首页 > 最新文献

Journal of Law Economics & Organization最新文献

英文 中文
Organization of the State: Home Assignment and Bureaucrat Performance 国家组织:家庭分配与官僚绩效
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-10-25 DOI: 10.1093/JLEO/EWAB022
Guo Xu, Marianne Bertrand, R. Burgess
How to allocate personnel is a central question in the organization of the state. We link survey data on the performance of 1,472 elite civil servants in India to their personnel records between 1975-2005 to study how home allocations affect their performance and careers. Using exogenous variation in home assignment generated by an allocation rule, we find that bureaucrats assigned to their home states are perceived to be less effective and more likely to be suspended. These negative effects are driven by states with higher levels of corruption and cohorts with greater numbers of home state officers. ∗First draft: December 2017. This paper has benefited from comments of seminar participants at the NBER Organizational Economics Meeting, the University of Houston, Northwestern Kellogg, Uppsala, Columbia GSB, Barcelona Graduate School of Economics Summer Forum, UC Berkeley, UC Davis, Chicago Harris, the BPP-GEM workshop, the Stanford Quality of Governance workshop and the ABCDE World Bank conference. We thank Oriana Bandiera, Tim Besley, Michael Callen, Arunish Chawla, Ernesto Dal Bo, Esther Duflo, Miguel Espinosa, Fred Finan, Olle Folke, Guido Friebel, Saad Gulzar, Rema Hanna, Julien Labonne, Anandi Mani, Jan Pierskalla, Andrea Prat, Johanne Rickne, John de Figueiredo, Daniel Rogger for their valuable comments. Finally, we particularly thank a group of senior IAS officers for sharing their institutional knowledge, and Lakshmi Iyer and Anandi Mani for sharing their data on empanelment outcomes. Fraser Clark, Anton Heil, Rebecca Rose, Jinling Yang and Jiemin Xu provided excellent research assistance. A previous version of this paper has been circulated under the title “Social Proximity and Bureaucrat Performance: Evidence from India.” All errors remain our own. †Guo Xu (corresponding author): guo.xu@berkeley.edu; Marianne Bertrand: marianne.bertrand@chicagobooth.edu; Robin Burgess: r.burgess@lse.ac.uk.
如何配置人员是国家组织中的一个中心问题。我们将1975年至2005年间印度1472名精英公务员的绩效调查数据与他们的个人记录联系起来,研究住房分配如何影响他们的绩效和职业生涯。利用分配规则产生的家乡分配的外生变化,我们发现,被分配到家乡的官僚被认为效率较低,更有可能被停职。这些负面影响是由腐败程度较高的州和本国官员人数较多的州造成的。*初稿:2017年12月。本文受益于NBER组织经济学会议、休斯顿大学、西北凯洛格大学、乌普萨拉大学、哥伦比亚大学商学院、巴塞罗那经济研究生院夏季论坛、加州大学伯克利分校、加州大学戴维斯分校、芝加哥哈里斯大学、BPP-GEM研讨会、斯坦福大学治理质量研讨会和ABCDE世界银行会议与会者的评论。我们感谢Oriana Bandiera、Tim Besley、Michael Callen、Arunish Chawla、Ernesto Dal Bo、Esther Duflo、Miguel Espinosa、Fred Finan、Olle Folke、Guido Friebel、Saad Gulzar、Rema Hanna、Julien Labonne、Anandi Mani、Jan Pierskalla、Andrea Prat、Johanne Rickne、John de Figueiredo、Daniel roger的宝贵意见。最后,我们特别感谢一组国际会计协会高级官员分享他们的机构知识,感谢Lakshmi Iyer和Anandi Mani分享他们关于聘用结果的数据。Fraser Clark, Anton Heil, Rebecca Rose, Jinling Yang和Jiemin Xu提供了出色的研究协助。这篇论文的前一个版本以“社会接近和官僚绩效:来自印度的证据”为题分发。所有的错误都是我们自己的。†郭旭(通讯作者):guo.xu@berkeley.edu;Marianne Bertrand: marianne.bertrand@chicagobooth.edu;罗宾·伯吉斯:r.burgess@lse.ac.uk。
{"title":"Organization of the State: Home Assignment and Bureaucrat Performance","authors":"Guo Xu, Marianne Bertrand, R. Burgess","doi":"10.1093/JLEO/EWAB022","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLEO/EWAB022","url":null,"abstract":"How to allocate personnel is a central question in the organization of the state. We link survey data on the performance of 1,472 elite civil servants in India to their personnel records between 1975-2005 to study how home allocations affect their performance and careers. Using exogenous variation in home assignment generated by an allocation rule, we find that bureaucrats assigned to their home states are perceived to be less effective and more likely to be suspended. These negative effects are driven by states with higher levels of corruption and cohorts with greater numbers of home state officers. ∗First draft: December 2017. This paper has benefited from comments of seminar participants at the NBER Organizational Economics Meeting, the University of Houston, Northwestern Kellogg, Uppsala, Columbia