Unintended Consequences of Products Liability: Evidence from the Pharmaceutical Market*

IF 1.3 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Journal of Law Economics & Organization Pub Date : 2020-11-10 DOI:10.1093/jleo/ewaa017
Eric A. Helland, D. Lakdawalla, A. Malani, S. Seabury
{"title":"Unintended Consequences of Products Liability: Evidence from the Pharmaceutical Market*","authors":"Eric A. Helland, D. Lakdawalla, A. Malani, S. Seabury","doi":"10.1093/jleo/ewaa017","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"In a complex economy, production is vertical and crosses jurisdictional lines. Goods are often produced by an upstream national or global firm and improved or distributed by local firms downstream. In this context, heightened products liability may have unintended consequences on product sales and consumer safety. Conventional wisdom holds that an increase in tort liability on the upstream firm will cause that firm to (weakly) increase investment in safety or disclosure. However, this may fail in the real-world, where upstream firms operate in many jurisdictions, so that the actions of a single jurisdiction may not be significant enough to influence upstream firm behavior. Even worse, if liability is shared between upstream and downstream firms, higher upstream liability may mechanically decrease liability of the downstream distributor and encourage more reckless behavior by the downstream firm. In this manner, higher upstream liability may perversely increase the sales of a risky good. We demonstrate this phenomenon in the context of the pharmaceutical market. We show that higher products liability on upstream pharmaceutical manufacturers reduces the liability faced by downstream doctors, who respond by prescribing more drugs than before. Eric Helland Claremont McKenna College Department of Economics Claremont, CA 91711 eric.helland@claremontmckenna.edu Darius Lakdawalla Schaeffer Center for Health Policy and Economics University of Southern California 3335 S. Figueroa St, Unit A Los Angeles, CA 90089-7273 and NBER dlakdawa@healthpolicy.usc.edu Anup Malani University of Chicago Law School 1111 E. 60th Street Chicago, IL 60637 and NBER amalani@uchicago.edu Seth A. Seabury Schaeffer Center for Health Policy and Economics University of Southern California 3335 S. Figueroa St, Unit A Los Angeles, CA 90089-7273 seabury@usc.edu A common feature of modern, complex economies is vertical production that crosses jurisdictional lines. Technological development and specialization is associated with vertical chains of production, where upstream firms supply inputs for downstream firms who add value and sell to consumers. Moreover, firms at all levels have grown in scale and scope, and they now often serve many markets across a range of different jurisdictions. This geographic expansion is perhaps even more pronounced for upstream firms, because downstream firms, such as distributors and retailers, tend to be local or at least retain a well-defined local presence. To remain relevant and effective, tort rules and other legal structures need to account for the interactions among firms in a vertical chain of production. To some extent, tort law has successfully incorporated the reality of vertical production. In the 1800s, a doctrine called “privity” prevented individuals from suing upstream firms for injuries from products of downstream firms. Cases such as MacPherson v. Buick Motor Company (N.Y. 1916) and Smith v. Peerless Glass Co (N.Y. 1932) abandoned the doctrine of privity and allowed consumers to sue firms further upstream (Prosser, 1960). Indeed, contemporary products litigation is now characterized by suits against several firms in the vertical chain of production and has become quantitatively significant.1 Overall torts liability grew four times faster than the overall economic growth rate between 1930 and 1994 (Sturgis, 1995). By 2009, total payments in products liability suits alone amounted to $248.1 billion, or 1.74% of U.S. GDP (Towers Watson, 2010). In health care, suits against doctors amount to 1-2% of physician expenditures (Mello, Chandra, Gawande, & Studdert, 2010), and suits against drug companies amount to 2.26% of all drug expenditures.2 However, an important way in which tort law has lagged the modern economy is in the persistence of local, rather than national or global tort rules. States set tort rules, even though firms may produce for national and even global markets. This has encouraged beggar-thy-neighbor policies by states who may have incentives to shift liability from local downstream defendants to upstream national defendants lacking a local presence (Krauss, 2002). For instance, 22 states have reduced the products liability local retailers face but not the liability that upstream manufacturers face (Shepherd, 2012). Nearly 30 states have caps on total or non-economic damages that physicians face in medical 1 For example, plaintiffs sue both the manufacturer of the car whose tire burst and the manufacturer of the tire (e.g., In re Bridgestone/Firestone, Inc., S.D. Ind. 2003), the home builder that used contaminated materials and the maker of those materials (e.g., In re Chinese Manufactured Drywall Products, E.D. La. 2010), the grocer that used spoiled food and the company that supplied the grocer with the spoiled food (e.g., cases against retailers and farmers implicated in the 2006 E. coli outbreak), and the doctor that prescribed a drug as well as the company that produced it (e.g.,Wyeth v. Levine, U.S. 2009) This last example is also the topic of the empirical application in this paper. 