Toward the great divergence: Economic growth in the Yangzi Delta, 1393–1953

Runzhuo Zhai
{"title":"Toward the great divergence: Economic growth in the Yangzi Delta, 1393–1953","authors":"Runzhuo Zhai","doi":"10.1111/aehr.70003","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p><i>The dissertation was completed in 2023 at the University of Oxford, under the supervision of Professor Stephen Broadberry. This work was partly funded by Designated Studentship Scholarship of the University of Oxford and PhD Bursary Scheme of Economic History Society</i>.</p><p><i>The full dissertation can be accessed through the Library of the University of Oxford</i>.</p><p>This dissertation examines the economic growth process of the Yangzi Delta, one of China's most developed sub-regions, from 1393 to 1953. For the first time in the literature, an annual-frequency GDP series is constructed using an output-based approach. The new GDP data shed light on how the Yangzi Delta's economy evolved over seven centuries.</p><p>From the perspective of Chinese economic history, the nine Taihu Lake-centred prefectures studied in this dissertation had a GDP per capita well above the national average for a long time (~170%). However, before the mid-19th century, the local economy appeared to be trapped in what Mark Elvin (<span>1973</span>) refers to as the ‘high-level equilibrium trap.’ While the GDP per capita exhibited a Malthusian-style growth pattern, numerous technological and managerial innovations allowed it to remain at a high level.</p><p>In the context of global economic history, this dissertation incorporates the Yangzi Delta's directly calculated GDP into global GDP comparisons for the first time. Since the late 14th century, the Yangzi Delta maintained a GDP per capita level comparable to that of the most developed European economies, including those of Italy, the Netherlands, and Britain. However, by the late 17th century, this neck-and-neck growth pattern came to an end. From that point onward, the leading European economies surpassed the Yangzi Delta in terms of GDP per capita, and the gap widened irreversibly. In short, the Great Divergence is believed to have begun at the end of the 17th century.</p><p>This dissertation is divided into two sections: <i>Measuring Economic Growth</i> (Chapters 2–4) and <i>Analysing Economic Growth</i> (Chapters 5 and 6). To measure economic growth in the Yangzi Delta, I first examine the region's population and cultivated land in Chapter 2. Although many macro-level population and land-use figures exist in Chinese historical records, as Ho (<span>1959</span>) pointed out, these figures cannot be used directly. The primary focus of Chapter 2 is to reconstruct data on population and cultivated land while considering institutional factors. From an institutional perspective, I delve into the traditions and practices of China's statistical system, explaining when the available data can be considered reliable and when it cannot. By carefully assessing the boundaries of the historical data, I am ultimately able to construct a complete set of benchmark data on population and cultivated land in the Yangzi Delta. In the long run, decreasing cultivated land per capita was the dominant characteristic of the region's demographic and land-use patterns.</p><p>Chapter 3 examines the historical agricultural economy of the Yangzi Delta, with the primary objective of constructing a long-term agricultural output dataset. This chapter begins by calculating grain yields per unit of land. I collect nearly 3000 samples from the Yangzi Delta and surrounding areas to establish a long-term grain yield trend series. To capture short-term annual fluctuations, I gather over 20,000 descriptive records from local gazetteers and convert these textual records into ranked series using standardised methods from historical climate studies. The integration of long-term and short-term data allows me to generate an annual-frequency grain yield dataset. Next, I separately examined crop types, cultivated area, and non-crop sectors, combined with grain yields, and ultimately derived an annual-frequency agricultural value-added series.</p><p>Chapter 4 focuses on the industrial and service sectors, beginning with the central question: how did the Yangzi Delta's economic structure evolve over time? This question arises primarily because agricultural output per capita declined over time. If non-agricultural output per capita did not increase significantly, GDP per capita in the Yangzi Delta would have inevitably declined in the long run. In other words, sustaining economic growth in the region would have required substantial structural shifts towards non-agricultural sectors.</p><p>First, I analyze qualitative evidence. Most of the Yangzi Delta's non-agricultural sectors did not appear to have expanded significantly faster than the population. Indeed, the urbanisation rate—often used as an indirect measure of economic structural transformation—suggests that urban population growth did not outpace overall population growth. If these industries only grew at a rate proportional to the population, non-agricultural output per capita would have remained stagnant at best. When agricultural output per capita declined while non-agricultural output remained unchanged, structural changes in the economy inevitably took place, leading to what appears to be a process of proto-industrialisation. However, this transformation was insufficient to prevent a further decline in GDP per capita, as non-agricultural growth did not significantly exceed population growth over the long run. Next, based on the overall trend of non-agricultural sector growth derived from qualitative evidence, I conducted a detailed estimation of industrial and service sector output using the output-based approach.</p><p>The second section, <i>Analyzing Economic Growth</i>, begins in Chapter 5with an investigation of the Yangzi Delta's economic trajectory over several centuries. Using the newly constructed GDP dataset, I explore several key macroeconomic questions: (1) Was the Yangzi Delta the most developed region in China? (2) What were the long-term trends and turning points in the Yangzi Delta's economic growth process? (3) Did the Yangzi Delta experience a Malthusian trap? (4) Can Boserupian or Smithian growth models help explain the region's economic growth patterns?</p><p>Chapter 6 places the Yangzi Delta's economic growth process in a global context, with a particular focus on addressing the <i>Great Divergence Debate</i>. Based on directly estimated GDP data for the Yangzi Delta, I conclude that the Great Divergence occurred at the end of the 17th century when compared to the most developed European economies. I also conduct robustness tests to verify the dating of the Great Divergence and explore several counterfactual scenarios, considering what might have happened if the divergence had not occurred. All available evidence suggests that the Great Divergence took place at the end of the 17th century.</p><p>Beyond the Great Divergence debate, I compare the Yangzi Delta's economy with that of most of Europe and argue that the greatest economic challenge for the Yangzi Delta was not merely the divergence itself but rather the region's failure to capitalise on the broader wave of economic growth that swept across Eurasia during the 19th century. In fact, apart from England, the first long-term and sustained per capita GDP growth in most economies around the world almost all began in the 19th century. In other words, although the Great Divergence in the 17th century caused the Yangzi region to lose its position as the global economic leader, as long as it could take off alongside other economies in the 19th century, it would not be considered too late (such as Japan). However, the per capita GDP of the Yangzi region showed no improvement in the 19th century and was ultimately left behind by the wave of global growth. This failure directly contributed to the Yangzi Delta lagging far behind even the poorest European economies by the early 20th century.</p>","PeriodicalId":100132,"journal":{"name":"Asia‐Pacific Economic History Review","volume":"65 1","pages":"160-162"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2025-02-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aehr.70003","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Asia‐Pacific Economic History Review","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/aehr.70003","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"0","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