GSB, Barcelona Graduate School of Economics Summer Forum, UC Berkeley, UC Davis, Chicago Harris, the BPP-GEM workshop, the Stanford Quality of Governance workshop and the ABCDE World Bank conference. We thank Oriana Bandiera, Tim Besley, Michael Callen, Arunish Chawla, Ernesto Dal Bo, Esther Duflo, Miguel Espinosa, Fred Finan, Olle Folke, Guido Friebel, Saad Gulzar, Rema Hanna, Julien Labonne, Anandi Mani, Jan Pierskalla, Andrea Prat, Johanne Rickne, John de Figueiredo, Daniel Rogger for their valuable comments. Finally, we particularly thank a group of senior IAS officers for sharing their institutional knowledge, and Lakshmi Iyer and Anandi Mani for sharing their data on empanelment outcomes. Fraser Clark, Anton Heil, Rebecca Rose, Jinling Yang and Jiemin Xu provided excellent research assistance. A previous version of this paper has been circulated under the title “Social Proximity and Bureaucrat Performance: Evidence from India.” All errors remain our own. †Guo Xu (corresponding author): guo.xu@berkeley.edu; Marianne Bertrand: marianne.bertrand@chicagobooth.edu; Robin Burgess: r.burgess@lse.ac.uk.","PeriodicalId":47987,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Law Economics & Organization","volume":"208 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2021-10-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"79819916","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
The Behavioral Effects of (Unenforceable) Contracts† (不可执行的)合同的行为影响
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-04-11 DOI: 10.1093/JLEO/EWAA018
Evan Starr, J. Prescott, Norman D. Bishara
We study the relationship between employment noncompetition agreements and employee mobility patterns using novel data from the 2014 Noncompete Survey Project. Specifically, we examine how noncompetes relate to the duration and nature of employee mobility, and we leverage our detailed individual-level survey data to identify and explore the precise mechanisms underlying the relationships we observe. We find that individuals with noncompetes appear to exhibit materially longer tenures and are more likely to depart for new employers that do not “compete” with their prior employers. To account for these patterns, we investigate the role noncompetes may play at each stage of the mobility “process”: job search, employer recruitment, offer receipt, negotiation, offer acceptance, etc. We present evidence that employees bound by noncompetes substitute job search activity and receptivity to recruitment in the direction of noncompetitors and that noncompetes are a factor in the choice to turn down approximately 40 percent of the offers employees receive from competitors.
我们利用2014年竞业禁止调查项目的新数据研究了雇佣竞业禁止协议与员工流动模式之间的关系。具体来说,我们研究了竞业禁止与员工流动的持续时间和性质之间的关系,并利用我们详细的个人层面调查数据来识别和探索我们所观察到的关系背后的精确机制。我们发现,拥有竞业禁止的员工似乎表现出更长的任期,并且更有可能跳槽到不与前雇主“竞争”的新雇主。为了解释这些模式,我们研究了非竞争对手在流动“过程”的每个阶段可能发挥的作用:求职、雇主招聘、收到offer、谈判、接受offer等。我们提供的证据表明,受竞业禁止约束的员工会以非竞争对手的方式替代求职活动和对招聘的接受程度,并且竞业禁止是员工选择拒绝来自竞争对手的约40%的工作机会的一个因素。
{"title":"The Behavioral Effects of (Unenforceable) Contracts†","authors":"Evan Starr, J. Prescott, Norman D. Bishara","doi":"10.1093/JLEO/EWAA018","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLEO/EWAA018","url":null,"abstract":"We study the relationship between employment noncompetition agreements and employee mobility patterns using novel data from the 2014 Noncompete Survey Project. Specifically, we examine how noncompetes relate to the duration and nature of employee mobility, and we leverage our detailed individual-level survey data to identify and explore the precise mechanisms underlying the relationships we observe. We find that individuals with noncompetes appear to exhibit materially longer tenures and are more likely to depart for new employers that do not “compete” with their prior employers. To account for these patterns, we investigate the role noncompetes may play at each stage of the mobility “process”: job search, employer recruitment, offer receipt, negotiation, offer acceptance, etc. We present evidence that employees bound by noncompetes substitute job search activity and receptivity to recruitment in the direction of noncompetitors and that noncompetes are a factor in the choice to turn down approximately 40 percent of the offers employees receive from competitors.","PeriodicalId":47987,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Law Economics & Organization","volume":"1 1","pages":"633-687"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2021-04-11","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"72529002","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Unintended Consequences of Products Liability: Evidence from the Pharmaceutical Market* 产品责任的意外后果:来自医药市场的证据*
