John Maynard Keynes Narrates the Great Depression: His Reports to the Philips Electronics Firm

Robert W. Dimand, Bradley W. Bateman
{"title":"John Maynard Keynes Narrates the Great Depression: His Reports to the Philips Electronics Firm","authors":"Robert W. Dimand, Bradley W. Bateman","doi":"10.1080/05775132.2023.2272544","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"AbstractIn October 1929, the Dutch electronics firm Philips approached John Maynatd Keynes to write confidential reports on the state of the British and world economies, which he did from January 1930 to November 1934, at first monthly and then quarterly. These substantial reports (Keynes’s November 1931 report was twelve typed pages) show Keynes narrating the Great Depression in real time, as the world went through the US slowdown after the Wall Street crash, the Credit-Anstalt collapse in Austria, the German banking crisis (summer 1931), Britain’s departure from the gold exchange standard in August and September 1931, the US banking crisis leading to the Bank Holiday of March 1933, the London Economic Conference of 1933, and the coming of the New Deal. This series of reports has not been discussed in the literature, though the reports and surrounding correspondence are in the Chadwyck-Healey microfilm edition of the Keynes Papers. We examine Keynes’s account of the unfolding events of the early 1930s, his insistence that the crisis would be more severe and long-lasting than most observers predicted, and his changing position on whether monetary policy would be sufficient to promote recovery and relate his reading of contemporary events to his theoretical development. Notes1 “Thursday, October 24, is the first of the days which history – such as it is on the subject – identifies with the panic of 1929” (Galbraith Citation1961, 103–104), but already on Monday, October 21, Irving Fisher had characterized the fall in stock prices as just the “shaking out of the lunatic fringe” and on Tuesday, Charles Mitchell of the National City Bank declared that “the decline has gone too far” (Galbraith Citation1961, 102).2 Philips Incandescent Lamp Works, later Philips Electronics, successor to a firm founded by Lion Philips (originally Presburg), maternal uncle of Karl Marx (Gabriel Citation2011, 44, 110, 291-93, 295, 299, 315, 334, 366). Although relations between uncle and nephew were “strained by politics” (Gabriel Citation2011, 291), Mary Gabriel (Citation2011, 299) refers to Marx’s “fund of last resort, his uncle … He had sold himself to this pragmatic businessman as a successful writer only temporarily short of cash.” Gabriel (Citation2011, 642) remarks that “Marx’s dabbling in the stock market has been questioned by some scholars, who believe he may simply have wanted his uncle to believe he was engaged in ‘capital’ transactions, not Capital.” After the death of Lion Philips, his sons did not reply to Marx’s letter asking for help with his daughter Laura’s wedding (Gabriel Citation2011, 364). Anthony Sampson (Citation1968, 95) reported that the firm’s chairman Frits Philips was “a keen Moral Rearmer and a fervent anti-communist, embarrassed by the fact that his grandfather was a cousin of Karl Marx.”3 For a sense of what £150 a year might have meant to Keynes: Moggridge (Citation1992, 508, 585) and Skidelsky (Citation2003, 417–418, 519, 565) report that Keynes’s net worth fluctuated from £44,000 at the end of 1927 to £7,815 at the end of 1929, then rising to over £506,222 at the end of 1936, dropping again to £181,244 at the end of 1938. The offer from Philips came at a particularly low point in his finances. According to Skidelsky (Citation2003, 265) “investment, directorship and consultancy income” accounted for more than 70% of Keynes’s income between 1923-24 and 1928-29 (including £1,000 a year as chairman of National Mutual Life Assurance), books and articles for another 20%, leaving no more than a tenth of income from such academic sources as teaching, examining, being secretary of the Royal Economic Society and editor of its journal, and being Bursar and a Fellow of King’s College.4 However, writing to Keynes on January 21, H. du Pré was moved “to remark that the latest figures from the Argentine which, according to the handwritten note at the bottom of your letter, you intended to enclose, were not received here, so that we cannot give you an opinion about their importance for us.”5 When the majority report of the May Committee on National