A New Era of Machinery: Will the Accumulation of Capital Grow and Labor Intensity Decrease?

IF 0.3 Q4 SOCIAL ISSUES Social Evolution & History Pub Date : 2019-03-01 DOI:10.30884/SEH/2019.01.04
A. Akaev, Artícles, A. Rudskoi, A. Sarygulov, V. Sokolov
{"title":"A New Era of Machinery: Will the Accumulation of Capital Grow and Labor Intensity Decrease?","authors":"A. Akaev, Artícles, A. Rudskoi, A. Sarygulov, V. Sokolov","doi":"10.30884/SEH/2019.01.04","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"In order to forecast the macroevolution of the contemporary developed societies it appears essential to take into account the dynamics of a number of economic and technological indicators. In the present paper we undertake such an attempt. Almost ten years after the start of the last economic crisis, the world economy is looking for the most effective plans for recovery. Such recovery is often associated with the fourth industrial revolution, in which the technological factor becomes a key driver of development. However, like any technological breakthrough, it will bring not only ‘roses of prosperity’ but ‘prickly thorns’ of disappointment as well. The key challenges will be the provision of a new quality of economic growth and addressing the associated employment problem. In this paper, we attempt to show the trends in the ratio between capital and output, as well as the possible effects on employment in the industrialized countries and China until 2050. We used a modified production function with labor-saving technological progress. It is shown that by 2050 the capital-output ratio will not undergo significant changes, and in case of a rejection of institutional reforms and legislative diversification of new types of labor activity in different segments of the economy, there may be a decrease in the number of employed by an average of 20 per cent. Social Evolution & History / March 2019 68 INTRODUCTION In order to forecast the macroevolution of the contemporary developed societies it appears essential to take into account the dynamics of a number of economic and technological indicators. Such an attempt is undertaken in the present paper. Despite the considerable efforts made by financial regulators to overcome the consequences of the 2008–2009 crisis, the economies of industrially developed countries show sluggish growth. In the case of the US economy, this was described as ‘secular stagnation’ (Summers 2014). Researchers who analyzed more than ten years of stagnation in the Japanese economy cited low efficiency of capital use as a reason (Ando, Christeris, and Miyagawa 2003; Hayashi 2006). The same process was named ‘Stagnation Traps’ (Benigno and Fornaro 2015), when under conditions of pessimistic expectations, the gap between large volumes of production and low growth rates can coexist. In their joint study, the Japanese and Korean economists consider the extremely low rate of capital expenditures for development as the reason for the stagnation of the Japanese economy. Thus, there is a clear trend that has been defined in economic policy to overcome stagnation: stimulation of aggregate demand, a policy of maintaining a low interest rate, new investments in the economy and a number of other regulatory measures. At the same time, another way has been outlined to solve the problem of economic stagnation: the search for new technological solutions that could qualitatively change the entire economic landscape and give a new impetus to development. Recommendations for the development strategy of Industry 4.0 for German manufacturers (Kagermann, Wahlster and Helbig 2013), and two American concepts: Industrial Internet (Evans and Annunziata 2012) and Internet of Things (Swan 2012) should be noted here. The famous work on artificial intelligence, published in 2003 (Russel and Norvig 2003) laid the foundation for the industrial development of systems with artificial intelligence. At the World Economic Forum in 2016, K. Schwab initiated a broad discussion on the Fourth Industrial Revolution (Schwab 2016). Hence, one can easily notice an obvious accumulation of the necessary ‘critical mass’ of new knowledge and technologies that, like an explosion, can create new conditions for development, and this new ‘critical mass of knowledge and technologies’ can be defined as a new machine era. Obviously, its development will require significant amounts of capital and expenditure on maintaining human resources. The subject of our further consideration will be two questions: what kind of capital / output ratio will take place and what is likely to happen in the employment Akaev et al. / A New Era of Machinery 69 market when new intelligent machine systems, global computer networks and markets create conditions for both free job search and for partial replacement of human knowledge with intelligent machines? SOME INITIAL ASSUMPTIONS Nicholas Kaldor (1961) has formulated five empirical regul arities, known as ‘stylized facts’, which are valid in the long term, when the consequences of various economic and financial shocks and crises are smoothed out. Some of these laws have remained valid so far and there is reason to believe that they will continue to act in the twentyfirst century, at least in the first half. For our study, the following three empirical laws of Kaldor (Kaldor 1961) are of interest: 1. The ratio of physical capital to output is almost constant. 2. The shares of labor and physical capital in the national income growth are almost constant. 