A blueprint for U.S. health insurance policy

IF 2.3 3区 管理学 Q2 ECONOMICS Journal of Policy Analysis and Management Pub Date : 2024-04-30 DOI:10.1002/pam.22602
Liran Einav, Amy Finkelstein
{"title":"A blueprint for U.S. health insurance policy","authors":"Liran Einav,&nbsp;Amy Finkelstein","doi":"10.1002/pam.22602","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>There is no shortage of proposals for U.S. health insurance reform. In our recent book, <i>We've Got You Covered</i>: <i>Rebooting American Health Care</i> (Einav &amp; Finkelstein, <span>2023</span>), we offered one more. It grew out of our internal debates over healthcare reform, between two academic economists who work (often together) on U.S. health policy but have not yet been involved in making that policy.</p><p>We started by trying to define the goal: what is the problem that healthcare policy should address? There are many good reasons for government to be involved, but the reasons are usually assumed rather than articulated when proposing or evaluating a specific policy proposal. That's unfortunate. It's hard to have a constructive debate about solutions unless we've articulated—and hopefully agreed upon—goals.</p><p>We therefore spent a fair amount of time trying to identify the driving impetus behind our history of health policy reforms and attempted reforms. From this, we ended up concluding that our health policy has been motivated by an enduring, if unwritten, social contract: access to essential health care, regardless of resources.</p><p>We expected a fair amount of push back on this definition of the goal of U.S. health policy. After all, we are a society known for advocating independence and liberty, and for lifting oneself up by the bootstraps. We are also, (in)famously, the only high-income country without universal health insurance coverage. We therefore devoted about a third of our book to trying to convince our readers that in fact this social contract exists, and that the myriad problems with the current U.S. health insurance “system” reflect our failure to fulfill our obligations, not their absence.</p><p>Somewhat to our surprise, in the many reactions we've received from readers across the political spectrum, there has been near-universal agreement with our premise: that the U.S. is committed as a society to trying to ensure access to essential medical care for everyone, whether or not they can pay for it. Reactions have instead focused on particular elements of our proposal for how to fulfill this commitment.</p><p>We described what we thought an ideal system would look like, freed from political, but not economic, constraints. It contains two main elements. The first is universal coverage that is automatic, free to the patient, and basic. The second is the option—for those who want and can afford it—to purchase supplemental coverage in a well-functioning marketplace. We argued that we could thus fulfill our social contract without tackling the other multi-trillion-dollar elephant in the room: the problem of high and often inefficient healthcare spending.</p><p>In what follows, we briefly describe how we arrived at these key elements.</p><p>We estimate that about two thirds of Americans—those who are covered by Medicare or by private health insurance through an employer—would want to supplement beyond the basic. There are two key design issues with supplemental coverage: how it is priced, and how to prevent it from eroding the adequacy of the care provided through basic coverage.</p><p>From Nixon to Clinton to Obama, presidents have bundled proposals for universal coverage with proposals to reduce the level of healthcare spending. The instinct is understandable. After all, coverage and costs are arguably the two great problems in the U.S. healthcare system.</p><p>We, however, have deliberately shied away from tackling the problems of healthcare delivery. That's because we can tackle the problem of coverage—and fulfill our social contract—without tackling the problem of healthcare delivery. We do not have to hold our healthcare commitments hostage to improving the efficiency of healthcare delivery.</p><p>Which is a relief, since we don't (yet) have the silver bullet for dramatically lowering healthcare spending while fulfilling the dictate to “do no harm” to the patient. Nor, we hasten to add, does anyone else. Despite what you may have heard on TV. It's indisputable that there is a lot of waste in U.S. health care. But the old adage about advertising is also true: half of spending is wasted, we just don't know which half.</p><p>However, even without “bending the cost curve,” we could provide our proposed universal, free basic coverage that fulfills our social contract without raising taxes. To see this, consider the level of government healthcare spending in other high-income countries whose universal basic coverage with (almost) no consumer payments looks similar to what we propose. The UK is one example. Canada and Germany are others. In 2019, total healthcare spending in these countries was about 8% to 9% of their economy, with most of this spending financed by taxpayers. Guess how much U.S. taxpayers spent in that same year on health care? Also about 9% of the economy (World Health Organization [WHO], <span>2019</span>).</p><p>Of course, total spending on health care in the U.S. as a share of national income is much larger than it is in any other country—17% in the U.S. in 2019—compared to an average of 9% across high-income countries. That higher U.S. spending, however, primarily reflects higher <i>private</i> spending, not higher public spending (WHO, <span>2019</span>). Our taxes are already paying for the cost of universal basic coverage. We're just not getting it.</p><p>Because total healthcare spending need not change under our proposal, the healthcare system and the provision of medical care need not change either. That will be reassuring to those worried about health insurance reform disrupting a sector that amounts to almost one fifth of the economy, but disappointing to those who would like to radically improve the efficiency of U.S. healthcare delivery. Whatever your perspective, these issues are distinct from the reform that is required to fulfil our social contract.</p><p>Likewise, we deliberately left unspecified many of the health policy debates that loom large in the public zeitgeist. Will basic coverage be provided through a single, public payer who directly employs the healthcare providers (as in the UK or the U.S. VA), or through multiple private payers paying private healthcare providers (as in Switzerland or the Netherlands or Medicare coverage for prescription drugs in the U.S.), or through some combination of the two (as in Australia or Medicare coverage for hospital and physician care in the U.S.)? These and many other design questions can involve important trade-offs. But their resolution is not a requirement for fulfilling our social contract. The experience of other countries makes that clear.</p><p>The experience of other countries provides another reassuring observation. We developed our proposal from first principles by focusing on the problem that needs to be solved and what is essential to that solution. But once we did this, we were struck—and humbled—to realize that, at a high level, our proposal contains several key components that every high-income country (and all but a few Canadian provinces) has embraced: guaranteed basic coverage which must be delivered within a fixed budget (two things the U.S. currently doesn't have), and the option for people to purchase upgrades.</p><p>The lack of universal U.S. health insurance may be exceptional. The fix, it turns out, is not.</p>","PeriodicalId":48105,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Policy Analysis and Management","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.3000,"publicationDate":"2024-04-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1002/pam.22602","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Journal of Policy Analysis and Management","FirstCategoryId":"91","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1002/pam.22602","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