Expenditure projected on July 31, 1931, that the budget deficit for 1931-32 would be £120 million, necessitating £96 million of cuts to unemployment benefits, road construction, and government and armed forces pay, it counted all borrowing by the Unemployment and Road funds as “public expenditure on current account” as well as “the usual provision for the redemption of debt” of £50 million (Winch Citation1969, 126–130). Keynes accused the majority on the May Committee of not “having given a moment’s thought to the possible repercussions of their programme, either on the volume of unemployment or on the receipts of taxation” – he estimated it would add 250,000 to 400,000 to the unemployed, and reduce tax receipts by £70 million (New Statesman and Nation, August 15, 1931; Keynes Citation1971-89, Vol. IX, 141–145; Winch Citation1969, 130, Skidelsky Citation2003, 446).6 With regard to Britain, Keynes noted that “There is, however, tremendous pressure of public opinion towards the Government Economy, which means in the main a reduction in the salaries of Government employees and of the allowances of the unemployed. It is equally difficult for the present [Labour] Government either to refuse or concede concessions to this trend of opinion. But if a movement in this direction takes place, which is still most doubtful, it remains exceedingly open to argument whether the result on the actual level of unemployment will be favourable.”7 Keynes had given three Harris Foundation Lectures on “An Economic Analysis of Unemployment” at the University of Chicago in June and July 1931, published in Quincy Wright, ed. (Citation1931), and reprinted in Keynes (Citation1971-89), Vol. XIII. These lectures mostly expounded the analysis of Keynes’s Treatise, but the third lecture also examined the debt-deflation process, the undermining of the financial structure by an increase in the real value of debts and fall in the nominal value of collateral (Keynes Citation1971-89, Vol. XIII, 359–361, see Dimand Citation2011).8 He also raised a “small personal matter”, asking for advice on buying a new wireless set that would “have a thoroughly good loud speaker, both for voice and music reproduction and should be able to pick up distant stations such as Moscow.”9 A passage crossed-out in the draft of Keynes’s November 1931 letter, in the section discussing the general election, stated that, “As has been the case in the last three or four General Elections, it is that old wretch Lord Rothermere [publisher of the Daily Mail] who has been dead right. It is said that he has made a profit on the crisis of £100,000, buying majorities on the Stock Exchange.” Skidelsky (Citation2003, 472) relates that Keynes “consistently lost money (his own and his friends’) on the results of general elections.”Additional informationNotes on contributorsRobert W. DimandRobert W. Dimand is a professor of economics at Brock University, Canada, and a visiting professor at Yale University, and author of The Origins of the Keynesian and an editor of The Elgar Companion to John Maynard Keynes.Bradley W. BatemanBradley W. Bateman is president emeritus of Randolph College, Virginia, coauthor of Capitalist Revolutionary: John Maynard Keynes and an editor of The Cambridge Companion to Keynes.","PeriodicalId":88850,"journal":{"name":"Challenge (Atlanta, Ga.)","volume":"19 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2023-10-26","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Challenge (Atlanta, Ga.)","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/05775132.2023.2272544","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

AbstractIn October 1929, the Dutch electronics firm Philips approached John Maynatd Keynes to write confidential reports on the state of the British and world economies, which he did from January 1930 to November 1934, at first monthly and then quarterly. These substantial reports (Keynes’s November 1931 report was twelve typed pages) show Keynes narrating the Great Depression in real time, as the world went through the US slowdown after the Wall Street crash, the Credit-Anstalt collapse in Austria, the German banking crisis (summer 1931), Britain’s departure from the gold exchange standard in August and September 1931, the US banking crisis leading to the Bank Holiday of March 1933, the London Economic Conference of 1933, and the coming of the New Deal. This series of reports has not been discussed in the literature, though the reports and