Decision-Making Rules and Judicial Strategy On the United States Courts of Appeals

B. Atkins
{"title":"Decision-Making Rules and Judicial Strategy On the United States Courts of Appeals","authors":"B. Atkins","doi":"10.1177/106591297202500404","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"HE COMBINED use by the courts of appeals of a three-member rotating panel procedure with an en banc system provides a provocative context for testing hypotheses which relate the strategic options available to policyoriented judges with institutional decision-making rules.' One question of particular interest concerns the extent to which the dual decision-making procedures of the intermediate appellate courts facilitate a minority's ability to circumvent a majority's policy preference. Superficially, a system of rotating panels appears to facilitate a proportionate expression of minority views on a court of appeals. To grasp this proposition, the policy outcomes on the United States Supreme Court as determined by the decisionmaking rules operative there may be compared with a hypothetical instance in which the decisions of the high court are determined by three-judge panels. Two assumptions are made: (1) that the court is composed of two opposing blocs on civil liberty issues, a liberal majority of six and a conservative minority of three; and (2) that defection from a bloc is not permissible. Under these conditions, the liberal segment of the court could determine the gamut of civil liberty policy to be formulated by the court. The conservative minority must be content with either: (1) complete minority status, that is, the status quo; (2) joining the majority in order to parake in the available power to be distributed; (3) capturing votes from the majority in order to form a new coalition; or (4) awaiting shifts in the court's personnel that would be conducive to their conceptions of civil liberty policy. However, if the Supreme Court changed its decision-making procedures so as to permit the formation of threemember panels, the contours of majority-minority conflict would alter dramatically. Incorporating the additional assumptions (1) that all panels may appear with equal probability and (2) that empirically, all panels do in fact contribute equally to decision-making, then a minority of three would clearly contribute to policy-making in those instances when two members of the minority coalition combine to form a panel with a member of the majority or when the three minority members meet simultaneously to form a panel. An implicit assumption of the first eventually is","PeriodicalId":83314,"journal":{"name":"The Western political quarterly","volume":"77 1","pages":"626 - 642"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1972-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"21","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"The Western political quarterly","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1177/106591297202500404","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 21

Abstract

HE COMBINED use by the courts of appeals of a three-member rotating panel procedure with an en banc system provides a provocative context for testing hypotheses which relate the strategic options available to policyoriented judges with institutional decision-making rules.' One question of particular interest concerns the extent to which the dual decision-making procedures of the intermediate appellate courts facilitate a minority's ability to circumvent a majority's policy preference. Superficially, a system of rotating panels appears to facilitate a proportionate expression of minority views on a court of appeals. To grasp this proposition, the policy outcomes on the United States Supreme Court as determined by the decisionmaking rules operative there may be compared with a hypothetical instance in which the decisions of the high court are determined by three-judge panels. Two assumptions are made: (1) that the court is composed of two opposing blocs on civil liberty issues, a liberal majority of six and a conservative minority of three; and (2) that defection from a bloc is not permissible. Under these conditions, the liberal segment of the court could determine the gamut of civil liberty policy to be formulated by the court. The conservative minority must be content with either: (1) complete minority status, that is, the status quo; (2) joining the majority in order to parake in the available power to be distributed; (3) capturing votes from the majority in order to form a new coalition; or (4) awaiting shifts in the court's personnel that would be conducive to their conceptions of civil liberty policy. However, if the Supreme Court changed its decision-making procedures so as to permit the formation of threemember panels, the contours of majority-minority conflict would alter dramatically. Incorporating the additional assumptions (1) that all panels may appear with equal probability and (2) that empirically, all panels do in fact contribute equally to decision-making, then a minority of three would clearly contribute to policy-making in those instances when two members of the minority coalition combine to form a panel with a member of the majority or when the three minority members meet simultaneously to form a panel. An implicit assumption of the first eventually is
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
美国上诉法院的决策规则与司法策略
他说:“上诉法院将三人轮流小组程序与全院制度相结合,为测试与政策导向法官可用的战略选择和制度决策规则有关的假设提供了一个具有挑衅性的背景。”一个特别令人感兴趣的问题是,中级上诉法院的双重决策程序在多大程度上便利了少数人规避多数人的政策偏好的能力。从表面上看,轮换小组制度似乎有助于少数人在上诉法院中按比例表达意见。为了把握这一命题,美国最高法院的政策结果由其运作的决策规则决定,可以与高等法院的判决由三名法官组成的小组决定的假设案例进行比较。有两个假设:(1)法院由两个在公民自由问题上对立的集团组成,自由派占多数的6个,保守派占少数的3个;(2)脱离集团是不允许的。在这些条件下,法院的自由派可以决定法院将制定的公民自由政策的范围。保守的少数人必须满足于:(1)完全的少数人地位,即现状;(二)加入多数人,以分享可供分配的权力;(三)夺取多数选票,组成新的联合政府;或者(4)等待法院人员的变动,这将有利于他们对公民自由政策的看法。但是,如果最高法院改变其决策程序,允许组成三人小组,多数人与少数人冲突的轮廓将发生巨大变化。结合额外的假设(1)所有小组可能以相同的概率出现,(2)从经验上看,所有小组实际上对决策的贡献是平等的,那么当少数联盟的两名成员与多数成员联合组成一个小组,或者当三名少数成员同时开会组成一个小组时,三名少数成员显然会对决策做出贡献。第一个隐含的假设最终是
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
Judicial decision making and biological fact: Roe v. Wade and the unresolved question of fetal viability. Bicameralism and the Theory of Voting Party, Ideology, and the Lure of Victory: Iowa Activists in the 1980 Prenomination Campaign Campaign Spending in Contests for Governor The End of Methodology? a Review Essay On Evaluation Research Methods
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1