How China Became Capitalist

D. D. Murphey
{"title":"How China Became Capitalist","authors":"D. D. Murphey","doi":"10.5860/choice.50-2176","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"How China Became Capitalist Ronald Coase and Ning Wang Palgrave Macmillan, 2013China's transition from Maoism to \"capitalism with Chinese characteristics\" is not only one of the principal facts about the global economy today, but is also a subject of great complexity and ambiguity. What is one to make of a society in which Adam Smith is revered while Marxism is still universally taught in the schools? In How China Became Capitalist, Ronald Coase, a Nobel Prize winner in economics, and Ning Wang, an assistant professor at the School of Politics and Global Studies at Arizona State University, have joined in writing an extended essay on the history and economics of China since the Communists completed their victory over Chiang Kai-shek in 1949. It is clear from the book's title that they believe China has \"become capitalist,\" but it is apparent that there is much that is muddled about the transformation. There are many contradictory elements that go together to cook up a social and economic stew that is likely to bubble vigorously for quite a while before it develops any culinary coherence.The subject is of such importance that there is compelling reason for serious minds to read this book attentively. It is full of information new to any reader who isn't a China specialist. At the same time, it is for several reasons hard to recommend it to the general reader. It isn't difficult reading or full of technical information, but neither is it particularly engaging, as one might require of a \"good read.\" Even though the chapter titles suggest a chronological account, there is throughout the book a rather jumbled mixture of time elements, with much rehashing, as though the chapters were done as separate essays independently needing to cover and recover the same ground. The result is not an ordered chronology. We are reminded of Eric Hoffer's observation that many books' content could just as well be stated in a single article, attaining greater concision and clarity. More substantively, a telling criticism is that there is much that Coase and Wang don't explain or even inquire into, leaving many unanswered questions. We will have more to say about that later.Through most of the country's history before the Communist take-over in 1949, \"the family had been the basic social unit and organizational form in rural China.\" Mao changed things radically into the commune system, where \"all assets were taken away from households and managed as collective goods.\" Coase and Wang write of this as \"an extreme form of socialist agricultural management where farming was organized by production teams..., with households treated as employees.\" It will surprise many readers that Mao had an \"instinctive hostility toward centralization.\" There was \"no private property or free market,\" but also \"much less central planning than the name socialism might suggest.\" Although we are told that China received a fair amount of equipment from the Soviet bloc during the first Five Year Plan, the authors don't explain how it happened that Communist China eventually built up \"an impressive nationwide industrial base\" during Mao's tenure. We know that the Great Leap Forward in the late 1950s was an attempt at that, with its command that millions of people try making steel in backyard furnaces, but we also know that that was a disastrous failure. Perhaps a reason industrialization went forward lay in Mao's \"bias against consumer goods.\" On another point, the authors tell us that since there was no market creating a price system, prices were set by \"a powerful computing machine\" that was intended to \"calculate prices scientifically,\" using input-output data. Even though Coase is a prominent economist and may be presumed to know much more than this book tells us, the discussion isn't broadened to inform readers about Wassily Leontief and how his input-output theory became the basis for the Soviet Union's socialist planning. That would have allowed readers to understand China's experience in a broader, less provincial, context. …","PeriodicalId":52486,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Social, Political, and Economic Studies","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2014-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"11","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Journal of Social, Political, and Economic Studies","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.5860/choice.50-2176","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q4","JCRName":"Social Sciences","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11