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-11-10 DOI: 10.1093/jleo/ewaa017
Eric A. Helland, D. Lakdawalla, A. Malani, S. Seabury
In a complex economy, production is vertical and crosses jurisdictional lines. Goods are often produced by an upstream national or global firm and improved or distributed by local firms downstream. In this context, heightened products liability may have unintended consequences on product sales and consumer safety. Conventional wisdom holds that an increase in tort liability on the upstream firm will cause that firm to (weakly) increase investment in safety or disclosure. However, this may fail in the real-world, where upstream firms operate in many jurisdictions, so that the actions of a single jurisdiction may not be significant enough to influence upstream firm behavior. Even worse, if liability is shared between upstream and downstream firms, higher upstream liability may mechanically decrease liability of the downstream distributor and encourage more reckless behavior by the downstream firm. In this manner, higher upstream liability may perversely increase the sales of a risky good. We demonstrate this phenomenon in the context of the pharmaceutical market. We show that higher products liability on upstream pharmaceutical manufacturers reduces the liability faced by downstream doctors, who respond by prescribing more drugs than before. Eric Helland Claremont McKenna College Department of Economics Claremont, CA 91711 eric.helland@claremontmckenna.edu Darius Lakdawalla Schaeffer Center for Health Policy and Economics University of Southern California 3335 S. Figueroa St, Unit A Los Angeles, CA 90089-7273 and NBER dlakdawa@healthpolicy.usc.edu Anup Malani University of Chicago Law School 1111 E. 60th Street Chicago, IL 60637 and NBER amalani@uchicago.edu Seth A. Seabury Schaeffer Center for Health Policy and Economics University of Southern California 3335 S. Figueroa St, Unit A Los Angeles, CA 90089-7273 seabury@usc.edu A common feature of modern, complex economies is vertical production that crosses jurisdictional lines. Technological development and specialization is associated with vertical chains of production, where upstream firms supply inputs for downstream firms who add value and sell to consumers. Moreover, firms at all levels have grown in scale and scope, and they now often serve many markets across a range of different jurisdictions. This geographic expansion is perhaps even more pronounced for upstream firms, because downstream firms, such as distributors and retailers, tend to be local or at least retain a well-defined local presence. To remain relevant and effective, tort rules and other legal structures need to account for the interactions among firms in a vertical chain of production. To some extent, tort law has successfully incorporated the reality of vertical production. In the 1800s, a doctrine called “privity” prevented individuals from suing upstream firms for injuries from products of downstream firms. Cases such as MacPherson v. Buick Motor Company (N.Y. 1916) and Smith v. Peerless Glass Co (N.Y. 1932) abandoned the do
