{"title":"Meeting environmental objectives through energy sector reforms in Asia and the Pacific","authors":"Thilak Mallawaarachchi, Rabindra Nepal, H. Ross","doi":"10.1080/14486563.2021.1989009","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Economic development in the pursuit of better living standards for all requires a reliable supply of energy. Energy supplies enable growth in consumption and economic well-being both in powering basic household needs and the broader processes of production and distribution. Energy, being an essential factor input in economic production, implies that the expansion of energy sources and services have catapulted economic development by facilitating industrialisation and modernisation (Stern and Kander 2012). Therefore, access to affordable and clean energy is recognised globally as one of the distinct sustainable development goals within the framework of the United Nations. Notably, public policy focus and development planning efforts have shifted toward facilitating access, reliability, and utilisation of energy, for both households and industry. This path followed the first and second laws of thermodynamics (energy conservation and entropy), which implies that energy exists in various forms and engineering manipulations can yield productivity gains. The global emphasis towards clean and affordable energy is urgent as a climate change mitigation and adaptation response. As economies grew, and living standards improved, the world began to realise the growing impacts of associated environmental costs of fossil energy use. Although economists attributed those costs to the lack of a socially cost reflective pricing (i.e. non-pricing of the externality costs though accumulated carbon emissions) economic growth fuelled through under-priced fossil fuels always won the political debate. As this journal remarked in an editorial a decade ago, pricing attempts were incorrectly labelled as taxing, and the social purpose of driving change through appropriate price incentives was overlooked (Ross and Carter 2012). Global warming is now a reality, and the COVID-19 pandemic has made the situation overwhelming. In the growing Asia, the emergency response consumes the meagre resources that were previously directed to poverty reduction efforts, making the contest a double hurdle. The question is whether governments and communities could work together to learn from the past reform experience and reshape policy agendas toward greater coordination. How can the development community help, and would it be feasible to find solutions that work in meeting both the environmental objectives and arresting poverty as a social reality? These questions require a revisit against the backdrop that many Asian economies since the early 1990s have initiated energy sector reforms. Microeconomic and industrial organisation theories provided the economic rationale for undertaking energy sector reforms with the key objective of maximising economic welfare (Joskow 1998). The first fundamental theorem of welfare economics holds that all competitive outcomes are Pareto efficient. Therefore, promoting competition in the generation and retail segments of the energy supply industry (ESI) was one of the core objectives of reforms. Likewise, the monopoly segments of the ESI such as transmission and distribution networks are economically regulated based on incentive regulation in line with the theory of the second best since some distortions (or deadweight loss) arising from monopoly network characteristics cannot be eliminated. Therefore, these market-based reforms were primarily focussed on introducing competition,","PeriodicalId":46081,"journal":{"name":"Australasian Journal of Environmental Management","volume":"28 1","pages":"305 - 313"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1000,"publicationDate":"2021-10-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"1","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Australasian Journal of Environmental Management","FirstCategoryId":"90","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/14486563.2021.1989009","RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q4","JCRName":"ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Abstract