surrounding correspondence are in the Chadwyck-Healey microfilm edition of the Keynes Papers. We examine Keynes’s account of the unfolding events of the early 1930s, his insistence that the crisis would be more severe and long-lasting than most observers predicted, and his changing position on whether monetary policy would be sufficient to promote recovery and relate his reading of contemporary events to his theoretical development. Notes1 “Thursday, October 24, is the first of the days which history – such as it is on the subject – identifies with the panic of 1929” (Galbraith Citation1961, 103–104), but already on Monday, October 21, Irving Fisher had characterized the fall in stock prices as just the “shaking out of the lunatic fringe” and on Tuesday, Charles Mitchell of the National City Bank declared that “the decline has gone too far” (Galbraith Citation1961, 102).2 Philips Incandescent Lamp Works, later Philips Electronics, successor to a firm founded by Lion Philips (originally Presburg), maternal uncle of Karl Marx (Gabriel Citation2011, 44, 110, 291-93, 295, 299, 315, 334, 366). Although relations between uncle and nephew were “strained by politics” (Gabriel Citation2011, 291), Mary Gabriel (Citation2011, 299) refers to Marx’s “fund of last resort, his uncle … He had sold himself to this pragmatic businessman as a successful writer only temporarily short of cash.” Gabriel (Citation2011, 642) remarks that “Marx’s dabbling in the stock market has been questioned by some scholars, who believe he may simply have wanted his uncle to believe he was engaged in ‘capital’ transactions, not Capital.” After the death of Lion Philips, his sons did not reply to Marx’s letter asking for help with his daughter Laura’s wedding (Gabriel Citation2011, 364). Anthony Sampson (Citation1968, 95) reported that the firm’s chairman Frits Philips was “a keen Moral Rearmer and a fervent anti-communist, embarrassed by the fact that his grandfather was a cousin of Karl Marx.”3 For a sense of what £150 a year might have meant to Keynes: Moggridge (Citation1992, 508, 585) and Skidelsky (Citation2003, 417–418, 519, 565) report that Keynes’s net worth fluctuated from £44,000 at the end of 1927 to £7,815 at the end of 1929, then rising to over £506,222 at the end of 1936, dropping again to £181,244 at the end of 1938. The offer from Philips came at a particularly low point in his finances. According to Skidelsky (Citation2003, 265) “investment, directorship and consultancy income” accounted for more than 70% of Keynes’s income between 1923-24 and 1928-29 (including £1,000 a year as chairman of National Mutual Life Assurance), books and articles for another 20%, leaving no more than a tenth of income from such academic sources as teaching, examining, being secretary of the Royal Economic Society and editor of its journal, and being Bursar and a Fellow of King’s College.4 However, writing to Keynes on January 21, H. du Pré was moved “to remark that the latest figures from the Argentine which, according to the handwritten note at the bottom of your letter, you intended to enclose, were not received here, so that we cannot give you an opinion about their importance for us.”5 When the majority report of the May Committee on National Expenditure projected on July 31, 1931, that the budget deficit for 1931-32 would be £120 million, necessitating £96 million of cuts to unemployment benefits, road construction, and government and armed forces pay, it counted all borrowing by the Unemployment and Road funds as “public expenditure on current account” as well as “the usual provision for the redemption of debt” of £50 million (Winch Citation1969, 126–130). Keynes accused the majority on the May Committee of not “having given a moment’s thought to the possible repercussions of their programme, either on the volume of unemployment or on the receipts of taxation” – he estimated it would add 250,000 to 400,000 to the unemployed, and reduce tax receipts by £70 million (New Statesman and Nation, August 15, 1931; Keynes Citation1971-89, Vol. IX, 141–145; Winch Citation1969, 130, Skidelsky Citation2003, 446).6 With regard to Britain, Keynes noted that “There is, however, tremendous pressure of public opinion towards the Government Economy, which means in the main a reduction in the salaries of Government employees and of the allowances of the unemployed. It is equally difficult for the present [Labour] Government either to refuse or concede concessions to this