Executive Superstars, Peer Groups and Overcompensation: Cause, Effect and Solution

Charles m. Elson, Craig K. Ferrere
{"title":"Executive Superstars, Peer Groups and Overcompensation: Cause, Effect and Solution","authors":"Charles m. Elson, Craig K. Ferrere","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2125979","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"In setting the pay of their CEOs, boards invariably reference the pay of the executives at other enterprises in similar industries and of similar size and complexity. In what is described as “competitive benchmarking”, compensation levels are generally targeted to either the 50th, 75th, or 90th percentile. This process is alleged to provide an effective gauge of “market wages” which are necessary for executive retention. As we will describe, this conception of such a market was created purely by happenstance and based upon flawed assumptions, particularly the easy transferability of executive talent. Because of its uniform application across companies, the effects of structural flaws in its design significantly affect the level of executive compensation. It has been observed in both the academic and professional communities that the practice of targeting the pay of executives to median or higher levels of the competitive benchmark will naturally create an upward bias and movement in total compensation amounts. Whether this escalation has been dramatic or merely incremental, the compounded effect has been to create a significant disparity between the pay of CEOs and what is appropriate to the companies they run. This is not surprising. By basing pay on primarily external comparisons, a separate regime which was untethered from the actual wage structures of the rest of the organization was established. Over time, these disconnected systems were bound to diverge. The pay of a chief executive officer, however, has a profound effect on the incentive structure throughout the corporate hierarchy. Rising pay thus has costs far greater than the amount actually transferred to the CEOs themselves. To mitigate this, boards must set pay in a manner in which is more consistent with the internal corporate wage structures. An important step in that direction is to diminish the focus on external benchmarking. We argue that: (I) theories of optimal market-based contracting are misguided in that they are predicated upon the chimerical notion of vigorous and competitive markets for transferable executive talent; (II) that even boards comprised of only the most faithful fiduciaries of shareholder interests will fail to reach an agreeable resolution to the compensation conundrum because of the unfounded reliance on the structurally malignant and unnecessary process of peer benchmarking; and, (III) that the solution lies in avoiding the mechanistic and arbitrary application of peer group data in arriving at executive compensation levels. Instead, independent and shareholder-conscious compensation committees must develop internally created standards of pay based on the individual nature of the organization concerned, its particular competitive environment and its internal dynamics.","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"38 1","pages":"487"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2012-08-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.2125979","citationCount":"33","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"The Journal of corporation law","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2125979","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 33

Abstract

In setting the pay of their CEOs, boards invariably reference the pay of the executives at other enterprises in similar industries and of similar size and complexity. In what is described as “competitive benchmarking”, compensation levels are generally targeted to either the 50th, 75th, or 90th percentile. This process is alleged to provide an effective gauge of “market wages” which are necessary for executive retention. As we will describe, this conception of such a market was created purely by happenstance and based upon flawed assumptions, particularly the easy transferability of executive talent. Because of its uniform application across companies, the effects of structural flaws in its design significantly affect the level of executive compensation. It has been observed in both the academic and professional communities that the practice of targeting the pay of executives to median or higher levels of the competitive benchmark will naturally create an upward bias and movement in total compensation amounts. Whether this escalation has been dramatic or merely incremental, the compounded effect has been to create a significant disparity between the pay of CEOs and what is appropriate to the companies they run. This is not surprising. By basing pay on primarily external comparisons, a separate regime which was untethered from the actual wage structures of the rest of the organization was established. Over time, these disconnected systems were bound to diverge. The pay of a chief executive officer, however, has a profound effect on the incentive structure throughout the corporate hierarchy. Rising pay thus has costs far greater than the amount actually transferred to the CEOs themselves. To mitigate this, boards must set pay in a manner in which is more consistent with the internal corporate wage structures. An important step in that direction is to diminish the focus on external benchmarking. We argue that: (I) theories of optimal market-based contracting are misguided in that they are predicated upon the chimerical notion of vigorous and competitive markets for transferable executive talent; (II) that even boards comprised of only the most faithful fiduciaries of shareholder interests will fail to reach an agreeable resolution to the compensation conundrum because of the unfounded reliance on the structurally malignant and unnecessary process of peer benchmarking; and, (III) that the solution lies in avoiding the mechanistic and arbitrary application of peer group data in arriving at executive compensation levels. Instead, independent and shareholder-conscious compensation committees must develop internally created standards of pay based on the individual nature of the organization concerned, its particular competitive environment and its internal dynamics.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
高管巨星、同辈群体与薪酬过高:原因、影响与对策
在确定首席执行官的薪酬时,董事会总是参照类似行业、规模和复杂程度相似的其他企业高管的薪酬。在所谓的“竞争性基准”中,薪酬水平通常以第50、75或90个百分位为目标。据称,这一过程提供了对“市场工资”的有效衡量标准,而“市场工资”是留住高管所必需的。正如我们将描述的那样,这种市场的概念纯粹是偶然产生的,并且基于有缺陷的假设,特别是管理人才的容易转移性。由于其在各公司的统一应用,其设计中的结构性缺陷的影响显著影响高管薪酬水平。学术界和专业人士都观察到,将高管薪酬定为竞争基准的中位数或更高水平的做法,自然会造成薪酬总额的上升倾向和变动。无论这种升级是戏剧性的,还是仅仅是渐进的,其复合效应是在首席执行官的薪酬与他们所经营的公司的薪酬之间造成了巨大的差距。这并不奇怪。由于薪金主要以外部比较为基础,因此建立了一个与组织其他部门的实际工资结构无关的单独制度。随着时间的推移,这些不相连的系统必然会分化。然而,首席执行官的薪酬对整个公司层级的激励结构有着深远的影响。因此,加薪的成本远远大于实际转移到首席执行官本人身上的金额。为了缓解这种情况,董事会必须以一种与公司内部工资结构更一致的方式设定薪酬。朝着这个方向迈出的重要一步是减少对外部基准的关注。我们认为:(1)基于市场的最优契约理论是错误的,因为它们是建立在一个虚幻的概念之上的,即对于可转移的管理人才来说,市场是充满活力和竞争的;(二)即使董事会只由最忠实的股东利益受托人组成,也无法就薪酬难题达成一致的解决方案,因为毫无根据地依赖于结构性恶性和不必要的同行基准过程;(三)解决方案在于避免在确定高管薪酬水平时机械性和武断地使用同行群体数据。相反,独立和有股东意识的薪酬委员会必须根据有关组织的个别性质、其特殊的竞争环境及其内部动态,制订内部制定的薪酬标准。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
The nature of profits Conclusion Investment Corporate governance How to Enhance Directors’ Independence at Controlled Companies
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1