在一个复杂的经济体中,生产是垂直的,并且跨越了管辖范围。商品通常由上游的国家或全球公司生产,并由下游的当地公司改进或分销。在这种情况下,提高产品责任可能会对产品销售和消费者安全产生意想不到的后果。传统观点认为,上游企业侵权责任的增加将导致该企业(弱地)增加安全或信息披露方面的投资。然而,这在现实世界中可能会失败,因为上游公司在许多司法管辖区经营,因此单一司法管辖区的行为可能不足以影响上游公司的行为。更糟糕的是,如果责任由上游和下游企业共同承担,较高的上游责任可能会机械地减少下游经销商的责任,并鼓励下游企业采取更鲁莽的行为。在这种情况下,较高的上游负债可能会相反地增加风险商品的销售。我们在医药市场的背景下证明了这一现象。我们表明,上游制药商较高的产品责任降低了下游医生面临的责任,他们通过开出比以前更多的药物来应对。Eric Helland Claremont McKenna学院经济系Claremont, CA 91711 eric.helland@claremontmckenna.edu Darius Lakdawalla schaeffa卫生政策和经济中心南加州大学3335 S. Figueroa St, la Unit A, CA 90089-7273和NBER dlakdawa@healthpolicy.usc.edu Anup Malani芝加哥大学法学院1111 E. 60 Street芝加哥,IL 60637和NBER amalani@uchicago.edu Seth A. Seabury Schaeffer健康政策和经济中心南加州大学3335 S. Figueroa St, Unit A Los Angeles, CA 90089-7273 seabury@usc.edu现代复杂经济的一个共同特征是跨越司法管辖区的垂直生产。技术发展和专业化与垂直生产链有关,上游公司为下游公司提供投入,下游公司增加价值并向消费者销售。此外,所有级别的公司在规模和范围上都有所增长,它们现在经常服务于一系列不同司法管辖区的许多市场。这种地理扩张对于上游公司来说可能更为明显,因为下游公司,如分销商和零售商,往往是本地的,或者至少保留了一个明确的本地存在。为了保持相关性和有效性,侵权规则和其他法律结构需要考虑到垂直生产链中公司之间的相互作用。侵权法在一定程度上成功地融入了垂直生产的现实。在19世纪,一种被称为“特权”的原则阻止个人起诉上游公司,因为下游公司的产品造成了伤害。麦克弗森诉别克汽车公司(1916年纽约州)和史密斯诉无双玻璃公司(1932年纽约州)等案例放弃了隐私原则,允许消费者起诉更上游的公司(普罗瑟,1960年)。事实上,当代产品诉讼现在的特点是对垂直生产链上的几家公司提起诉讼,并且在数量上已经变得重要在1930年至1994年间,总体侵权责任的增长速度比总体经济增长率快四倍(斯特吉斯,1995年)。到2009年,仅产品责任诉讼的支付总额就达到了2481亿美元,占美国GDP的1.74%(韬睿惠悦,2010)。在医疗保健领域,针对医生的诉讼占医生支出的1-2% (Mello, Chandra, Gawande, & Studdert, 2010),针对制药公司的诉讼占所有药品支出的2.26%然而,侵权法落后于现代经济的一个重要方面是地方性的侵权规则,而不是全国性或全球性的侵权规则。即使公司可能为国内甚至全球市场生产产品,各州也会制定侵权规则。这鼓励了各州采取以邻为壑的政策,这些国家可能有动机将责任从当地下游被告转移到缺乏当地存在的上游国家被告(Krauss, 2002)。例如,22个州减少了当地零售商面临的产品责任,但没有减少上游制造商面临的责任(Shepherd, 2012)。近30个州对医生在医疗事故中面临的总损失或非经济损失设置了上限。例如,原告既起诉轮胎爆裂的汽车制造商,也起诉轮胎制造商(例如,2003年,普利司通/凡士通公司),使用受污染材料的房屋建筑商和这些材料的制造商(例如,2010年,中国制造的石膏板产品,E.D. La)。使用变质食品的杂货商和向杂货商提供变质食品的公司(例如,2006年大肠杆菌爆发中涉及的零售商和农民的案件),开处方的医生以及生产该药物的公司(例如。
{"title":"Unintended Consequences of Products Liability: Evidence from the Pharmaceutical Market*","authors":"Eric A. Helland, D. Lakdawalla, A. Malani, S. Seabury","doi":"10.1093/jleo/ewaa017","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewaa017","url":null,"abstract":"In a complex economy, production is vertical and crosses jurisdictional lines. Goods are often produced by an upstream national or global firm and improved or distributed by local firms downstream. In this context, heightened products liability may have unintended consequences on product sales and consumer safety. Conventional wisdom holds that an increase in tort liability on the upstream firm will cause that firm to (weakly) increase investment in safety or disclosure. However, this may fail in the real-world, where upstream firms operate in many jurisdictions, so that the actions of a single jurisdiction may not be significant enough to influence upstream firm behavior. Even worse, if liability is shared between upstream and downstream firms, higher upstream liability may mechanically decrease liability of the downstream distributor and encourage more reckless behavior by the downstream firm. In this manner, higher upstream liability may perversely increase the sales of a risky good. We demonstrate this phenomenon in the context of the pharmaceutical market. We show that higher products liability on upstream pharmaceutical manufacturers reduces the liability faced by downstream doctors, who respond by prescribing more drugs than before. Eric Helland Claremont McKenna College Department of Economics Claremont, CA 91711 eric.helland@claremontmckenna.edu Darius Lakdawalla Schaeffer Center for Health Policy and Economics University of Southern California 3335 S. Figueroa St, Unit A Los Angeles, CA 90089-7273 and NBER dlakdawa@healthpolicy.usc.edu Anup Malani University of Chicago Law School 1111 E. 60th Street Chicago, IL 60637 and NBER amalani@uchicago.edu Seth A. Seabury Schaeffer Center for Health Policy and Economics University of Southern California 3335 S. Figueroa St, Unit A Los Angeles, CA 90089-7273 seabury@usc.edu A common feature of modern, complex economies is vertical production that crosses jurisdictional lines. Technological development and specialization is associated with vertical chains of production, where upstream firms supply inputs for downstream firms who add value and sell to consumers. Moreover, firms at all levels have grown in scale and scope, and they now often serve many markets across a range of different jurisdictions. This geographic expansion is perhaps even more pronounced for upstream firms, because downstream firms, such as distributors and retailers, tend to be local or at least retain a well-defined