trend of opinion. But if a movement in this direction takes place, which is still most doubtful, it remains exceedingly open to argument whether the result on the actual level of unemployment will be favourable.”7 Keynes had given three Harris Foundation Lectures on “An Economic Analysis of Unemployment” at the University of Chicago in June and July 1931, published in Quincy Wright, ed. (Citation1931), and reprinted in Keynes (Citation1971-89), Vol. XIII. These lectures mostly expounded the analysis of Keynes’s Treatise, but the third lecture also examined the debt-deflation process, the undermining of the financial structure by an increase in the real value of debts and fall in the nominal value of collateral (Keynes Citation1971-89, Vol. XIII, 359–361, see Dimand Citation2011).8 He also raised a “small personal matter”, asking for advice on buying a new wireless set that would “have a thoroughly good loud speaker, both for voice and music reproduction and should be able to pick up distant stations such as Moscow.”9 A passage crossed-out in the draft of Keynes’s November 1931 letter, in the section discussing the general election, stated that, “As has been the case in the last three or four General Elections, it is that old wretch Lord Rothermere [publisher of the Daily Mail] who has been dead right. It is said that he has made a profit on the crisis of £100,000, buying majorities on the Stock Exchange.” Skidelsky (Citation2003, 472) relates that Keynes “consistently lost money (his own and his friends’) on the results of general elections.”Additional informationNotes on contributorsRobert W. DimandRobert W. Dimand is a professor of economics at Brock University, Canada, and a visiting professor at Yale University, and author of The Origins of the Keynesian and an editor of The Elgar Companion to John Maynard Keynes.Bradley W. BatemanBradley W. Bateman is president emeritus of Randolph College, Virginia, coauthor of Capitalist Revolutionary: John Maynard Keynes and an editor of The Cambridge Companion to Keynes.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
约翰·梅纳德·凯恩斯讲述大萧条:他给飞利浦电子公司的报告
1929年10月,荷兰飞利浦电子公司找到约翰·梅纳德·凯恩斯,请他撰写有关英国和世界经济状况的机密报告。凯恩斯从1930年1月至1934年11月,开始是每月一次,后来是每季度一次。这些实质性的报告(凯恩斯1931年11月的报告有12页)显示了凯恩斯对大萧条的实时叙述,当世界经历了华尔街崩溃后的美国经济放缓,奥地利信贷-安斯塔特银行倒闭,德国银行业危机(1931年夏天),英国在1931年8月和9月脱离金汇制,美国银行业危机导致1933年3月的银行假期,1933年伦敦经济会议,以及新政的到来这一系列的报告还没有在文献中讨论,虽然报告和周围的通信是在查德威克-希利的凯恩斯论文微缩胶片版。我们将研究凯恩斯对20世纪30年代初发生的事件的描述,他坚持认为危机将比大多数观察家预测的更为严重和持久,以及他在货币政策是否足以促进复苏方面的立场变化,并将他对当代事件的解读与他的理论发展联系起来。注1“10月24日星期四,是历史上——就这个主题而言——第一次与1929年的恐慌相提并论的日子”(Galbraith Citation1961, 103-104),但早在10月21日星期一,欧文·费雪就已经把股价下跌描述为“从极端分子中颤抖出来”,周二,国民城市银行的查尔斯·米切尔宣布“下跌太过分了”(Galbraith Citation1961, 102)飞利浦白炽灯厂,即后来的飞利浦电子公司,是卡尔·马克思的舅舅狮子·飞利浦(原普雷斯堡)创立的公司的继承者(Gabriel Citation2011, 44, 110, 291- 93,295, 299, 315, 334, 366)。尽管叔叔和侄子之间的关系“因政治而紧张”(Gabriel Citation2011, 291),玛丽·加布里埃尔(Mary Gabriel, Citation2011, 299)提到马克思的“最后的资金来源,他的叔叔……他把自己卖给了这个务实的商人,作为一个成功的作家,只是暂时缺钱。”Gabriel (Citation2011, 642)评论说:“马克思涉足股票市场的行为受到了一些学者的质疑,他们认为他可能只是想让他的叔叔相信他从事的是‘资本’交易,而不是《资本论》。”在Lion Philips去世后,他的儿子们没有回复马克思请求帮助他女儿Laura婚礼的信(Gabriel Citation2011, 364)。安东尼·桑普森(引文1968,95)报道说,公司主席弗里茨·飞利浦是“一个热心的道德斗士和一个狂热的反共分子,他为自己的祖父是卡尔·马克思的堂兄而感到尴尬。”为了了解每年150英镑对凯恩斯意味着什么:莫格里奇(citation1992,508,585)和斯基德尔斯基(citation2003,417 - 418,519,565)报告说,凯恩斯的净资产从1927年底的44,000英镑波动到1929年底的7,815英镑,然后在1936年底上升到506,222英镑以上,在1938年底再次下降到181,244英镑。飞利浦的报价是在他财务状况特别糟糕的时候提出的。根据斯基德尔斯基(Citation2003, 265)的说法,“投资、董事和咨询收入”在1923-24年至1928-29年间占凯恩斯收入的70%以上(包括作为国家互助人寿保险公司主席每年1000英镑),书籍和文章占另外20%,剩下的收入不超过十分之一来自教学、考试、担任皇家经济学会秘书和期刊编辑、担任财务主管和国王学院研究员等学术来源。在1月21日给凯恩斯的信中,h·杜·普瑞尔感动地“指出,根据您打算附上的信件底部的手写注释,我们没有收到阿根廷的最新数据,因此我们无法就其对我们的重要性向您发表意见。”5 1931年7月31日,五月国家支出委员会的多数报告预测,1931-32年的预算赤字将达到1.2亿英镑,因此需要削减失业救济金、道路建设、政府和武装部队的开支9600万英镑,它把失业和道路基金的所有借款都计算为“经常项目的公共支出”以及5000万英镑的“通常债务偿还准备金”(Winch Citation1969, 126-130)。凯恩斯指责五月委员会的大多数人“没有考虑过他们的计划可能对失业人数或税收收入产生的影响”——他估计,该计划将增加25万至40万失业人口,并减少7000万英镑的税收收入(《新政治家与国家》,1931年8月15日;凯恩斯引文1971-89,卷九,141-145;Winch Citation1969, 130; Skidelsky Citation2003, 446)。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
Fiscal Stimulus Caused Only 1% of the 8% Rise in U.S. Inflation Institutions as Instruments of Social Welfare “Not a Thing” Seven Legal Reasons the Federal “Debt Ceiling” is Null & Void John Maynard Keynes Narrates the Great Depression: His Reports to the Philips Electronics Firm Notice of duplicate publication: “Globalization and the Labor Market: An Economic Approach.”
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1