首页 > 最新文献

The Journal of corporation law最新文献

英文 中文
The nature of profits 利润的本质
Pub Date : 2020-04-15 DOI: 10.4324/9780367351496-2
D. Mueller
{"title":"The nature of profits","authors":"D. Mueller","doi":"10.4324/9780367351496-2","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.4324/9780367351496-2","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"5 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-04-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"74415500","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Investment 投资
Pub Date : 2020-04-15 DOI: 10.4324/9780367351496-7
D. Mueller
{"title":"Investment","authors":"D. Mueller","doi":"10.4324/9780367351496-7","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.4324/9780367351496-7","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"206 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-04-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"75553438","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Conclusion 结论
Pub Date : 2020-04-15 DOI: 10.4324/9780367351496-10
D. Mueller
{"title":"Conclusion","authors":"D. Mueller","doi":"10.4324/9780367351496-10","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.4324/9780367351496-10","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"11 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-04-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"75170661","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Corporate governance 公司治理
Pub Date : 2020-04-15 DOI: 10.4324/9780367351496-6
D. Mueller
{"title":"Corporate governance","authors":"D. Mueller","doi":"10.4324/9780367351496-6","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.4324/9780367351496-6","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"74 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-04-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"83217952","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
How to Enhance Directors’ Independence at Controlled Companies 如何提高控股公司董事的独立性
Pub Date : 2018-09-29 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.3257432
G. Strampelli
Directors' independence at controlled companies is an intriguing corporate governance conundrum. Recently, Bebchuk and Hamdani have shed new light on it by providing an analytical framework which seeks to make independent directors more effective in performing their oversight role. They convincingly argue that some independent directors should be accountable to public investors who, in order to achieve this aim, should have the power to influence the election or retention of several "enhanced-independence" directors. Starting from this persuasive outcome, and adopting a comparative and functional analysis, this Article will further extend the Bebchuk and Hamdani framework in several directions, with the aim of rendering it more effective and adaptable to different jurisdictions around the world. First, reliance only on the initiative of activist hedge funds might raise some concerns with regard to the effectiveness of enhanced-independence directors as monitors as well as to the cohesiveness of the board. This Article will therefore argue that the involvement of non-activist institutional investors in the selection and election of enhanced-independence directors should be enhanced. It will further argue that the refinement of the election and retention process for independent directors might not be enough in order to tangibly enhance their independence, as the "human nature" of corporate boards must be taken into consideration as well. Pursuing this line of thought, it will develop an in-depth analysis of strategies available in order to limit the distorting effects of the board’s relational dimension and to induce enhanced-independence directors to perform their oversight role in a truly independent way.
控股公司董事的独立性是一个有趣的公司治理难题。最近,Bebchuk和Hamdani通过提供一个旨在使独立董事更有效地履行其监督职责的分析框架,对这一问题进行了新的阐释。他们令人信服地认为,一些独立董事应该对公众投资者负责,为了实现这一目标,公众投资者应该有权影响几位“增强独立性”董事的选举或留任。本文将从这一有说服力的结果出发,采用比较和功能分析,在几个方向上进一步扩展Bebchuk和Hamdani框架,目的是使其更有效,更适应世界各地不同的司法管辖区。首先,仅仅依赖激进对冲基金的主动性,可能会引起人们对增强独立性的董事作为监督者的有效性以及董事会凝聚力的担忧。因此,本文将认为,应加强非激进机构投资者对增强独立董事的选择和选举的参与。本文将进一步论证,为了切实提高独立董事的独立性,仅仅完善独立董事的选举和留任程序可能是不够的,因为还必须考虑公司董事会的“人性”。遵循这一思路,本文将对现有策略进行深入分析,以限制董事会关系维度的扭曲效应,并诱导增强独立性的董事以真正独立的方式履行其监督角色。
{"title":"How to Enhance Directors’ Independence at Controlled Companies","authors":"G. Strampelli","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.3257432","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3257432","url":null,"abstract":"Directors' independence at controlled companies is an intriguing corporate governance conundrum. Recently, Bebchuk and Hamdani have shed new light on it by providing an analytical framework which seeks to make independent directors more effective in performing their oversight role. They convincingly argue that some independent directors should be accountable to public investors who, in order to achieve this aim, should have the power to influence the election or retention of several \"enhanced-independence\" directors. Starting from this persuasive outcome, and adopting a comparative and functional analysis, this Article will further extend the Bebchuk and Hamdani framework in several directions, with the aim of rendering it more effective and adaptable to different jurisdictions around the world. First, reliance only on the initiative of activist hedge funds might