The dissertation was completed in 2023 at the University of Oxford, under the supervision of Professor Stephen Broadberry. This work was partly funded by Designated Studentship Scholarship of the University of Oxford and PhD Bursary Scheme of Economic History Society.

The full dissertation can be accessed through the Library of the University of Oxford.

This dissertation examines the economic growth process of the Yangzi Delta, one of China's most developed sub-regions, from 1393 to 1953. For the first time in the literature, an annual-frequency GDP series is constructed using an output-based approach. The new GDP data shed light on how the Yangzi Delta's economy evolved over seven centuries.

From the perspective of Chinese economic history, the nine Taihu Lake-centred prefectures studied in this dissertation had a GDP per capita well above the national average for a long time (~170%). However, before the mid-19th century, the local economy appeared to be trapped in what Mark Elvin (1973) refers to as the ‘high-level equilibrium trap.’ While the GDP per capita exhibited a Malthusian-style growth pattern, numerous technological and managerial innovations allowed it to remain at a high level.

In the context of global economic history, this dissertation incorporates the Yangzi Delta's directly calculated GDP into global GDP comparisons for the first time. Since the late 14th century, the Yangzi Delta maintained a GDP per capita level comparable to that of the most developed European economies, including those of Italy, the Netherlands, and Britain. However, by the late 17th century, this neck-and-neck growth pattern came to an end. From that point onward, the leading European economies surpassed the Yangzi Delta in terms of GDP per capita, and the gap widened irreversibly. In short, the Great Divergence is believed to have begun at the end of the 17th century.

This dissertation is divided into two sections: Measuring Economic Growth (Chapters 2–4) and Analysing Economic Growth (Chapters 5 and 6). To measure economic growth in the Yangzi Delta, I first examine the region's population and cultivated land in Chapter 2. Although many macro-level population and land-use figures exist in Chinese historical records, as Ho (1959) pointed out, these figures cannot be used directly. The primary focus of Chapter 2 is to reconstruct data on population and cultivated land while considering institutional factors. From an institutional perspective, I delve into the traditions and practices of China's statistical system, explaining when the available data can be considered reliable and when it cannot. By carefully assessing the boundaries of the historical data, I am ultimately able to construct a complete set of benchmark data on population and cultivated land in the Yangzi Delta. In the long run, decreasing cultivated land per capita was the dominant characteristic of the region's demographic and land-use patterns.

Chapter 3 examines the historical agricultural economy of the Yangzi Delta, with the primary objective of constructing a long-term agricultural output dataset. This chapter begins by calculating grain yields per unit of land. I collect nearly 3000 samples from the Yangzi Delta and surrounding areas to establish a long-term grain yield trend series. To capture short-term annual fluctuations, I gather over 20,000 descriptive records from local gazetteers and convert these textual records into ranked series using standardised methods from historical climate studies. The integration of long-term and short-term data allows me to generate an annual-frequency grain yield dataset. Next, I separately examined crop types, cultivated area, and non-crop sectors, combined with grain yields, and ultimately derived an annual-frequency agricultural value-added series.