local presence. To remain relevant and effective, tort rules and other legal structures need to account for the interactions among firms in a vertical chain of production. To some extent, tort law has successfully incorporated the reality of vertical production. In the 1800s, a doctrine called “privity” prevented individuals from suing upstream firms for injuries from products of downstream firms. Cases such as MacPherson v. Buick Motor Company (N.Y. 1916) and Smith v. Peerless Glass Co (N.Y. 1932) abandoned the do","PeriodicalId":47987,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Law Economics & Organization","volume":"21 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2020-11-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"83070957","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Voter Turnout and City Performance: Evidence from Italian Municipalities 选民投票率和城市绩效:来自意大利市政当局的证据
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-09-10 DOI: 10.1093/jleo/ewaa012
A. Prete, F. Revelli
Using data on mayoral elections in large Italian cities during the 2000s, we investigate whether and how voter turnout affects city performance across a number of dimensions. To address the issue of voter turnout endogeneity and identify the transmission mechanism, we exploit exogenous variation in participation rates in mayoral elections due to anticipated shocks (concurrence of local and national elections) and unanticipated shocks (bad weather on the day of the election) to the cost of voting. The results consistently point to a negative impact of voter turnout rates on indicators of urban environmental performance, life quality, and administrative efficiency. Interestingly, though, we find that only anticipated shocks to turnout affect the quality of elected mayors measured on a number of competence dimensions, compatibly with the hypothesis of a selection mechanism whereby parties choose candidates to maximize their chances of winning the elections based on their expectations on voter turnout rates (JEL D72, H72, C26).
利用2000年代意大利大城市市长选举的数据,我们从多个维度调查选民投票率是否以及如何影响城市绩效。为了解决选民投票率内生性问题并确定传导机制,我们利用了由于预期冲击(地方和全国选举同时进行)和意外冲击(选举当天的恶劣天气)对投票成本造成的市长选举参与率的外生变化。结果一致表明,选民投票率对城市环境绩效、生活质量和行政效率等指标产生负面影响。然而,有趣的是,我们发现只有对投票率的预期冲击才会影响当选市长的素质,这与一种选择机制的假设是一致的,即政党根据对选民投票率的预期来选择候选人,以最大化他们赢得选举的机会(JEL D72, H72, C26)。
{"title":"Voter Turnout and City Performance: Evidence from Italian Municipalities","authors":"A. Prete, F. Revelli","doi":"10.1093/jleo/ewaa012","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewaa012","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000 Using data on mayoral elections in large Italian cities during the 2000s, we investigate whether and how voter turnout affects city performance across a number of dimensions. To address the issue of voter turnout endogeneity and identify the transmission mechanism, we exploit exogenous variation in participation rates in mayoral elections due to anticipated shocks (concurrence of local and national elections) and unanticipated shocks (bad weather on the day of the election) to the cost of voting. The results consistently point to a negative impact of voter turnout rates on indicators of urban environmental performance, life quality, and administrative efficiency. Interestingly, though, we find that only anticipated shocks to turnout affect the quality of elected mayors measured on a number of competence dimensions, compatibly with the hypothesis of a selection mechanism whereby parties choose candidates to maximize their chances of winning the elections based on their expectations on voter turnout rates (JEL D72, H72, C26).","PeriodicalId":47987,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Law Economics & Organization","volume":"49 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2020-09-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"91298665","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Is a Corruption Crackdown Really Good for the Economy? Firm-Level Evidence from China 反腐对经济真的有好处吗?来自中国的企业层面证据
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-09-10 DOI: 10.1093/jleo/ewaa014
