为信息的选举讲义”,456.38 Muno,“概念化和衡量庇护主义”。39劳森和格林,《让裙带关系发挥作用》40 Kitschelt和Wilkinson,《公民与政治的联系》。41劳森和格林,“使裙带关系发挥作用”,Chang,“行为模型”,Finan和Schechter,“投票购买和互惠”。费南和谢斯特街42号,贿选和互惠。43,同上,44劳森和格林,《使裙带关系有效》。45 Hicken, Clientelism。拉瓦尼拉等人,“经纪人、社会网络、互惠。”48 Finan和Schester,“投票购买和互惠”。49 Duarte等人,“利用信息中介投票”。50 Vilchez et al.,“一个系统框架。”51劳森和格林,让裙带关系发挥作用。《52狐狸》,艰难的过渡。53卡林和莫斯利,《当庇护主义适得其反》"卡林街和莫斯利街54号,"好的民主党人,坏的目标。55 Gonzales-Ocantos et al.,贿选。“56 Altemeyer”,另一个“专制人格”。" 57同上,52.58同上,48。
期刊介绍:
Democratization aims to promote a better understanding of democratization - defined as the way democratic norms, institutions and practices evolve and are disseminated both within and across national and cultural boundaries. While the focus is on democratization viewed as a process, the journal also builds on the enduring interest in democracy itself and its analysis. The emphasis is contemporary and the approach comparative, with the publication of scholarly contributions about those areas where democratization is currently attracting considerable attention world-wide.