2 This estimate is derived from all settlement special items reported in the income statement. For pharmaceutical companies this represents provisions to alter reserves for litigation and settlement. For other companies the amount would include insurance payments from the firms general liability policy but pharmaceutical firms do not typically have insurance against loses in litigation. As such the sum of the settlement special items represents unexpected payments in litigation. Although some of this litigation is likely not related to product liability the vast majority of loses in excess of reserves is likely major product liability cases—a fact reflected by disclosures in the 10k statements. We sum the total special reserves incurred from 2002-2008 and divide this by total sales over the same period to get the ratio of 2.26%.","PeriodicalId":47987,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Law Economics & Organization","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.3000,"publicationDate":"2020-11-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"3","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Journal of Law Economics & Organization","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewaa017","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q3","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3

Abstract

In a complex economy, production is vertical and crosses jurisdictional lines. Goods are often produced by an upstream national or global firm and improved or distributed by local firms downstream. In this context, heightened products liability may have unintended consequences on product sales and consumer safety. Conventional wisdom holds that an increase in tort liability on the upstream firm will cause that firm to (weakly) increase investment in safety or disclosure. However, this may fail in the real-world, where upstream firms operate in many jurisdictions, so that the actions of a single jurisdiction may not be significant enough to influence upstream firm behavior. Even worse, if liability is shared between upstream and downstream firms, higher upstream liability may mechanically decrease liability of the downstream distributor and encourage more reckless behavior by the downstream firm. In this manner, higher upstream liability may perversely increase the sales of a risky good. We demonstrate this phenomenon in the context of the pharmaceutical market. We show that higher products liability on upstream pharmaceutical manufacturers reduces the liability faced by downstream doctors, who respond by prescribing more drugs than before. Eric Helland Claremont McKenna College Department of Economics Claremont, CA 91711 eric.helland@claremontmckenna.edu Darius Lakdawalla Schaeffer Center for Health Policy and Economics University of Southern California 3335 S. Figueroa St, Unit A Los Angeles, CA 90089-7273 and NBER dlakdawa@healthpolicy.usc.edu Anup Malani University of Chicago Law School 1111 E. 60th Street Chicago, IL 60637 and NBER amalani@uchicago.edu Seth A. Seabury Schaeffer Center for Health Policy and Economics University of Southern California 3335 S. Figueroa St, Unit A Los Angeles, CA 90089-7273 seabury@usc.edu A common feature of modern, complex economies is vertical production that crosses jurisdictional lines. Technological development and specialization is associated with vertical chains of production, where upstream firms supply inputs for downstream firms who add value and sell to consumers. Moreover, firms at all levels have grown in scale and scope, and they now often serve many markets across a range of different jurisdictions. This geographic expansion is perhaps even more pronounced for upstream firms, because downstream firms, such as distributors and retailers, tend to be local or at least retain a well-defined local presence. To remain relevant and effective, tort rules and other legal structures need to account for the interactions among firms in a vertical chain of production. To some extent, tort law has successfully incorporated the reality of vertical production. In the 1800s, a doctrine called “privity” prevented individuals from suing upstream firms for injuries from products of downstream firms. Cases such as MacPherson v. Buick Motor Company (N.Y. 1916) and Smith v. Peerless Glass Co (N.Y. 1932) abandoned the doctrine of privity and allowed consumers to sue firms further upstream (Prosser, 1960). Indeed, contemporary products litigation is now characterized by suits against several firms in the vertical