There is no shortage of proposals for U.S. health insurance reform. In our recent book, We've Got You Covered: Rebooting American Health Care (Einav & Finkelstein, 2023), we offered one more. It grew out of our internal debates over healthcare reform, between two academic economists who work (often together) on U.S. health policy but have not yet been involved in making that policy.

We started by trying to define the goal: what is the problem that healthcare policy should address? There are many good reasons for government to be involved, but the reasons are usually assumed rather than articulated when proposing or evaluating a specific policy proposal. That's unfortunate. It's hard to have a constructive debate about solutions unless we've articulated—and hopefully agreed upon—goals.

We therefore spent a fair amount of time trying to identify the driving impetus behind our history of health policy reforms and attempted reforms. From this, we ended up concluding that our health policy has been motivated by an enduring, if unwritten, social contract: access to essential health care, regardless of resources.

We expected a fair amount of push back on this definition of the goal of U.S. health policy. After all, we are a society known for advocating independence and liberty, and for lifting oneself up by the bootstraps. We are also, (in)famously, the only high-income country without universal health insurance coverage. We therefore devoted about a third of our book to trying to convince our readers that in fact this social contract exists, and that the myriad problems with the current U.S. health insurance “system” reflect our failure to fulfill our obligations, not their absence.

Somewhat to our surprise, in the many reactions we've received from readers across the political spectrum, there has been near-universal agreement with our premise: that the U.S. is committed as a society to trying to ensure access to essential medical care for everyone, whether or not they can pay for it. Reactions have instead focused on particular elements of our proposal for how to fulfill this commitment.

We described what we thought an ideal system would look like, freed from political, but not economic, constraints. It contains two main elements. The first is universal coverage that is automatic, free to the patient, and basic. The second is the option—for those who want and can afford it—to purchase supplemental coverage in a well-functioning marketplace. We argued that we could thus fulfill our social contract without tackling the other multi-trillion-dollar elephant in the room: the problem of high and often inefficient healthcare spending.

In what follows, we briefly describe how we arrived at these key elements.

We estimate that about two thirds of Americans—those who are covered by Medicare or by private health insurance through an employer—would want to supplement beyond the basic. There are two key design issues with supplemental coverage: how it is priced, and how to prevent it from eroding the adequacy of the care provided through basic coverage.

From Nixon to Clinton to Obama, presidents have bundled proposals for universal coverage with proposals to reduce the level of healthcare spending. The instinct is understandable. After all, coverage and costs are arguably the two great problems in the U.S. healthcare system.

We, however, have deliberately shied away from tackling the problems of healthcare delivery. That's because we can tackle the problem of coverage—and fulfill our social contract—without tackling the problem of healthcare delivery. We do not have to hold our healthcare commitments hostage to improving the efficiency of healthcare delivery.

Which is a relief, since we don't (yet) have the silver bullet for dramatically lowering healthcare spending while fulfilling the dictate to “do no harm” to the patient. Nor, we hasten to add, does anyone else. Despite what you may have heard on TV. It's indisputable that there is a lot of waste in U.S. health care. But the old adage about advertising is also true: half of spending is wasted, we just don't know which half.