raise some concerns with regard to the effectiveness of enhanced-independence directors as monitors as well as to the cohesiveness of the board. This Article will therefore argue that the involvement of non-activist institutional investors in the selection and election of enhanced-independence directors should be enhanced. It will further argue that the refinement of the election and retention process for independent directors might not be enough in order to tangibly enhance their independence, as the \"human nature\" of corporate boards must be taken into consideration as well. Pursuing this line of thought, it will develop an in-depth analysis of strategies available in order to limit the distorting effects of the board’s relational dimension and to induce enhanced-independence directors to perform their oversight role in a truly independent way.","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"44 1","pages":"103-150"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-09-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.3257432","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43502370","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
A Job Is Not a Hobby: The Judicial Revival of Corporate Paternalism and Its Problematic Implications 工作不是爱好:企业家长式作风的司法复兴及其问题含义
Pub Date : 2015-09-22 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2555816
L. Strine
This article connects the Supreme Court’s decision in Burwell v. Hobby Lobby to the history of “corporate paternalism.” It details the history of employer efforts to restrict the freedom of employees, and legislative attempts to ensure worker freedom. It also highlights the role of employment in healthcare coverage, and situates the Affordable Care Act’s “minimum essential guarantees” in a historical and global context. The article also discusses how Hobby Lobby combines with the Supreme Court’s earlier decisions in Citizens United and National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius to constrain the government’s ability to extend the social safety net, and shows how those decisions put pressure on corporate law itself.
这篇文章将最高法院在Burwell v. Hobby Lobby一案中的判决与“企业家长式作风”的历史联系起来。它详细介绍了雇主努力限制雇员自由的历史,以及立法努力确保工人自由的历史。它还强调了就业在医疗保险中的作用,并将《平价医疗法案》的“最低基本保障”置于历史和全球背景下。这篇文章还讨论了Hobby Lobby如何与最高法院早期在“联合公民”和“全国独立企业联合会诉西贝利厄斯案”中做出的裁决相结合,限制政府扩大社会保障网络的能力,并展示了这些裁决如何对公司法本身施加压力。
{"title":"A Job Is Not a Hobby: The Judicial Revival of Corporate Paternalism and Its Problematic Implications","authors":"L. Strine","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2555816","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2555816","url":null,"abstract":"This article connects the Supreme Court’s decision in Burwell v. Hobby Lobby to the history of “corporate paternalism.” It details the history of employer efforts to restrict the freedom of employees, and legislative attempts to ensure worker freedom. It also highlights the role of employment in healthcare coverage, and situates the Affordable Care Act’s “minimum essential guarantees” in a historical and global context. The article also discusses how Hobby Lobby combines with the Supreme Court’s earlier decisions in Citizens United and National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius to constrain the government’s ability to extend the social safety net, and shows how those decisions put pressure on corporate law itself.","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"41 1","pages":"71"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-09-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68201574","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 18
Law Firm Selection and the Value of Transactional Lawyering 律师事务所选择与交易律师业务的价值
Pub Date : 2015-08-11 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2642299
Elisabeth de Fontenay
Following the contraction in demand for law firms’ services during the Great Recession, “Big Law” was widely diagnosed as suffering from several maladies that would spell its ultimate demise, including excessive fees, excessive size, increased competition from in-house counsel, the commoditization of legal work, and the decline in demand for “relationship firms.” While each of these market pressures is only too real for certain segments of the law-firm population, their threat to the most elite U.S. law firms has been largely misunderstood. Even as many firms reduce their fees and contract in size, we should expect certain firms to continue to charge more and grow bigger. The current prescriptions for fixing Big Law fail to recognize that the top-tier firms within the group serve a unique market function. Focusing on a particular type of legal work – major corporate transactions – this Article proposes a novel theory of the value created by elite law firms: their private information about “market” deal terms, acquired through repeated exposure to the same types of transactions, provides clients with a significant bargaining advantage in deal negotiations. By aggregating expertise in the ever-changing and ever-increasing set of deal terms for certain transactions, law firms help their clients price such terms more accurately and thereby maximize their surplus from the deal. This pricing function – traditionally thought to be limited to investment banks – is one that cannot be replicated or subsumed by in-house counsel, other service providers, or commoditized contracts.