Economic development in the pursuit of better living standards for all requires a reliable supply of energy. Energy supplies enable growth in consumption and economic well-being both in powering basic household needs and the broader processes of production and distribution. Energy, being an essential factor input in economic production, implies that the expansion of energy sources and services have catapulted economic development by facilitating industrialisation and modernisation (Stern and Kander 2012). Therefore, access to affordable and clean energy is recognised globally as one of the distinct sustainable development goals within the framework of the United Nations. Notably, public policy focus and development planning efforts have shifted toward facilitating access, reliability, and utilisation of energy, for both households and industry. This path followed the first and second laws of thermodynamics (energy conservation and entropy), which implies that energy exists in various forms and engineering manipulations can yield productivity gains. The global emphasis towards clean and affordable energy is urgent as a climate change mitigation and adaptation response. As economies grew, and living standards improved, the world began to realise the growing impacts of associated environmental costs of fossil energy use. Although economists attributed those costs to the lack of a socially cost reflective pricing (i.e. non-pricing of the externality costs though accumulated carbon emissions) economic growth fuelled through under-priced fossil fuels always won the political debate. As this journal remarked in an editorial a decade ago, pricing attempts were incorrectly labelled as taxing, and the social purpose of driving change through appropriate price incentives was overlooked (Ross and Carter 2012). Global warming is now a reality, and the COVID-19 pandemic has made the situation overwhelming. In the growing Asia, the emergency response consumes the meagre resources that were previously directed to poverty reduction efforts, making the contest a double hurdle. The question is whether governments and communities could work together to learn from the past reform experience and reshape policy agendas toward greater coordination. How can the development community help, and would it be feasible to find solutions that work in meeting both the environmental objectives and arresting poverty as a social reality? These questions require a revisit against the backdrop that many Asian economies since the early 1990s have initiated energy sector reforms. Microeconomic and industrial organisation theories provided the economic rationale for undertaking energy sector reforms with the key objective of maximising economic welfare (Joskow 1998). The first fundamental theorem of welfare economics holds that all competitive outcomes are Pareto efficient. Therefore, promoting competition in the generation and retail segments of the energy supply industry (ESI) was one of the core objectives of reforms. Likewise, the monopoly segments of the ESI such as transmission and distribution networks are economically regulated based on incentive regulation in line with the theory of the second best since some distortions (or deadweight loss) arising from monopoly network characteristics cannot be eliminated. Therefore, these market-based reforms were primarily focussed on introducing competition,
为提高所有人的生活水平而进行的经济发展需要可靠的能源供应。能源供应在满足基本家庭需求和更广泛的生产和分配过程方面,能够促进消费和经济福祉的增长。能源作为经济生产的重要要素,意味着能源和服务的扩张通过促进工业化和现代化而推动了经济发展(Stern and Kander 2012)。因此,获得负担得起的清洁能源是全球公认的联合国框架内独特的可持续发展目标之一。值得注意的是,公共政策重点和发展规划工作已转向促进家庭和工业的能源获取、可靠性和利用。这条道路遵循热力学第一和第二定律(能量守恒和熵),这意味着能量以各种形式存在,工程操作可以产生生产力增益。作为减缓和适应气候变化的对策,全球迫切需要重视清洁和负担得起的能源。随着经济的增长和生活水平的提高,世界开始意识到化石能源使用带来的相关环境成本的影响越来越大。尽管经济学家将这些成本归因于缺乏社会成本反射定价(即通过累积的碳排放对外部性成本进行非定价),但通过价格过低的化石燃料推动的经济增长总是赢得政治辩论。正如本刊在10年前的一篇社论中所说,定价尝试被错误地贴上了征税的标签,而通过适当的价格激励推动变革的社会目的被忽视了(Ross and Carter 2012)。全球变暖已成为现实,新冠肺炎疫情更是雪上加霜。在不断发展的亚洲,应急反应消耗了原本用于减贫工作的微薄资源,使竞争成为双重障碍。问题是政府和社区能否共同努力,从过去的改革经验中吸取教训,重塑政策议程,以加强协调。发展界如何提供帮助?找到既能实现环境目标又能作为社会现实消除贫困的解决办法是否可行?这些问题需要在许多亚洲经济体自上世纪90年代初以来启动能源部门改革的背景下重新审视。微观经济和产业组织理论为以经济福利最大化为主要目标的能源部门改革提供了经济依据(Joskow 1998)。福利经济学的第一个基本定理认为,所有竞争结果都是帕累托效率。因此,促进能源供应行业(ESI)的发电和零售部门的竞争是改革的核心目标之一。同样,由于垄断网络特征引起的一些扭曲(或无谓损失)无法消除,因此ESI的垄断部分(如输电和配电网络)基于符合次优理论的激励监管进行经济监管。因此,这些以市场为基础的改革主要集中在引入竞争,