3. According to the Kondratiev cycles theory at the downward stage of the 6 Large cycle (2018–2050) the effect of capital saturation should come and one must actually assume that the accumulation of capital will take place not through an exponential function, but through a logistic one. The first of these regularities can be formalized as follows: Y = κ · K, κ = const, (1) where κ is the coefficient of capital return. We proceed from the premise that Equation (1) can be observed in the first half of the twentyfirst century. This directly follows from the results obtained by Thomas Piketty and set forth in his work ‘Capital in the twenty-first Century’ (Piketty 2014). Indeed, T. Piketty demonstrated that in the developed countries (USA, Great Britain, Germany, France, etc.) the ratio between capital (K) and output (Y) in the twentieth century, returned to values close to those observed at the end of the nineteenth century (Piketty 2014: 124, 125, 150, 159). Between the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, this ratio, representing the capital intensity Y K   1   , in the leading European states was quite stable and amounted 7   in France and the UK, and 5 . 6   in Germany (Piketty 2015: 135, 153). In the US, this ratio reached quasi-stability at the beginning of the twentieth century at the level of 5 . 4   , and then, starting from the mid-twentieth century, stabilized at the level of 4   (Piketty 2014). As we can see, the changes in capital intensity in the United States were of a very limited scale in contrast with Western Europe, i.e. Kaldor's respective pattern for the United States also worked in the twenSocial Evolution & History / March 2019 70 tieth century. Piketty explains the return of capital intensity in the twenty-first century to a high level close to the indices observed in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries by the transition to a regime of slow economic growth (Piketty 2014: 171). In this regard, Piketty predicts that in global terms the capital intensity (β), which has already approached the 5 mark and reached the 1910 level, will later be around 6 in the middle of the twenty-first century and will reach 7 by the end of the twenty-first century. In our opinion, a significant increase in capital will actually take place, but the ratio (β) will remain practically unchanged, which we will show further on the basis of model calculations. As for the second of the above-mentioned Kaldor regularities, presumably, it will no longer be observed in the twenty-first century, as the share of capital in GDP growth will steadily increase which does not contradict the results that Piketty obtained.","PeriodicalId":42677,"journal":{"name":"Social Evolution & History","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.3000,"publicationDate":"2019-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"5","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Social Evolution & History","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.30884/SEH/2019.01.04","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q4","JCRName":"SOCIAL ISSUES","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5

Abstract

In order to forecast the macroevolution of the contemporary developed societies it appears essential to take into account the dynamics of a number of economic and technological indicators. In the present paper we undertake such an attempt. Almost ten years after the start of the last economic crisis, the world economy is looking for the most effective plans for recovery. Such recovery is often associated with the fourth industrial revolution, in which the technological factor becomes a key driver of development. However, like any technological breakthrough, it will bring not only ‘roses of prosperity’ but ‘prickly thorns’ of disappointment as well. The key challenges will be the provision of a new quality of economic growth and addressing the associated employment problem. In this paper, we attempt to show the trends in the ratio between capital and output, as well as the possible effects on employment in the industrialized countries and China until 2050. We used a modified production function with labor-saving technological progress. It is shown that by 2050 the capital-output ratio will not undergo significant changes, and in case of a rejection of institutional reforms and legislative diversification of new types of labor activity in different segments of the economy, there may be a decrease in the number of employed by an average of 20 per cent. Social Evolution & History / March 2019 68 INTRODUCTION In order to forecast the macroevolution of the contemporary developed societies it appears essential to take into account the dynamics of a number of economic and technological indicators. Such an attempt is undertaken in the present paper. Despite the considerable efforts made by financial regulators to overcome the consequences of the 2008–2009 crisis, the economies of industrially developed countries show sluggish growth. In the case of the US economy, this was described as ‘secular stagnation’ (Summers 2014). Researchers who analyzed more than ten years of stagnation in the Japanese economy cited low efficiency of capital use as a reason (Ando, Christeris, and Miyagawa 2003; Hayashi 2006). The same process was named ‘Stagnation Traps’ (Benigno and Fornaro 2015), when under conditions of pessimistic expectations, the gap between large