在经济大衰退期间,对律师事务所服务的需求萎缩之后,人们普遍认为,“大律师事务所”患上了几种最终导致其灭亡的疾病,包括过高的费用、过大的规模、来自内部律师的竞争加剧、法律工作的商品化以及对“关系公司”需求的下降。虽然这些市场压力对律师事务所的某些部分来说都太真实了,但它们对美国最精英的律师事务所的威胁在很大程度上被误解了。即使许多律所降低收费并缩小规模,我们也应该预期某些律所会继续收取更高的费用并变得更大。目前修复“大律所”的处方未能认识到集团内的顶级律所具有独特的市场功能。本文聚焦于一种特殊类型的法律工作——重大公司交易——提出了一种关于精英律师事务所创造价值的新理论:他们通过反复接触相同类型的交易而获得的关于“市场”交易条款的私人信息,为客户在交易谈判中提供了显著的议价优势。通过对不断变化和不断增加的交易条款集合的专业知识,律师事务所帮助客户更准确地为这些条款定价,从而最大限度地从交易中获利。这种定价功能——传统上被认为仅限于投资银行——是内部法律顾问、其他服务提供商或商品化合同无法复制或纳入的功能。
{"title":"Law Firm Selection and the Value of Transactional Lawyering","authors":"Elisabeth de Fontenay","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2642299","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2642299","url":null,"abstract":"Following the contraction in demand for law firms’ services during the Great Recession, “Big Law” was widely diagnosed as suffering from several maladies that would spell its ultimate demise, including excessive fees, excessive size, increased competition from in-house counsel, the commoditization of legal work, and the decline in demand for “relationship firms.” While each of these market pressures is only too real for certain segments of the law-firm population, their threat to the most elite U.S. law firms has been largely misunderstood. Even as many firms reduce their fees and contract in size, we should expect certain firms to continue to charge more and grow bigger. The current prescriptions for fixing Big Law fail to recognize that the top-tier firms within the group serve a unique market function. Focusing on a particular type of legal work – major corporate transactions – this Article proposes a novel theory of the value created by elite law firms: their private information about “market” deal terms, acquired through repeated exposure to the same types of transactions, provides clients with a significant bargaining advantage in deal negotiations. By aggregating expertise in the ever-changing and ever-increasing set of deal terms for certain transactions, law firms help their clients price such terms more accurately and thereby maximize their surplus from the deal. This pricing function – traditionally thought to be limited to investment banks – is one that cannot be replicated or subsumed by in-house counsel, other service providers, or commoditized contracts.","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"1 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-08-11","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68237063","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Executive Superstars, Peer Groups and Overcompensation: Cause, Effect and Solution 高管巨星、同辈群体与薪酬过高:原因、影响与对策
Pub Date : 2012-08-07 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2125979
Charles m. Elson, Craig K. Ferrere
In setting the pay of their CEOs, boards invariably reference the pay of the executives at other enterprises in similar industries and of similar size and complexity. In what is described as “competitive benchmarking”, compensation levels are generally targeted to either the 50th, 75th, or 90th percentile. This process is alleged to provide an effective gauge of “market wages” which are necessary for executive retention. As we will describe, this conception of such a market was created purely by happenstance and based upon flawed assumptions, particularly the easy transferability of executive talent. Because of its uniform application across companies, the effects of structural flaws in its design significantly affect the level of executive compensation. It has been observed in both the academic and professional communities that the practice of targeting the pay of executives to median or higher levels of the competitive benchmark will naturally create an upward bias and movement in total compensation amounts. Whether this escalation has been dramatic or merely incremental, the compounded effect has been to create a significant