Index Funds and Securities Fraud Litigation

R. Booth
{"title":"Index Funds and Securities Fraud Litigation","authors":"R. Booth","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1996587","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Most legal scholars agree that securities fraud class actions do little to compensate investors. Most investors are well diversified and thus are just as likely to sell an overpriced stock as to buy one. Moreover, since the defendant company ultimately pays in a successful class action, holders effectively pay buyers. Although this circularity is widely recognized, few have noted that because of the anticipated payout, the prospect of a class action causes stock price to decline by more than it otherwise would, thus generating additional (feedback) loss for both buyers and holders. In this article, I describe a method by which one can measure the net effect of class actions on fund investors who are both buyers and holders of a fraud-affected stock. Since an index fund almost always holds more shares than it buys during the fraud period, an index fund almost always loses more than it gains. Thus, class actions systematically penalize rational index fund investors for the benefit of irrational undiversified stock-picking investors. Accordingly, index funds should oppose class actions as contrary to the best interest of investors. To be sure, one possible problem is that in the absence of the deterrent effect of class actions, there might be more securities fraud. The answer is that whenever there is a meritorious class claim, the corporation itself will also have a claim – against the individual wrongdoers – for any increase in cost of capital resulting from reputational harm and any direct expenses relating to enforcement proceedings. In a class action, these elements of loss are imbedded in the price decrease that occurs when the fraud is discovered. But these losses are in fact suffered by the corporation and should be the subject of a derivative action for the benefit of the corporation – and thus all of the stockholders – not a class action for the benefit only of those who bought during the fraud period. Although the corporation claim may be smaller than the class claim in the aggregate, it is likely to be quite substantial from the point of view of individual wrongdoers and thus to constitute a significant deterrent to fraud. Happily, the rules of civil procedure provide a clear fix for the problem. First, the law is clear that a claim that can be handled as a derivative claim must be handled as a derivative claim and that a derivative claim must be resolved first before any class claim may be addressed. Second, no class action may proceed unless the court certifies it as a proper class action. And no action may be so certified if there is any other equally good way to litigate the issues (as by means of a derivative action). But someone make the argument. It is puzzling that no one has done so, especially because derivative actions eliminate feedback losses and serve to restore stock price. There are several possible explanations. One is that insurance does not cover derivative claims as it does class claims. Another is that attorney fees are likely to be higher in class actions than in derivative actions. These factors may incline plaintiff lawyers to favor class actions even though investors would be better served by derivative actions. On the other hand, until now no one has quantified the costs and benefits of class actions for real world investors. As shown here, index funds almost always lose more than they gain and thus should oppose class actions in favor of derivative actions. Indeed, index funds owe a duty to their investors to do so.","PeriodicalId":82746,"journal":{"name":"South Carolina law review","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2012-01-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"1","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"South Carolina law review","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1996587","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

