What Does Expanding Horizontal Control Mean for Antitrust Enforcement? A Look at Mergers, Partial Ownership, and Joint Ventures

Diana L. Moss
{"title":"What Does Expanding Horizontal Control Mean for Antitrust Enforcement? A Look at Mergers, Partial Ownership, and Joint Ventures","authors":"Diana L. Moss","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3730310","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"The many mechanisms for expanding horizontal ownership and control of economic resources pose ongoing challenges for merger enforcement. This is readily apparent in markets that have undergone profound structural change from horizontal consolidation and rising concentration over the last several decades, including wireless telecommunications, airlines, hospitals, health insurance, meat processing, and others. Horizontal control is a central concept in industrial organization and frequently encountered concern in antitrust enforcement. For example, the vast majority of all merger transactions challenged by the U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ) Antitrust Division and Federal Trade Commission (FTC) involve some form of horizontal control. Horizontal mergers that completely and permanently eliminate an independent competitor receive the most attention. But other forms of horizontal control that do not completely eliminate a rival — including acquisitions of partial ownership stakes and some joint venture agreements — have no less important implications for competition and consumers. \n \nFor example, production, marketing, and R&D joint ventures (or “competitor collaborations”) can weaken incentives for parties to the agreement to compete independently. Such arrangements have become more common, as we have seen, for example, in the agricultural biotechnology and pharmaceutical sectors. Rivals’ partial ownership stakes in each other, and private equity and institutional investors that acquire stakes in multiple rivals competing in the same product markets, can also weaken competitive incentives. Private equity buyouts raise broader concerns about the damage left behind in the wake of rapid exits and in raising prices to consumers. Yet there remains little transparency around the role of private equity in the broader landscape of horizontal control. Moreover, research indicates that partial ownership can lessen incentives to compete more than under a monopoly. Meanwhile, there is ongoing debate over whether antitrust can reach to competitive issues raised by institutional investor ownership of stock in rivals in sectors such as airlines and banking. \n \nAs antitrust enforcers try to keep pace with the many forms of horizontal control and their competitive implications, we see indications of weakening merger enforcement under Section 7 of the Clayton Act. For example, the scales have tipped sharply toward merging parties in merely predicting the pro-competitive effects of their deals, while the government bears a nearly insurmountable burden of proving that a merger will harm competition. Research shows that the benefits of mergers are often speculative and never materialize, leaving consumers with higher prices, lower quality, less innovation. Moreover, data on merger enforcement reveals that the antitrust agencies increasingly seek remedies for problematic mergers, rather than moving to block them or to force their abandonment. Yet we see a growing list of failed merger remedies, leaving consumers with higher prices, lower quality, and less innovation. \n \nGiven its many faces, ubiquity, and indubitable link to market concentration, it is time to take a fresh look at horizontal control. Analysis in this White Paper reveals troubling issues for antitrust enforcement in light of rising concentration, weakening enforcement, evidence of failed mergers and merger remedies, and growth of the partial ownership model. These takeaways should inform potential antitrust reform proposals and approaches to invigorating merger enforcement and competition policy. The first part of the paper examines the competitive dynamics of different forms of horizontal control. The second part examines major enforcement and policy issues raised by expanding horizontal control and highlights areas of much needed analysis. This includes analyses of failed merger remedies, whether litigated mergers have produced claimed benefits, and how partial ownership acquisitions by private equity firms have affected market concentration. The paper also recommends that the agencies withdraw the “safe harbor” provision for some partial ownership acquisitions in their proposed revisions to the Hart Scott Rodino (HSR) Act filing requirements.","PeriodicalId":11797,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2020-11-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3730310","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