disparity between the pay of CEOs and what is appropriate to the companies they run. This is not surprising. By basing pay on primarily external comparisons, a separate regime which was untethered from the actual wage structures of the rest of the organization was established. Over time, these disconnected systems were bound to diverge. The pay of a chief executive officer, however, has a profound effect on the incentive structure throughout the corporate hierarchy. Rising pay thus has costs far greater than the amount actually transferred to the CEOs themselves. To mitigate this, boards must set pay in a manner in which is more consistent with the internal corporate wage structures. An important step in that direction is to diminish the focus on external benchmarking. We argue that: (I) theories of optimal market-based contracting are misguided in that they are predicated upon the chimerical notion of vigorous and competitive markets for transferable executive talent; (II) that even boards comprised of only the most faithful fiduciaries of shareholder interests will fail to reach an agreeable resolution to the compensation conundrum because of the unfounded reliance on the structurally malignant and unnecessary process of peer benchmarking; and, (III) that the solution lies in avoiding the mechanistic and arbitrary application of peer group data in arriving at executive compensation levels. Instead, independent and shareholder-conscious compensation committees must develop internally created standards of pay based on the individual nature of the organization concerned, its particular competitive environment and its internal dynamics.
在确定首席执行官的薪酬时,董事会总是参照类似行业、规模和复杂程度相似的其他企业高管的薪酬。在所谓的“竞争性基准”中,薪酬水平通常以第50、75或90个百分位为目标。据称,这一过程提供了对“市场工资”的有效衡量标准,而“市场工资”是留住高管所必需的。正如我们将描述的那样,这种市场的概念纯粹是偶然产生的,并且基于有缺陷的假设,特别是管理人才的容易转移性。由于其在各公司的统一应用,其设计中的结构性缺陷的影响显著影响高管薪酬水平。学术界和专业人士都观察到,将高管薪酬定为竞争基准的中位数或更高水平的做法,自然会造成薪酬总额的上升倾向和变动。无论这种升级是戏剧性的,还是仅仅是渐进的,其复合效应是在首席执行官的薪酬与他们所经营的公司的薪酬之间造成了巨大的差距。这并不奇怪。由于薪金主要以外部比较为基础,因此建立了一个与组织其他部门的实际工资结构无关的单独制度。随着时间的推移,这些不相连的系统必然会分化。然而,首席执行官的薪酬对整个公司层级的激励结构有着深远的影响。因此,加薪的成本远远大于实际转移到首席执行官本人身上的金额。为了缓解这种情况,董事会必须以一种与公司内部工资结构更一致的方式设定薪酬。朝着这个方向迈出的重要一步是减少对外部基准的关注。我们认为:(1)基于市场的最优契约理论是错误的,因为它们是建立在一个虚幻的概念之上的,即对于可转移的管理人才来说,市场是充满活力和竞争的;(二)即使董事会只由最忠实的股东利益受托人组成,也无法就薪酬难题达成一致的解决方案,因为毫无根据地依赖于结构性恶性和不必要的同行基准过程;(三)解决方案在于避免在确定高管薪酬水平时机械性和武断地使用同行群体数据。相反,独立和有股东意识的薪酬委员会必须根据有关组织的个别性质、其特殊的竞争环境及其内部动态,制订内部制定的薪酬标准。
{"title":"Executive Superstars, Peer Groups and Overcompensation: Cause, Effect and Solution","authors":"Charles m. Elson, Craig K. Ferrere","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2125979","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2125979","url":null,"abstract":"In setting the pay of their CEOs, boards invariably reference the pay of the executives at other enterprises in similar industries and of similar size and complexity. In what is described as “competitive benchmarking”, compensation levels are generally targeted to either the 50th, 75th, or 90th percentile. This process is alleged to provide an effective gauge of “market wages” which are necessary for executive retention. As we will describe, this conception of such a market was created purely by happenstance and based upon flawed assumptions, particularly the easy transferability of executive talent. Because of its uniform application across companies, the effects of structural flaws in its design significantly affect the level of executive compensation. It has been observed in both the academic and professional communities that the practice of targeting the pay of executives to median or higher levels of the competitive benchmark will naturally create an upward bias and movement in total compensation amounts. Whether this escalation has been dramatic or merely incremental, the compounded effect has been to create a significant disparity between the pay of CEOs and what is appropriate