Zhiyuan Chen, Xin Jin, Xu Xu
We study the impact of anticorruption efforts on firm performance, exploiting an unanticipated corruption crackdown in China’s Heilongjiang province in 2004. We compare firms in the affected regions with those in other inland regions before and after the crackdown. Our main finding is an overall negative impact of the crackdown on firm productivity and entry rates. Furthermore, these negative impacts are mainly experienced by private and foreign firms, while state-owned firms are mostly unaffected. We present evidence concerning two potential explanations for our findings. First, the corruption crackdown may have limited bribery opportunities that helped private firms operate. Second, the corruption crackdown may have interfered with personal connections between private firms and government officials to a greater extent than institutional connections between state-owned firms and the government. Overall, our findings suggest that corruption crackdowns may not restore efficiency in the economy, but instead lead to worse economic outcomes, at least in the short run (JEL L2, M1, O1).
本文以2004年中国黑龙江省出人意料的反腐行动为例,研究了反腐败努力对企业绩效的影响。我们将受影响地区的公司与其他内陆地区的公司在打击行动前后进行了比较。我们的主要发现是打击对企业生产率和进入率的总体负面影响。此外,这些负面影响主要是由私营和外国公司经历的,而国有公司大多不受影响。我们为我们的发现提供了两种可能的解释证据。首先,打击腐败可能限制了帮助私营公司运营的贿赂机会。其次,打击腐败可能在更大程度上干扰了私营企业与政府官员之间的个人关系,而不是国有企业与政府之间的机构关系。总体而言,我们的研究结果表明,打击腐败可能不会恢复经济效率,反而会导致更糟糕的经济结果,至少在短期内是这样(JEL L2, M1, 01)。
{"title":"Is a Corruption Crackdown Really Good for the Economy? Firm-Level Evidence from China","authors":"Zhiyuan Chen, Xin Jin, Xu Xu","doi":"10.1093/jleo/ewaa014","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewaa014","url":null,"abstract":"We study the impact of anticorruption efforts on firm performance, exploiting an unanticipated corruption crackdown in China’s Heilongjiang province in 2004. We compare firms in the affected regions with those in other inland regions before and after the crackdown. Our main finding is an overall negative impact of the crackdown on firm productivity and entry rates. Furthermore, these negative impacts are mainly experienced by private and foreign firms, while state-owned firms are mostly unaffected. We present evidence concerning two potential explanations for our findings. First, the corruption crackdown may have limited bribery opportunities that helped private firms operate. Second, the corruption crackdown may have interfered with personal connections between private firms and government officials to a greater extent than institutional connections between state-owned firms and the government. Overall, our findings suggest that corruption crackdowns may not restore efficiency in the economy, but instead lead to worse economic outcomes, at least in the short run (JEL L2, M1, O1).","PeriodicalId":47987,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Law Economics & Organization","volume":"37 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2020-09-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"85629401","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 10
Product Safety and Harm-Mitigation Incentives When Mitigation Lowers Consumption Benefits 当危害减轻降低消费效益时,产品安全和危害减轻激励
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-09-03 DOI: 10.1093/jleo/ewaa011
F. Baumann, Tim Friehe
To reduce the expected harm its product causes to consumers, a firm can invest in a product’s safety before sale or mitigate harm after sale in the event product risks materialize. After-sale harm mitigation interferes with consumers’ product use and reduces consumption benefits. We describe a firm’s incentives for safety investments and harm mitigation as a function of the level of the firm’s liability. Whereas post-sale mitigation incentives are scaled up by liability, pre-sale product safety is a U-shaped function of liability, making the two harm reduction instruments substitutes at low levels of liability and complements at high levels. To induce efficient harm mitigation, liability must be less than full. Further reducing the level of liability improves product safety at the cost of the firm’s profits. (JEL K13, D42).