However, even without “bending the cost curve,” we could provide our proposed universal, free basic coverage that fulfills our social contract without raising taxes. To see this, consider the level of government healthcare spending in other high-income countries whose universal basic coverage with (almost) no consumer payments looks similar to what we propose. The UK is one example. Canada and Germany are others. In 2019, total healthcare spending in these countries was about 8% to 9% of their economy, with most of this spending financed by taxpayers. Guess how much U.S. taxpayers spent in that same year on health care? Also about 9% of the economy (World Health Organization [WHO], 2019).

Of course, total spending on health care in the U.S. as a share of national income is much larger than it is in any other country—17% in the U.S. in 2019—compared to an average of 9% across high-income countries. That higher U.S. spending, however, primarily reflects higher private spending, not higher public spending (WHO, 2019). Our taxes are already paying for the cost of universal basic coverage. We're just not getting it.

Because total healthcare spending need not change under our proposal, the healthcare system and the provision of medical care need not change either. That will be reassuring to those worried about health insurance reform disrupting a sector that amounts to almost one fifth of the economy, but disappointing to those who would like to radically improve the efficiency of U.S. healthcare delivery. Whatever your perspective, these issues are distinct from the reform that is required to fulfil our social contract.

Likewise, we deliberately left unspecified many of the health policy debates that loom large in the public zeitgeist. Will basic coverage be provided through a single, public payer who directly employs the healthcare providers (as in the UK or the U.S. VA), or through multiple private payers paying private healthcare providers (as in Switzerland or the Netherlands or Medicare coverage for prescription drugs in the U.S.), or through some combination of the two (as in Australia or Medicare coverage for hospital and physician care in the U.S.)? These and many other design questions can involve important trade-offs. But their resolution is not a requirement for fulfilling our social contract. The experience of other countries makes that clear.

The experience of other countries provides another reassuring observation. We developed our proposal from first principles by focusing on the problem that needs to be solved and what is essential to that solution. But once we did this, we were struck—and humbled—to realize that, at a high level, our proposal contains several key components that every high-income country (and all but a few Canadian provinces) has embraced: guaranteed basic coverage which must be delivered within a fixed budget (two things the U.S. currently doesn't have), and the option for people to purchase upgrades.

The lack of universal U.S. health insurance may be exceptional. The fix, it turns out, is not.

查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
美国医疗保险政策蓝图
美国医疗保险改革不乏各种建议。在我们最近出版的新书《我们为您提供保障》(We've Got You Covered:重启美国医疗保健》(Einav & Finkelstein, 2023 年)一书中,我们又提出了一项建议。这本书源于我们内部关于医疗改革的争论,这两位学术经济学家(经常一起)研究美国医疗政策,但尚未参与政策的制定。政府参与其中有很多很好的理由,但在提出或评估一项具体的政策建议时,这些理由通常是假定的,而不是阐明的。这是令人遗憾的。因此,我们花了相当多的时间,试图找出我们医疗政策改革和尝试改革的历史背后的推动力。由此,我们最终得出结论,我们的医疗政策是由一个持久的、虽然不成文的社会契约所驱动的:无论资源如何,都能获得基本的医疗保健。毕竟,我们是一个以倡导独立、自由和自力更生而著称的社会。我们也是(著名的)唯一一个没有全民医疗保险的高收入国家。因此,我们在书中用了大约三分之一的篇幅来试图说服读者,事实上这种社会契约是存在的,而美国现行医疗保险 "体系 "中存在的无数问题反映出我们没有履行义务,而不是没有义务。让我们感到有些意外的是,在我们从不同政治派别的读者那里收到的许多反应中,他们几乎普遍同意我们的前提:美国作为一个社会,致力于努力确保每个人都能获得基本的医疗服务,无论他们是否有能力支付。我们描述了我们心目中摆脱了政治(而非经济)限制的理想体系。它包含两个主要因素。第一个要素是自动、免费和基本的全民医保。其次是那些有意愿且有能力的人可以选择在运作良好的市场上购买补充保险。我们认为,这样我们就可以履行我们的社会契约,而无需解决房间里另一个价值数万亿美元的大象:高昂且往往效率低下的医疗支出问题。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
5.80
自引率
2.60%
发文量
82
期刊介绍: This journal encompasses issues and practices in policy analysis and public management. Listed among the contributors are economists, public managers, and operations researchers. Featured regularly are book reviews and a department devoted to discussing ideas and issues of importance to practitioners, researchers, and academics.
期刊最新文献
Unearthing the impact of earthquakes: A review of economic and social consequences Can destigmatizing mental health increase willingness to seek help? Experimental evidence from Nepal Issue Information Contents Introduction to the Research Articles
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1