The many mechanisms for expanding horizontal ownership and control of economic resources pose ongoing challenges for merger enforcement. This is readily apparent in markets that have undergone profound structural change from horizontal consolidation and rising concentration over the last several decades, including wireless telecommunications, airlines, hospitals, health insurance, meat processing, and others. Horizontal control is a central concept in industrial organization and frequently encountered concern in antitrust enforcement. For example, the vast majority of all merger transactions challenged by the U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ) Antitrust Division and Federal Trade Commission (FTC) involve some form of horizontal control. Horizontal mergers that completely and permanently eliminate an independent competitor receive the most attention. But other forms of horizontal control that do not completely eliminate a rival — including acquisitions of partial ownership stakes and some joint venture agreements — have no less important implications for competition and consumers. For example, production, marketing, and R&D joint ventures (or “competitor collaborations”) can weaken incentives for parties to the agreement to compete independently. Such arrangements have become more common, as we have seen, for example, in the agricultural biotechnology and pharmaceutical sectors. Rivals’ partial ownership stakes in each other, and private equity and institutional investors that acquire stakes in multiple rivals competing in the same product markets, can also weaken competitive incentives. Private equity buyouts raise broader concerns about the damage left behind in the wake of rapid exits and in raising prices to consumers. Yet there remains little transparency around the role of private equity in the broader landscape of horizontal control. Moreover, research indicates that partial ownership can lessen incentives to compete more than under a monopoly. Meanwhile, there is ongoing debate over whether antitrust can reach to competitive issues raised by institutional investor ownership of stock in rivals in sectors such as airlines and banking. As antitrust enforcers try to keep pace with the many forms of horizontal control and their competitive implications, we see indications of weakening merger enforcement under Section 7 of the Clayton Act. For example, the scales have tipped sharply toward merging parties in merely predicting the pro-competitive effects of their deals, while the government bears a nearly insurmountable burden of proving that a merger will harm competition. Research shows that the benefits of mergers are often speculative and never materialize, leaving consumers with higher prices, lower quality, less innovation. Moreover, data on merger enforcement reveals that the antitrust agencies increasingly seek remedies for problematic mergers, rather than moving to block them or to force their abandonment. Yet we see a growing list of failed merger remedies, leaving consumers with higher prices, lower quality, and less innovation. Given its many faces, ubiquity, and indubitable link to market concentration, it is time to take a fresh look at horizontal control. Analysis in this White Paper reveals troubling issues for antitrust enforcement in light of rising concentration, weakening enforcement, evidence of failed mergers and merger remedies, and growth of the partial ownership model. These takeaways should inform potential antitrust reform proposals and approaches to invigorating merger enforcement and competition policy. The first part of the paper examines the competitive dynamics of different forms of horizontal control. The second part examines major enforcement and policy issues raised by expanding horizontal control and highlights areas of much needed analysis. This includes analyses of failed merger remedies, whether litigated mergers have produced claimed benefits, and how partial ownership acquisitions by private equity firms have affected market concentration. The paper also recommends that the agencies withdraw the “safe harbor” provision for some partial ownership acquisitions in their proposed revisions to the Hart Scott Rodino (HSR) Act filing requirements.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
扩大横向控制对反垄断执法意味着什么?并购、部分所有权和合资企业
扩大经济资源横向所有权和控制的许多机制对合并的执行构成了持续的挑战。在过去几十年经历了横向整合和集中度上升的深刻结构变化的市场中,这一点很明显,包括无线电信、航空、医院、健康保险、肉类加工等。横向控制是产业组织中的一个核心概念,也是反垄断执法中经常遇到的问题。例如,美国司法部(DOJ)反垄断部门和联邦贸易委员会(FTC)质疑的绝大多数合并交易都涉及某种形式的横向控制。完全和永久消除独立竞争者的横向合并最受关注。但其他没有完全消灭竞争对手的横向控制形式——包括收购部分股权和一些合资协议——对竞争和消费者的影响同样重要。例如,生产、营销和研发合资企业(或“竞争对手合作”)会削弱协议各方独立竞争的动机。正如我们在农业生物技术和制药部门所看到的那样,这种安排已变得更加普遍。竞争对手相互持有部分股权,以及私募股权和机构投资者收购在同一产品市场竞争的多家竞争对手的股权,也会削弱竞争激励。私人股本收购引发了更广泛的担忧,即快速退出和价格上涨给消费者带来的损害。然而,在更广泛的横向控制格局中,私人股本所扮演的角色仍然缺乏透明度。此外,研究表明,部分所有权比垄断更能减少竞争的动力。与此同时,关于反垄断是否可以触及机构投资者持有航空和银行业等行业竞争对手股票所引发的竞争问题,目前仍存在争论。由于反垄断执法者试图跟上多种形式的横向控制及其竞争影响的步伐,我们看到了《克莱顿法》第7条削弱合并执法的迹象。例如,在预测并购交易对竞争有利的影响方面,天平已经急剧向并购方倾斜,而政府则承担着几乎无法逾越的责任,要证明并购会损害竞争。研究表明,并购的好处往往是投机性的,永远不会实现,给消费者带来的是更高的价格、更低的质量和更少的创新。此外,关于合并执行的数据显示,反垄断机构越来越多地为有问题的合并寻求补救措施,而不是采取行动阻止它们或强迫它们放弃。然而,我们看到越来越多失败的并购补救措施,给消费者带来更高的价格、更低的质量和更少的创新。考虑到它的多面性、普遍性以及与市场集中度的必然联系,是时候重新审视横向控制了。本白皮书的分析揭示了在集中度上升、执法力度减弱、合并失败和合并补救的证据以及部分所有权模式的增长的背景下,反垄断执法面临的令人不安的问题。这些结论应该为潜在的反垄断改革建议和重振合并执法和竞争政策的方法提供信息。本文第一部分考察了不同形式的横向控制的竞争动态。第二部分审查了扩大横向控制所引起的主要执法和政策问题,并强调了急需分析的领域。这包括对失败的合并补救措施的分析,提起诉讼的合并是否产生了声称的利益,以及私人股本公司的部分所有权收购如何影响市场集中度。该文件还建议,这些机构在修订《高铁法案》(Hart Scott Rodino Act, HSR)备案要求的提议中,撤销针对部分所有权收购的“安全港”条款。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
Sound GUPPI Safe Harbor: A Calibrated Unilateral Effects Screen for Horizontal Mergers with Differentiated Products Consolidation on Aisle Five: Effects of Mergers in Consumer Packaged Goods Optimal Exit Policy with Uncertain Demand Friends in High Places: Demand Spillovers and Competition on Digital Platforms The Ambiguous Competitive Effects of Passive Partial Forward Integration
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1