为了减少其产品对消费者造成的预期伤害,企业可以在销售前投资于产品的安全性,或者在产品风险成为现实的情况下减轻销售后的伤害。售后减害干扰了消费者的产品使用,降低了消费者的消费效益。我们将企业对安全投资和减轻损害的激励描述为企业负债水平的函数。虽然售后缓解激励措施因责任而扩大,但售前产品安全是责任的u型函数,使两种减少危害工具在低责任水平上互为替代,在高责任水平上互为补充。为了有效地减轻损害,责任必须少于全部。进一步降低责任水平以公司利润为代价提高了产品安全。(凝胶k13, d42)。
{"title":"Product Safety and Harm-Mitigation Incentives When Mitigation Lowers Consumption Benefits","authors":"F. Baumann, Tim Friehe","doi":"10.1093/jleo/ewaa011","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewaa011","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000 To reduce the expected harm its product causes to consumers, a firm can invest in a product’s safety before sale or mitigate harm after sale in the event product risks materialize. After-sale harm mitigation interferes with consumers’ product use and reduces consumption benefits. We describe a firm’s incentives for safety investments and harm mitigation as a function of the level of the firm’s liability. Whereas post-sale mitigation incentives are scaled up by liability, pre-sale product safety is a U-shaped function of liability, making the two harm reduction instruments substitutes at low levels of liability and complements at high levels. To induce efficient harm mitigation, liability must be less than full. Further reducing the level of liability improves product safety at the cost of the firm’s profits. (JEL K13, D42).","PeriodicalId":47987,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Law Economics & Organization","volume":"11 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2020-09-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"74214916","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Risk Preferences and Incentives for Evidence Acquisition and Disclosure 证据获取和披露的风险偏好和激励
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-07-01 DOI: 10.1093/jleo/ewaa002
Erin C. Giffin, E. Lillethun
Civil disputes feature parties with biased incentives acquiring evidence with costly effort. Evidence may then be revealed at trial or concealed to persuade a judge or jury. Using a persuasion game, we examine how a litigant’s risk preferences influence evidence acquisition incentives. We find that high risk aversion depresses equilibrium evidence acquisition. We then study the problem of designing legal rules to balance good decision making against the costs of acquisition. We characterize the optimal design, which differs from equilibrium decision rules. Notably, for very risk-averse litigants, the design is “over-incentivized” with stronger rewards and punishments than in equilibrium. We find similar results for various common legal rules, including admissibility of evidence and maximum awards. These results have implications for how rules could differentiate between high risk aversion types (e.g., individuals) and low risk aversion types (e.g., corporations) to improve evidence acquisition efficiency.
民事纠纷的特点是,动机偏颇的当事人花费巨大的努力来获取证据。然后,证据可以在审判中披露或隐藏,以说服法官或陪审团。使用说服游戏,我们研究了诉讼当事人的风险偏好如何影响证据获取激励。我们发现,高风险厌恶抑制了均衡证据的获取。然后,我们研究设计法律规则的问题,以平衡良好的决策和收购成本。我们描述了不同于均衡决策规则的最优设计。值得注意的是,对于非常厌恶风险的诉讼当事人来说,这种设计是“过度激励”的,比均衡状态下的奖惩更强。我们发现,在包括证据的可采性和最高赔偿额在内的各种常见法律规则中,也有类似的结果。这些结果对规则如何区分高风险厌恶类型(如个人)和低风险厌恶类型(如公司)以提高证据获取效率具有启示意义。
{"title":"Risk Preferences and Incentives for Evidence Acquisition and Disclosure","authors":"Erin C. Giffin, E. Lillethun","doi":"10.1093/jleo/ewaa002","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewaa002","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000 Civil disputes feature parties with biased incentives acquiring evidence with costly effort. Evidence may then be revealed at trial or concealed to persuade a judge or jury. Using a persuasion game, we examine how a litigant’s risk preferences influence evidence acquisition incentives. We find that high risk aversion depresses equilibrium evidence acquisition. We then study the problem of designing legal rules to balance good decision making against the costs of acquisition. We characterize the optimal design, which differs from equilibrium decision rules. Notably, for very risk-averse litigants, the design is “over-incentivized” with stronger rewards and punishments than in equilibrium. We find similar results for various common legal rules, including admissibility of evidence and maximum awards. These results have implications for how rules could differentiate between high risk aversion types (e.g., individuals) and low risk aversion types (e.g., corporations) to improve evidence acquisition efficiency.","PeriodicalId":47987,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Law Economics & Organization","volume":"14 1","pages":"314-342"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2020-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"74466678","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Reducing Unjust Convictions: Plea Bargaining, Trial, and Evidence Disclosure 减少不公正的定罪:辩诉交易、审判和证据披露
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-07-01 DOI: 10.1093/jleo/ewaa001
A. Daughety, Jennifer F. Reinganum
We develop a dynamic model of a criminal case, from arrest through plea bargaining and (possibly) trial, allowing for the potential discovery of exculpatory evidence by prosecutors (who choose whether to disclose it) and defendants. We consider three regimes: (1) no disclosure required; (2) disclosure only required before trial; and (3) early disclosure required from arrest onward. These regimes have complex distributional consequences for the defendants. We find that innocent defendants ex ante prefer early disclosure whereas guilty defendants prefer disclosure only before trial. We also explore some of the social costs attributable to the regimes (JEL K4, D82, D73).