volumes of production and low growth rates can coexist. In their joint study, the Japanese and Korean economists consider the extremely low rate of capital expenditures for development as the reason for the stagnation of the Japanese economy. Thus, there is a clear trend that has been defined in economic policy to overcome stagnation: stimulation of aggregate demand, a policy of maintaining a low interest rate, new investments in the economy and a number of other regulatory measures. At the same time, another way has been outlined to solve the problem of economic stagnation: the search for new technological solutions that could qualitatively change the entire economic landscape and give a new impetus to development. Recommendations for the development strategy of Industry 4.0 for German manufacturers (Kagermann, Wahlster and Helbig 2013), and two American concepts: Industrial Internet (Evans and Annunziata 2012) and Internet of Things (Swan 2012) should be noted here. The famous work on artificial intelligence, published in 2003 (Russel and Norvig 2003) laid the foundation for the industrial development of systems with artificial intelligence. At the World Economic Forum in 2016, K. Schwab initiated a broad discussion on the Fourth Industrial Revolution (Schwab 2016). Hence, one can easily notice an obvious accumulation of the necessary ‘critical mass’ of new knowledge and technologies that, like an explosion, can create new conditions for development, and this new ‘critical mass of knowledge and technologies’ can be defined as a new machine era. Obviously, its development will require significant amounts of capital and expenditure on maintaining human resources. The subject of our further consideration will be two questions: what kind of capital / output ratio will take place and what is likely to happen in the employment Akaev et al. / A New Era of Machinery 69 market when new intelligent machine systems, global computer networks and markets create conditions for both free job search and for partial replacement of human knowledge with intelligent machines? SOME INITIAL ASSUMPTIONS Nicholas Kaldor (1961) has formulated five empirical regul arities, known as ‘stylized facts’, which are valid in the long term, when the consequences of various economic and financial shocks and crises are smoothed out. Some of these laws have remained valid so far and there is reason to believe that they will continue to act in the twentyfirst century, at least in the first half. For our study, the following three empirical laws of Kaldor (Kaldor 1961) are of interest: 1. The ratio of physical capital to output is almost constant. 2. The shares of labor and physical capital in the national income growth are almost constant. 3. According to the Kondratiev cycles theory at the downward stage of the 6 Large cycle (2018–2050) the effect of capital saturation should come and one must actually assume that the accumulation of capital will take place not through an exponential function, but through a logistic one. The first of these regularities can be formalized as follows: Y = κ · K, κ = const, (1) where κ is the coefficient of capital return. We proceed from the premise that Equation (1) can be observed in the first half of the twentyfirst century. This directly follows from the results obtained by Thomas Piketty and set forth in his work ‘Capital in the twenty-first Century’ (Piketty 2014). Indeed, T. Piketty demonstrated that in the developed countries (USA, Great Britain, Germany, France, etc.) the ratio between capital (K) and output (Y) in the twentieth century, returned to values close to those observed at the end of the nineteenth century (Piketty 2014: 124, 125, 150, 159). Between the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, this ratio, representing the capital intensity Y K   1   , in the leading European states was quite stable and amounted 7   in France and the UK, and 5 . 6   in Germany (Piketty 2015: 135, 153). In the US, this ratio reached quasi-stability at the beginning of the twentieth century at the level of 5 . 4   , and then, starting from the mid-twentieth century, stabilized at the level of 4   (Piketty 2014). As we can see, the changes in capital intensity in the United States were of a very limited scale in contrast with Western Europe, i.e. Kaldor's respective pattern for the United States also worked in the twenSocial Evolution & History / March 2019 70 tieth century. Piketty explains the return of capital intensity in the twenty-first century to a high level close to the indices observed in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries by the transition to a regime of slow economic growth (Piketty 2014: 171). In this regard, Piketty predicts that in global terms the capital intensity (β), which has already approached the 5 mark and reached the 1910 level, will later be around 6 in the middle of the twenty-first century and will reach 7 by the end of the twenty-first century. In our opinion, a significant increase in capital will actually take place, but the ratio (β) will remain practically unchanged, which we will show further on the basis of model calculations. As for the second of the above-mentioned Kaldor regularities, presumably, it will no longer be observed in the twenty-first century, as the share of capital in GDP growth will steadily increase which does not contradict the results that Piketty obtained.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
机器的新时代:资本积累会增长而劳动强度会下降吗?