Abstract

How China Became Capitalist Ronald Coase and Ning Wang Palgrave Macmillan, 2013China's transition from Maoism to "capitalism with Chinese characteristics" is not only one of the principal facts about the global economy today, but is also a subject of great complexity and ambiguity. What is one to make of a society in which Adam Smith is revered while Marxism is still universally taught in the schools? In How China Became Capitalist, Ronald Coase, a Nobel Prize winner in economics, and Ning Wang, an assistant professor at the School of Politics and Global Studies at Arizona State University, have joined in writing an extended essay on the history and economics of China since the Communists completed their victory over Chiang Kai-shek in 1949. It is clear from the book's title that they believe China has "become capitalist," but it is apparent that there is much that is muddled about the transformation. There are many contradictory elements that go together to cook up a social and economic stew that is likely to bubble vigorously for quite a while before it develops any culinary coherence.The subject is of such importance that there is compelling reason for serious minds to read this book attentively. It is full of information new to any reader who isn't a China specialist. At the same time, it is for several reasons hard to recommend it to the general reader. It isn't difficult reading or full of technical information, but neither is it particularly engaging, as one might require of a "good read." Even though the chapter titles suggest a chronological account, there is throughout the book a rather jumbled mixture of time elements, with much rehashing, as though the chapters were done as separate essays independently needing to cover and recover the same ground. The result is not an ordered chronology. We are reminded of Eric Hoffer's observation that many books' content could just as well be stated in a single article, attaining greater concision and clarity. More substantively, a telling criticism is that there is much that Coase and Wang don't explain or even inquire into, leaving many unanswered questions. We will have more to say about that later.Through most of the country's history before the Communist take-over in 1949, "the family had been the basic social unit and organizational form in rural China." Mao changed things radically into the commune system, where "all assets were taken away from households and managed as collective goods." Coase and Wang write of this as "an extreme form of socialist agricultural management where farming was organized by production teams..., with households treated as employees." It will surprise many readers that Mao had an "instinctive hostility toward centralization." There was "no private property or free market," but also "much less central planning than the name socialism might suggest." Although we are told that China received a fair amount of equipment from the Soviet bloc during the first Five Year Plan, the authors don't explain how it happened that Communist China eventually built up "an impressive nationwide industrial base" during Mao's tenure. We know that the Great Leap Forward in the late 1950s was an attempt at that, with its command that millions of people try making steel in backyard furnaces, but we also know that that was a disastrous failure. Perhaps a reason industrialization went forward lay in Mao's "bias against consumer goods." On another point, the authors tell us that since there was no market creating a price system, prices were set by "a powerful computing machine" that was intended to "calculate prices scientifically," using input-output data. Even though Coase is a prominent economist and may be presumed to know much more than this book tells us, the discussion isn't broadened to inform readers about Wassily Leontief and how his input-output theory became the basis for the Soviet Union's socialist planning. That would have allowed readers to understand China's experience in a broader, less provincial, context. …
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
中国如何成为资本主义国家
罗纳德·科斯和王宁,2013中国从毛主义向“有中国特色的资本主义”的过渡不仅是当今全球经济的主要事实之一,也是一个非常复杂和模棱两可的主题。我们该如何看待这样一个社会:亚当•斯密受到尊崇,而马克思主义仍在学校里普遍教授?在《中国是如何成为资本主义的》一书中,诺贝尔经济学奖得主罗纳德•科斯(Ronald Coase)和亚利桑那州立大学政治与全球研究学院助理教授王宁(Ning Wang)共同撰写了一篇关于中国共产党1949年战胜蒋介石以来的历史和经济的长篇文章。从书名中可以清楚地看出,他们相信中国已经“成为资本主义国家”,但很明显,他们对这种转变有很多误解。有许多相互矛盾的因素共同构成了一锅社会和经济炖菜,在形成任何烹饪一致性之前,可能会在相当长一段时间内剧烈起泡。这个主题是如此重要,以至于严肃的人有充分的理由认真阅读这本书。对于非中国问题专家的读者来说,这本书充满了新鲜的信息。同时,由于几个原因,很难把它推荐给普通读者。它并不难读,也不充满技术信息,但也不是特别吸引人,因为人们可能需要“好的阅读”。尽管各章的标题似乎是按时间顺序排列的,但贯穿全书的时间元素相当混乱,有很多重复,就好像各章是作为独立的文章独立完成的,需要涵盖和恢复相同的基础。结果并不是一个有序的年表。我们想起了Eric Hoffer的观察,许多书的内容也可以在一篇文章中陈述,从而获得更简洁和清晰。更重要的是,一个很有说服力的批评是,科斯和王没有解释甚至没有探究很多问题,留下了许多未解的问题。稍后我们将对此进行详细介绍。在1949年共产党掌权之前的大部分历史中,“家庭一直是中国农村的基本社会单位和组织形式。”毛在公社制度下彻底改变了一切,在公社制度下,“所有的财产都从家庭中拿走,作为集体财产来管理。”科斯和王将其描述为“社会主义农业管理的一种极端形式,即农业由生产队组织……在美国,家庭成员被视为雇员。”毛“对中央集权有一种本能的敌意”,这将使许多读者感到惊讶。“没有私有财产或自由市场”,但也“比社会主义这个名字所暗示的要少得多的中央计划”。虽然我们被告知中国在第一个五年计划期间从苏联集团获得了相当数量的设备,但作者并没有解释共产主义中国最终如何在毛任期内建立起“令人印象深刻的全国工业基础”。我们知道,20世纪50年代末的大跃进就是一个尝试,它要求数百万人在后院的熔炉里炼钢,但我们也知道,这是一个灾难性的失败。也许工业化得以推进的一个原因在于毛的“对消费品的偏见”。在另一点上,作者告诉我们,由于没有市场创造价格体系,价格是由“一台强大的计算机器”设定的,它旨在利用投入产出数据“科学地计算价格”。尽管科斯是一位杰出的经济学家,可能被认为知道的比这本书告诉我们的要多得多,但他的讨论并没有扩大到让读者了解瓦西里·莱昂惕夫,以及他的投入产出理论是如何成为苏联社会主义计划的基础的。这将使读者能够在更广泛的背景下理解中国的经验,而不是局限于某个地方。…
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
Journal of Social, Political, and Economic Studies
Journal of Social, Political, and Economic Studies Social Sciences-Political Science and International Relations
CiteScore
0.30
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊介绍: The quarterly Journal of Social, Political and Economic Studies (ISSN 0193-5941), which has been published regularly since 1976, is a peer-reviewed academic journal devoted to scholarly papers which present in depth information on contemporary issues of primarily international interest. The emphasis is on factual information rather than purely theoretical or historical papers, although it welcomes an historical approach to contemporary situations where this serves to clarify the causal background to present day problems.
期刊最新文献
Einstein: His Life and Universe The China Mirage: The Hidden History of American Disaster in Asia Being Mortal: Medicine and What Matters in the End Days of Rage: America's Radical Underground, the FBI, and the Forgotten Age of Revolutionary Violence The Specter of Capital
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1