to the companies they run. This is not surprising. By basing pay on primarily external comparisons, a separate regime which was untethered from the actual wage structures of the rest of the organization was established. Over time, these disconnected systems were bound to diverge. The pay of a chief executive officer, however, has a profound effect on the incentive structure throughout the corporate hierarchy. Rising pay thus has costs far greater than the amount actually transferred to the CEOs themselves. To mitigate this, boards must set pay in a manner in which is more consistent with the internal corporate wage structures. An important step in that direction is to diminish the focus on external benchmarking. We argue that: (I) theories of optimal market-based contracting are misguided in that they are predicated upon the chimerical notion of vigorous and competitive markets for transferable executive talent; (II) that even boards comprised of only the most faithful fiduciaries of shareholder interests will fail to reach an agreeable resolution to the compensation conundrum because of the unfounded reliance on the structurally malignant and unnecessary process of peer benchmarking; and, (III) that the solution lies in avoiding the mechanistic and arbitrary application of peer group data in arriving at executive compensation levels. Instead, independent and shareholder-conscious compensation committees must develop internally created standards of pay based on the individual nature of the organization concerned, its particular competitive environment and its internal dynamics.","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"38 1","pages":"487"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2012-08-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.2125979","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67927516","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 33
'Enlightened Shareholder Value': Corporate Governance Beyond the Shareholder-Stakeholder Divide “开明的股东价值”:超越股东-利益相关者鸿沟的公司治理
Pub Date : 2010-08-11 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1476116
Harper Ho, E. Virginia
The global financial crisis has led to calls for greater corporate accountability and heightened controls over public corporations. As a result, the past year has seen a marked increase in regulatory initiatives that give shareholders a greater voice in corporate affairs. While debate continues to rage in the academy and beyond over the promise and pitfalls of shareholder empowerment, an important undercurrent in the controversy is the potential impact of "shareholder democracy" on corporate stakeholders. This Article urges a vision of the corporation and its purpose that transcends the shareholder-stakeholder divide. Under this "enlightened shareholder value" approach, which has been introduced statutorially in the United Kingdom, attention to corporate stakeholders, including the environment, employees, and local communities, is seen as critical to generating long-term shareholder wealth. This Article observes that a similar paradigm is now being advanced in the U.S. by leading institutional investors who also identify stakeholder interests as key to long-term firm financial performance and effective risk management. It moves beyond prior literature by articulating a statement of the corporate purpose that is consistent with an investor-driven enlightened shareholder value approach and presents normative arguments in its favor. The Article then considers how enlightened shareholder value intersects with existing corporate governance rules in the U.S. context and the extent to which it in fact represents a departure from the standard shareholder wealth maximization norm. In so doing, it offers a response to some of the concerns surrounding corporate stakeholders that have been raised by skeptics of greater shareholder voice.