为了预测当代发达社会的宏观演变,似乎必须考虑到一些经济和技术指标的动态。在本文件中,我们进行了这样的尝试。上一次经济危机爆发近十年后,世界经济正在寻找最有效的复苏计划。这种复苏往往与第四次工业革命有关,在这场革命中,技术因素成为发展的关键驱动力。然而,就像任何技术突破一样,它不仅会带来“繁荣的玫瑰”,还会带来失望的“荆棘”。关键挑战将是提供新质量的经济增长和解决相关的就业问题。在本文中,我们试图展示2050年前工业化国家和中国资本与产出之比的趋势,以及对就业的可能影响。我们使用了一个经过修改的生产函数,节省了人力。研究表明,到2050年,资本产出率将不会发生重大变化,如果不同经济部门拒绝体制改革和新型劳动力活动的立法多样化,就业人数可能会平均减少20%。社会进化与历史/2019年3月68引言为了预测当代发达社会的宏观进化,似乎必须考虑一些经济和技术指标的动态。本文件进行了这样的尝试。尽管金融监管机构为克服2008-2009年危机的后果做出了巨大努力,但工业发达国家的经济增长缓慢。就美国经济而言,这被描述为“长期停滞”(Summers 2014)。研究人员分析了日本经济十多年的停滞,认为资本使用效率低是一个原因(Ando、Christeris和Miyagawa,2003年;Hayashi,2006年)。同样的过程被命名为“停滞陷阱”(Benigno和Fornaro,2015年),在悲观预期的条件下,大量生产和低增长率之间的差距可以共存。在他们的联合研究中,日本和韩国经济学家认为,用于发展的资本支出率极低是日本经济停滞的原因。因此,在克服停滞的经济政策中有一个明确的趋势:刺激总需求、维持低利率的政策、对经济的新投资以及一些其他监管措施。与此同时,还提出了解决经济停滞问题的另一种方法:寻找新的技术解决方案,从质量上改变整个经济格局,为发展提供新的动力。德国制造商的工业4.0发展战略建议(Kagermann,Wahlster和Helbig,2013),以及两个美国概念:工业互联网(Evans和Annunziata,2012)和物联网(Swan,2012),应在此处注明。2003年发表的关于人工智能的著名著作(Russel和Norvig,2003年)为人工智能系统的工业发展奠定了基础。在2016年的世界经济论坛上,K.Schwab发起了一场关于第四次工业革命的广泛讨论(Schwab 2016)。因此,人们可以很容易地注意到,新知识和技术的必要“临界量”的明显积累,就像爆炸一样,可以为发展创造新的条件,而这种新的“临界量知识和技术”可以被定义为一个新的机器时代。显然,它的发展将需要大量的资本和支出来维持人力资源。我们进一步考虑的主题将是两个问题:什么样的资本/产出比将发生,以及在就业中可能会发生什么。Akaev等人/机械69市场的新时代,当新的智能机器系统,全球计算机网络和市场为免费求职和用智能机器部分取代人类知识创造了条件?一些初步假设Nicholas Kaldor(1961)制定了五个经验规则,称为“程式化事实”,这些规则在各种经济和金融冲击和危机的后果消除后长期有效。到目前为止,其中一些法律仍然有效,有理由相信它们将在21世纪继续生效,至少在上半叶是这样。在我们的研究中,卡尔多(Kaldor 1961)的以下三个经验定律值得关注:1。实物资本与产出的比率几乎是恒定的。2.
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
0.80
自引率
33.30%
发文量
8
期刊最新文献
Dois Tempos, Periférica Agenda Breve debate historiográfico sobre a evolução da filosofia da história: uma revisão de literatura Reforma agrária do Brasil e Peru da década de 60, sobre a ótica comparativa dos regimes militares The Rohingyas of Rakhine State: Social Evolution and History in the Light of Ethnic Nationalism Egypt: From Upper Egyptian Rural Petty Polities to Unitary State
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1