Of Course Sin Taxes are Regressive

C. Snowdon
{"title":"Of Course Sin Taxes are Regressive","authors":"C. Snowdon","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3853609","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"There should be no debate about whether taxes on food, alcohol, tobacco and soft drinks (‘sin taxes’) are regressive. It can be easily demonstrated empirically, and countless studies have done so. As with most indirect taxes, they take a greater share of income from the poor than from the rich in all plausible scenarios. Sin taxes are regressive if we look at income groups and are even more regressive if we look at individual consumers. They are regressive in the short term and over the life-cycle. Alcohol taxes tend to be less regressive than tobacco and soft drink taxes as a result of high-income groups spending more money on alcoholic drinks, but they remain regressive in most countries. Some advocates for sin taxes claim that they produce health benefits that are progressive, i.e. they disproportionately benefit the poor. Decades of high taxes on tobacco and alcohol in many different countries suggest that this is not true. Despite very high rates of duty, smoking is much more common among low-income groups in Britain and whilst alcohol consumption is lower among these groups, rates of alcohol-related harm are considerably higher. Early evidence casts serious doubt on whether sugary drink taxes have ‘progressive’ health benefits either. Low-income consumers do not seem to have particularly elastic demand for sugary drinks. Even if they enjoyed disproportionate health gains from sin taxes, they would still suffer a net loss to their welfare and the tax would remain regressive in the traditional sense. Excise taxes raise significant sums of money and are relatively easy to collect. It is unrealistic to expect government to be entirely funded by taxes on the rich. Not every part of the tax system can be progressive, but advocates should be honest about the disproportionately high burden of sin taxes on low-income households.<br>","PeriodicalId":350924,"journal":{"name":"Sociology of Religion eJournal","volume":"49 49","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2018-07-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"4","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Sociology of Religion eJournal","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3853609","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4

Abstract

There should be no debate about whether taxes on food, alcohol, tobacco and soft drinks (‘sin taxes’) are regressive. It can be easily demonstrated empirically, and countless studies have done so. As with most indirect taxes, they take a greater share of income from the poor than from the rich in all plausible scenarios. Sin taxes are regressive if we look at income groups and are even more regressive if we look at individual consumers. They are regressive in the short term and over the life-cycle. Alcohol taxes tend to be less regressive than tobacco and soft drink taxes as a result of high-income groups spending more money on alcoholic drinks, but they remain regressive in most countries. Some advocates for sin taxes claim that they produce health benefits that are progressive, i.e. they disproportionately benefit the poor. Decades of high taxes on tobacco and alcohol in many different countries suggest that this is not true. Despite very high rates of duty, smoking is much more common among low-income groups in Britain and whilst alcohol consumption is lower among these groups, rates of alcohol-related harm are considerably higher. Early evidence casts serious doubt on whether sugary drink taxes have ‘progressive’ health benefits either. Low-income consumers do not seem to have particularly elastic demand for sugary drinks. Even if they enjoyed disproportionate health gains from sin taxes, they would still suffer a net loss to their welfare and the tax would remain regressive in the traditional sense. Excise taxes raise significant sums of money and are relatively easy to collect. It is unrealistic to expect government to be entirely funded by taxes on the rich. Not every part of the tax system can be progressive, but advocates should be honest about the disproportionately high burden of sin taxes on low-income households.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
当然,罪恶税是递减的
对于食品、酒精、烟草和软饮料的税收(“罪恶税”)是否属于累退性,不应该有任何争论。这可以很容易地从经验上证明,无数的研究都是这样做的。与大多数间接税一样,在所有可能的情况下,它们从穷人那里收取的收入比从富人那里收取的收入要大。如果我们看一下收入群体,罪恶税是递减的,如果我们看一下个人消费者,罪恶税的递减就更大了。它们在短期内和整个生命周期内都是退化的。由于高收入群体在酒精饮料上花费更多的钱,酒精税的累退性往往不如烟草税和软饮料税,但在大多数国家,它们仍然是累退性的。一些罪恶税的倡导者声称,罪恶税带来的健康福利是累进的,也就是说,它们不成比例地惠及穷人。许多不同国家几十年来对烟酒征收的高税收表明,事实并非如此。尽管税率很高,但吸烟在英国的低收入群体中更为普遍,虽然这些群体的酒精消费量较低,但酒精相关危害的发生率却相当高。早期证据对含糖饮料税是否具有“渐进式”健康益处提出了严重质疑。低收入消费者似乎对含糖饮料没有特别灵活的需求。即使他们从罪恶税中获得了不成比例的健康收益,他们仍然会遭受福利的净损失,而且税收仍然是传统意义上的累退。消费税能筹集大量资金,而且征收起来相对容易。指望政府完全靠向富人征税来筹措资金是不现实的。并不是税收体系的每个部分都可以是累进的,但支持者应该诚实地面对低收入家庭所承受的不成比例的高额罪过税负担。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
Religiosity and Corporate Social Responsibility A Meta Model Used for Reviewing Spirituality at Workplace Of Course Sin Taxes are Regressive
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1