全球金融危机促使人们呼吁加强企业问责,加强对上市公司的控制。因此,过去一年里,让股东在公司事务中拥有更大发言权的监管举措明显增多。在学术界和学术界以外,关于股东赋权的前景和缺陷的争论仍在激烈进行,而这场争论中一个重要的暗流是“股东民主”对企业利益相关者的潜在影响。本文提出了一种超越股东与利益相关者之分的公司愿景及其目的。在这种“开明的股东价值”方法下,对企业利益相关者的关注,包括环境、员工和当地社区,被视为创造长期股东财富的关键。这种方法已在英国被法定引入。本文观察到,美国领先的机构投资者正在推进类似的范式,他们也将利益相关者的利益视为公司长期财务绩效和有效风险管理的关键。它超越了先前的文献,阐明了与投资者驱动的开明股东价值方法一致的公司目标声明,并提出了有利于其的规范性论点。然后,本文考虑了开明的股东价值如何与美国背景下现有的公司治理规则相交,以及它实际上在多大程度上偏离了标准的股东财富最大化规范。通过这样做,它回应了对股东话语权扩大持怀疑态度的人提出的围绕企业利益相关者的一些担忧。
{"title":"'Enlightened Shareholder Value': Corporate Governance Beyond the Shareholder-Stakeholder Divide","authors":"Harper Ho, E. Virginia","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1476116","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1476116","url":null,"abstract":"The global financial crisis has led to calls for greater corporate accountability and heightened controls over public corporations. As a result, the past year has seen a marked increase in regulatory initiatives that give shareholders a greater voice in corporate affairs. While debate continues to rage in the academy and beyond over the promise and pitfalls of shareholder empowerment, an important undercurrent in the controversy is the potential impact of \"shareholder democracy\" on corporate stakeholders. This Article urges a vision of the corporation and its purpose that transcends the shareholder-stakeholder divide. Under this \"enlightened shareholder value\" approach, which has been introduced statutorially in the United Kingdom, attention to corporate stakeholders, including the environment, employees, and local communities, is seen as critical to generating long-term shareholder wealth. This Article observes that a similar paradigm is now being advanced in the U.S. by leading institutional investors who also identify stakeholder interests as key to long-term firm financial performance and effective risk management. It moves beyond prior literature by articulating a statement of the corporate purpose that is consistent with an investor-driven enlightened shareholder value approach and presents normative arguments in its favor. The Article then considers how enlightened shareholder value intersects with existing corporate governance rules in the U.S. context and the extent to which it in fact represents a departure from the standard shareholder wealth maximization norm. In so doing, it offers a response to some of the concerns surrounding corporate stakeholders that have been raised by skeptics of greater shareholder voice.","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"36 1","pages":"59"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2010-08-11","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.1476116","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68185666","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 112
Bankruptcy or Bailouts 破产或救助
Pub Date : 2009-03-18 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1362639
Kenneth M. Ayotte, D. Skeel
The usual reaction if one mentions bankruptcy as a mechanism for addressing a financial institution's default is incredulity. Those who favor the rescue of troubled financial institutions, and even those who prefer that their assets be promptly sold to a healthier institution, treat bankruptcy as anathema. Everyone seems to agree that nothing good can come from bankruptcy. Indeed, the Chapter 11 filing by Lehman Brothers has been singled out by many as the primary cause of the severe economic and financial contraction that followed, and proof that bankruptcy is disorderly and ineffective. As a result, ad hoc rescue lending to avoid bankruptcy has been the preferred solution. In this Article, we seek to provide the first careful assessment of the belief that governmental rescues are preferable to bankruptcy. While the interaction of financial firms, systemic risk, and Chapter 11 is complex, our analysis suggests that the widespread belief that bankruptcy should not be used to resolve the distress of financial firms is misguided, and that it has had serious costs in the recent crisis. Although bankruptcy is not always the optimal response to financial distress, it is more effective than is generally realized. In Parts I and II of the Article, we describe the principal problems created by financial distress - debt overhang and creditor runs - and the mechanisms bankruptcy provides for addressing these problems. We then provide historical context in Part III, looking to Drexel Burnham's bankruptcy in 1990 for further lessons about the efficacy of bankruptcy. In Part IV, we turn to firm-specific bailouts, describing this strategy's benefits and the distortions it causes. We then shift our focus back to bankruptcy, considering the (legitimate) concern that it may not adequately counteract systemic risk in Part V, and exploring its treatment of derivatives, one of the chief new habitats of systemic risk, in Part VI. Part VII is a brief conclusion.