Chapter 4 focuses on the industrial and service sectors, beginning with the central question: how did the Yangzi Delta's economic structure evolve over time? This question arises primarily because agricultural output per capita declined over time. If non-agricultural output per capita did not increase significantly, GDP per capita in the Yangzi Delta would have inevitably declined in the long run. In other words, sustaining economic growth in the region would have required substantial structural shifts towards non-agricultural sectors.

First, I analyze qualitative evidence. Most of the Yangzi Delta's non-agricultural sectors did not appear to have expanded significantly faster than the population. Indeed, the urbanisation rate—often used as an indirect measure of economic structural transformation—suggests that urban population growth did not outpace overall population growth. If these industries only grew at a rate proportional to the population, non-agricultural output per capita would have remained stagnant at best. When agricultural output per capita declined while non-agricultural output remained unchanged, structural changes in the economy inevitably took place, leading to what appears to be a process of proto-industrialisation. However, this transformation was insufficient to prevent a further decline in GDP per capita, as non-agricultural growth did not significantly exceed population growth over the long run. Next, based on the overall trend of non-agricultural sector growth derived from qualitative evidence, I conducted a detailed estimation of industrial and service sector output using the output-based approach.

The second section, Analyzing Economic Growth, begins in Chapter 5with an investigation of the Yangzi Delta's economic trajectory over several centuries. Using the newly constructed GDP dataset, I explore several key macroeconomic questions: (1) Was the Yangzi Delta the most developed region in China? (2) What were the long-term trends and turning points in the Yangzi Delta's economic growth process? (3) Did the Yangzi Delta experience a Malthusian trap? (4) Can Boserupian or Smithian growth models help explain the region's economic growth patterns?

Chapter 6 places the Yangzi Delta's economic growth process in a global context, with a particular focus on addressing the Great Divergence Debate. Based on directly estimated GDP data for the Yangzi Delta, I conclude that the Great Divergence occurred at the end of the 17th century when compared to the most developed European economies. I also conduct robustness tests to verify the dating of the Great Divergence and explore several counterfactual scenarios, considering what might have happened if the divergence had not occurred. All available evidence suggests that the Great Divergence took place at the end of the 17th century.

Beyond the Great Divergence debate, I compare the Yangzi Delta's economy with that of most of Europe and argue that the greatest economic challenge for the Yangzi Delta was not merely the divergence itself but rather the region's failure to capitalise on the broader wave of economic growth that swept across Eurasia during the 19th century. In fact, apart from England, the first long-term and sustained per capita GDP growth in most economies around the world almost all began in the 19th century. In other words, although the Great Divergence in the 17th century caused the Yangzi region to lose its position as the global economic leader, as long as it could take off alongside other economies in the 19th century, it would not be considered too late (such as Japan). However, the per capita GDP of the Yangzi region showed no improvement in the 19th century and was ultimately left behind by the wave of global growth. This failure directly contributed to the Yangzi Delta lagging far behind even the poorest European economies by the early 20th century.

查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
当人均农业产值下降而非农业产值保持不变时,经济结构不可避免地发生了变化,导致了似乎是原工业化的进程。然而,这种转变并不足以阻止人均国内生产总值的进一步下降,因为从长期来看,非农业增长并没有明显超过人口增长。接下来,根据定性证据得出的非农业部门增长的总体趋势,我采用基于产出的方法对工业和服务业部门的产出进行了详细估算。利用新构建的 GDP 数据集,我探讨了几个关键的宏观经济问题:(1)长江三角洲是中国最发达的地区吗?(2)长江三角洲经济增长过程中的长期趋势和转折点是什么?(3)长江三角洲是否经历了马尔萨斯陷阱?(4) 博瑟鲁普增长模型或斯密增长模型是否有助于解释该地区的经济增长模式?根据直接估算的长江三角洲 GDP 数据,我得出结论:与最发达的欧洲经济体相比,大分化发生在 17 世纪末。我还进行了稳健性测试以验证大分化的时间,并探讨了几种反事实情景,考虑如果没有发生大分化可能会发生什么。除了大分流的争论之外,我还将长江三角洲的经济与欧洲大部分地区的经济进行了比较,并认为长江三角洲面临的最大经济挑战不仅仅是分流本身,而是该地区未能利用 19 世纪席卷欧亚大陆的更广泛的经济增长浪潮。事实上,除了英国之外,世界上大多数经济体的人均 GDP 首次长期持续增长几乎都始于 19 世纪。换句话说,尽管 17 世纪的大分化使扬子江地区失去了全球经济领头羊的地位,但只要它能在 19 世纪与其他经济体(如日本)一起腾飞,就不算太晚。然而,扬子地区的人均 GDP 在 19 世纪没有任何起色,最终被全球经济增长的浪潮甩在了后面。这一失败直接导致长江三角洲在 20 世纪初甚至远远落后于最贫穷的欧洲经济体。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
1.00
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
Issue Information A reverse salient: Japan's economic sanctions on enemy business, 1914–1927 Toward the great divergence: Economic growth in the Yangzi Delta, 1393–1953 Land revenue, inequality and development in colonial India (1880–1910) Report of the editor of the Asia-Pacific Economic History Review for 2024
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1