chain of production and has become quantitatively significant.1 Overall torts liability grew four times faster than the overall economic growth rate between 1930 and 1994 (Sturgis, 1995). By 2009, total payments in products liability suits alone amounted to $248.1 billion, or 1.74% of U.S. GDP (Towers Watson, 2010). In health care, suits against doctors amount to 1-2% of physician expenditures (Mello, Chandra, Gawande, & Studdert, 2010), and suits against drug companies amount to 2.26% of all drug expenditures.2 However, an important way in which tort law has lagged the modern economy is in the persistence of local, rather than national or global tort rules. States set tort rules, even though firms may produce for national and even global markets. This has encouraged beggar-thy-neighbor policies by states who may have incentives to shift liability from local downstream defendants to upstream national defendants lacking a local presence (Krauss, 2002). For instance, 22 states have reduced the products liability local retailers face but not the liability that upstream manufacturers face (Shepherd, 2012). Nearly 30 states have caps on total or non-economic damages that physicians face in medical 1 For example, plaintiffs sue both the manufacturer of the car whose tire burst and the manufacturer of the tire (e.g., In re Bridgestone/Firestone, Inc., S.D. Ind. 2003), the home builder that used contaminated materials and the maker of those materials (e.g., In re Chinese Manufactured Drywall Products, E.D. La. 2010), the grocer that used spoiled food and the company that supplied the grocer with the spoiled food (e.g., cases against retailers and farmers implicated in the 2006 E. coli outbreak), and the doctor that prescribed a drug as well as the company that produced it (e.g.,Wyeth v. Levine, U.S. 2009) This last example is also the topic of the empirical application in this paper. 2 This estimate is derived from all settlement special items reported in the income statement. For pharmaceutical companies this represents provisions to alter reserves for litigation and settlement. For other companies the amount would include insurance payments from the firms general liability policy but pharmaceutical firms do not typically have insurance against loses in litigation. As such the sum of the settlement special items represents unexpected payments in litigation. Although some of this litigation is likely not related to product liability the vast majority of loses in excess of reserves is likely major product liability cases—a fact reflected by disclosures in the 10k statements. We sum the total special reserves incurred from 2002-2008 and divide this by total sales over the same period to get the ratio of 2.26%.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
产品责任的意外后果:来自医药市场的证据*
在一个复杂的经济体中,生产是垂直的,并且跨越了管辖范围。商品通常由上游的国家或全球公司生产,并由下游的当地公司改进或分销。在这种情况下,提高产品责任可能会对产品销售和消费者安全产生意想不到的后果。传统观点认为,上游企业侵权责任的增加将导致该企业(弱地)增加安全或信息披露方面的投资。然而,这在现实世界中可能会失败,因为上游公司在许多司法管辖区经营,因此单一司法管辖区的行为可能不足以影响上游公司的行为。更糟糕的是,如果责任由上游和下游企业共同承担,较高的上游责任可能会机械地减少下游经销商的责任,并鼓励下游企业采取更鲁莽的行为。在这种情况下,较高的上游负债可能会相反地增加风险商品的销售。我们在医药市场的背景下证明了这一现象。我们表明,上游制药商较高的产品责任降低了下游医生面临的责任,他们通过开出比以前更多的药物来应对。Eric Helland Claremont McKenna学院经济系Claremont, CA 91711 eric.helland@claremontmckenna.edu Darius Lakdawalla schaeffa卫生政策和经济中心南加州大学3335 S. Figueroa St, la Unit A, CA 90089-7273和NBER dlakdawa@healthpolicy.usc.edu Anup Malani芝加哥大学法学院1111 E. 60 Street芝加哥,IL 60637和NBER amalani@uchicago.edu Seth A. Seabury Schaeffer健康政策和经济中心南加州大学3335 S. Figueroa St, Unit A Los Angeles, CA 90089-7273 seabury@usc.edu现代复杂经济的一个共同特征是跨越司法管辖区的垂直生产。技术发展和专业化与垂直生产链有关,上游公司为下游公司提供投入,下游公司增加价值并向消费者销售。此外,所有级别的公司在规模和范围上都有所增长,它们现在经常服务于一系列不同司法管辖区的许多市场。这种地理扩张对于上游公司来说可能更为明显,因为下游公司,如分销商和零售商,往往是本地的,或者至少保留了一个明确的本地存在。为了保持相关性和有效性,侵权规则和其他法律结构需要考虑到垂直生产链中公司之间的相互作用。侵权法在一定程度上成功地融入了垂直生产的现实。在19世纪,一种被称为“特权”的原则阻止个人起诉上游公司,因为下游公司的产品造成了伤害。麦克弗森诉别克汽车公司(1916年纽约州)和史密斯诉无双玻璃公司(1932年纽约州)等案例放弃了隐私原则,允许消费者起诉更上游的公司(普罗瑟,1960年)。事实上,当代产品诉讼现在的特点是对垂直生产链上的几家公司提起诉讼,并且在数量上已经变得重要在1930年至1994年间,总体侵权责任的增长速度比总体经济增长率快四倍(斯特吉斯,1995年)。到2009年,仅产品责任诉讼的支付总额就达到了2481亿美元,占美国GDP的1.74%(韬睿惠悦,2010)。在医疗保健领域,针对医生的诉讼占医生支出的1-2% (Mello, Chandra, Gawande, & Studdert, 2010),针对制药公司的诉讼占所有药品支出的2.26%然而,侵权法落后于现代经济的一个重要方面是地方性的侵权规则,而不是全国性或全球性的侵权规则。即使公司可能为国内甚至全球市场生产产品,各州也会制定侵权规则。这鼓励了各州采取以邻为壑的政策,这些国家可能有动机将责任从当地下游被告转移到缺乏当地存在的上游国家被告(Krauss, 2002)。例如,22个州减少了当地零售商面临的产品责任,但没有减少上游制造商面临的责任(Shepherd, 2012)。近30个州对医生在医疗事故中面临的总损失或非经济损失设置了上限。例如,原告既起诉轮胎爆裂的汽车制造商,也起诉轮胎制造商(例如,2003年,普利司通/凡士通公司),使用受污染材料的房屋建筑商和这些材料的制造商(例如,2010年,中国制造的石膏板产品,E.D. La)。使用变质食品的杂货商和向杂货商提供变质食品的公司(例如,2006年大肠杆菌爆发中涉及的零售商和农民的案件),开处方的医生以及生产该药物的公司(例如。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
2.20
自引率
0.00%
发文量
25
期刊最新文献
Organization of the State: Home Assignment and Bureaucrat Performance The Behavioral Effects of (Unenforceable) Contracts† Unintended Consequences of Products Liability: Evidence from the Pharmaceutical Market* Is a Corruption Crackdown Really Good for the Economy? Firm-Level Evidence from China Voter Turnout and City Performance: Evidence from Italian Municipalities
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1