如果有人提到破产是解决金融机构违约的一种机制,通常的反应是不相信。那些支持救助陷入困境的金融机构的人,甚至那些希望自己的资产被迅速出售给更健康机构的人,都将破产视为诅咒。每个人似乎都同意破产不会带来任何好处。事实上,雷曼兄弟(Lehman Brothers)申请破产保护被许多人认为是导致随后严重的经济和金融收缩的主要原因,并证明破产是无序和无效的。因此,为避免破产而提供的临时救助贷款一直是首选的解决方案。在这篇文章中,我们试图对政府救助比破产更可取的信念提供第一次仔细的评估。虽然金融公司、系统性风险和破产法第11章之间的相互作用是复杂的,但我们的分析表明,普遍认为不应该用破产来解决金融公司的困境是错误的,而且在最近的危机中,破产已经造成了严重的代价。尽管破产并不总是应对财务困境的最佳办法,但它比人们通常认识到的更为有效。在文章的第一部分和第二部分中,我们描述了金融困境造成的主要问题-债务积压和债权人挤兑-以及破产提供的解决这些问题的机制。然后,我们在第三部分提供了历史背景,从1990年德崇证券的破产中寻求有关破产效力的进一步教训。在第四部分中,我们转向针对特定公司的救助,描述这一策略的好处及其造成的扭曲。然后,我们将焦点转移回破产,在第五部分中考虑到(合理的)担忧,即它可能无法充分抵消系统风险,并在第六部分中探索其对衍生品的处理,衍生品是系统风险的主要新栖息地之一。第七部分是一个简短的结论。
{"title":"Bankruptcy or Bailouts","authors":"Kenneth M. Ayotte, D. Skeel","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1362639","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1362639","url":null,"abstract":"The usual reaction if one mentions bankruptcy as a mechanism for addressing a financial institution's default is incredulity. Those who favor the rescue of troubled financial institutions, and even those who prefer that their assets be promptly sold to a healthier institution, treat bankruptcy as anathema. Everyone seems to agree that nothing good can come from bankruptcy. Indeed, the Chapter 11 filing by Lehman Brothers has been singled out by many as the primary cause of the severe economic and financial contraction that followed, and proof that bankruptcy is disorderly and ineffective. As a result, ad hoc rescue lending to avoid bankruptcy has been the preferred solution. In this Article, we seek to provide the first careful assessment of the belief that governmental rescues are preferable to bankruptcy. While the interaction of financial firms, systemic risk, and Chapter 11 is complex, our analysis suggests that the widespread belief that bankruptcy should not be used to resolve the distress of financial firms is misguided, and that it has had serious costs in the recent crisis. Although bankruptcy is not always the optimal response to financial distress, it is more effective than is generally realized. In Parts I and II of the Article, we describe the principal problems created by financial distress - debt overhang and creditor runs - and the mechanisms bankruptcy provides for addressing these problems. We then provide historical context in Part III, looking to Drexel Burnham's bankruptcy in 1990 for further lessons about the efficacy of bankruptcy. In Part IV, we turn to firm-specific bailouts, describing this strategy's benefits and the distortions it causes. We then shift our focus back to bankruptcy, considering the (legitimate) concern that it may not adequately counteract systemic risk in Part V, and exploring its treatment of derivatives, one of the chief new habitats of systemic risk, in Part VI. Part VII is a brief conclusion.","PeriodicalId":83094,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of corporation law","volume":"35 1","pages":"469"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-03-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.1362639","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68169870","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 77
期刊
The Journal of corporation law
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1