Abstract

Most legal scholars agree that securities fraud class actions do little to compensate investors. Most investors are well diversified and thus are just as likely to sell an overpriced stock as to buy one. Moreover, since the defendant company ultimately pays in a successful class action, holders effectively pay buyers. Although this circularity is widely recognized, few have noted that because of the anticipated payout, the prospect of a class action causes stock price to decline by more than it otherwise would, thus generating additional (feedback) loss for both buyers and holders. In this article, I describe a method by which one can measure the net effect of class actions on fund investors who are both buyers and holders of a fraud-affected stock. Since an index fund almost always holds more shares than it buys during the fraud period, an index fund almost always loses more than it gains. Thus, class actions systematically penalize rational index fund investors for the benefit of irrational undiversified stock-picking investors. Accordingly, index funds should oppose class actions as contrary to the best interest of investors. To be sure, one possible problem is that in the absence of the deterrent effect of class actions, there might be more securities fraud. The answer is that whenever there is a meritorious class claim, the corporation itself will also have a claim – against the individual wrongdoers – for any increase in cost of capital resulting from reputational harm and any direct expenses relating to enforcement proceedings. In a class action, these elements of loss are imbedded in the price decrease that occurs when the fraud is discovered. But these losses are in fact suffered by the corporation and should be the subject of a derivative action for the benefit of the corporation – and thus all of the stockholders – not a class action for the benefit only of those who bought during the fraud period. Although the corporation claim may be smaller than the class claim in the aggregate, it is likely to be quite substantial from the point of view of individual wrongdoers and thus to constitute a significant deterrent to fraud. Happily, the rules of civil procedure provide a clear fix for the problem. First, the law is clear that a claim that can be handled as a derivative claim must be handled as a derivative claim and that a derivative claim must be resolved first before any class claim may be addressed. Second, no class action may proceed unless the court certifies it as a proper class action. And no action may be so certified if there is any other equally good way to litigate the issues (as by means of a derivative action). But someone make the argument. It is puzzling that no one has done so, especially because derivative actions eliminate feedback losses and serve to restore stock price. There are several possible explanations. One is that insurance does not cover derivative claims as it does class claims. Another is that attorney fees are likely to be higher in class actions than in derivative actions. These factors may incline plaintiff lawyers to favor class actions even though investors would be better served by derivative actions. On the other hand, until now no one has quantified the costs and benefits of class actions for real world investors. As shown here, index funds almost always lose more than they gain and thus should oppose class actions in favor of derivative actions. Indeed, index funds owe a duty to their investors to do so.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
指数基金和证券欺诈诉讼
大多数法律学者都认为,证券欺诈集体诉讼对投资者的补偿作用不大。大多数投资者都很善于分散投资,因此,他们既可能卖出价格过高的股票,也可能买入过高的股票。此外,由于成功的集体诉讼中被告公司最终支付了赔偿金,因此持有人实际上支付给了买家。尽管这种循环性得到了广泛认可,但很少有人注意到,由于预期的支付,集体诉讼的前景导致股价下跌幅度大于预期,从而给买家和股东带来额外的(反馈)损失。在这篇文章中,我描述了一种方法,通过这种方法可以衡量集体诉讼对基金投资者的净影响,这些投资者既是受欺诈影响的股票的买家,也是持有人。由于在欺诈期间,指数基金持有的股票几乎总是多于买入的股票,因此指数基金的损失几乎总是大于收益。因此,集体诉讼系统地惩罚了理性的指数基金投资者,而有利于非理性的单一选股投资者。因此,指数基金应反对集体诉讼,因为这违背了投资者的最大利益。可以肯定的是,一个可能的问题是,如果没有集体诉讼的威慑作用,可能会出现更多的证券欺诈。答案是,每当有值得赞扬的集体索赔时,公司本身也将对因声誉损害和与执法程序有关的任何直接费用而导致的资本成本增加提出索赔-针对个人违法者。在集体诉讼中,当欺诈行为被发现时,这些损失因素都包含在价格下降中。但这些损失实际上是由公司承担的,应该是为了公司的利益——以及所有股东的利益——而不是为了那些在欺诈期间购买股票的人的利益而提起的集体诉讼。虽然公司的索赔总额可能小于集体索赔,但从个别违法者的角度来看,这可能是相当可观的,因此对欺诈构成了重大的威慑。令人高兴的是,民事诉讼规则为这个问题提供了一个明确的解决方案。首先,法律明确规定,可以作为派生索赔处理的索赔必须作为派生索赔处理,派生索赔必须在处理任何集体索赔之前先得到解决。第二,除非法院证明集体诉讼是正当的集体诉讼,否则不得提起集体诉讼。如果存在其他同样好的诉讼方式(如通过派生诉讼的方式),则任何诉讼均不得如此证明。但是有人提出了这样的观点。令人费解的是,没有人这样做,尤其是因为衍生品行为消除了反馈损失,有助于恢复股价。有几种可能的解释。一是保险不包括衍生索赔,因为它包括集体索赔。另一个原因是,集体诉讼的律师费可能高于衍生诉讼。这些因素可能使原告律师倾向于集体诉讼,尽管衍生诉讼对投资者更有利。另一方面,到目前为止,还没有人量化集体诉讼对现实世界投资者的成本和收益。如图所示,指数基金几乎总是损失大于收益,因此应该反对集体诉讼,而支持衍生诉讼。事实上,指数基金对其投资者负有这样做的责任。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
When to Praise the Machine: The Promise and Perils of Automated Transactional Drafting If It Walks Like Systematic Exclusion and Quacks Like Systematic Exclusion: Follow-Up on Removal of Women and African-Americans in Jury Selection in South Carolina Capital Cases, 1997-2014 Against Employer Dumpster Diving for E-Mail Index Funds and Securities Fraud Litigation Personal Jurisdiction in the Twenty-First Century: The Ironic Legacy of Justice Brennan
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1