我们开发了一个刑事案件的动态模型,从逮捕到辩诉交易和(可能的)审判,允许检察官(选择是否披露)和被告可能发现无罪证据。我们考虑了三种制度:(1)不需要披露;(2)审判前需披露的;(3)从逮捕开始就需要尽早披露。这些制度对被告有着复杂的分配后果。我们发现,无罪的被告倾向于提前披露,而有罪的被告则倾向于在审判前披露。我们还探讨了一些可归因于这些制度的社会成本(JEL K4, D82, D73)。
{"title":"Reducing Unjust Convictions: Plea Bargaining, Trial, and Evidence Disclosure","authors":"A. Daughety, Jennifer F. Reinganum","doi":"10.1093/jleo/ewaa001","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewaa001","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000 We develop a dynamic model of a criminal case, from arrest through plea bargaining and (possibly) trial, allowing for the potential discovery of exculpatory evidence by prosecutors (who choose whether to disclose it) and defendants. We consider three regimes: (1) no disclosure required; (2) disclosure only required before trial; and (3) early disclosure required from arrest onward. These regimes have complex distributional consequences for the defendants. We find that innocent defendants ex ante prefer early disclosure whereas guilty defendants prefer disclosure only before trial. We also explore some of the social costs attributable to the regimes (JEL K4, D82, D73).","PeriodicalId":47987,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Law Economics & Organization","volume":"13 1","pages":"378-414"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2020-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"87322312","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Conservation Agreements: Relational Contracts with Endogenous Monitoring 保护协议:具有内生性监控的关系契约
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-06-27 DOI: 10.1093/jleo/ewaa006
Heidi Gjertsen, Theodore Groves, David A. Miller, E. Niesten, D. Squires, Joel Watson
Author(s): Gjertsen, Heidi; Groves, Theodore; Miller, David A; Niesten, Eduard; Squires, Dale; Watson, Joel | Abstract: Abstract This article examines the structure and performance of conservation agreements, which are relational contracts used across the world to protect natural resources. Key elements of these agreements are (1) they are ongoing arrangements between a local community and an outside party, typically a nongovernmental organization (NGO); (2) they feature payments in exchange for conservation services; (3) the prospects for success depend on the NGO engaging in costly monitoring to detect whether the community is foregoing short-term gains to protect the resource; (4) lacking a strong external enforcement system, they rely on self-enforcement; and (5) the parties have the opportunity to renegotiate at any time. A repeated-game model is developed and utilized to organize an evaluation of real conservation agreements, using three case studies as representative examples. (JEL D74, D86, Q20, Q56)
作者:Gjertsen, Heidi;林,西奥多·;大卫·米勒;Niesten,爱德华·;Squires,戴尔;摘要:本文考察了保护协议的结构和绩效,保护协议是世界范围内用于保护自然资源的关系契约。这些协议的关键要素是:(1)它们是当地社区与外部各方(通常是非政府组织)之间的持续安排;(2)以支付保护服务作为交换;(3)成功的前景取决于非政府组织进行昂贵的监测,以检测社区是否为了保护资源而放弃短期利益;(4)缺乏强有力的外部执行机制,依靠自我执行;(5)双方有随时重新协商的机会。建立了一个重复博弈模型,并利用该模型对实际保护协议进行了评估,以三个案例研究为代表。(jel d74, d86, q20, q56)
{"title":"Conservation Agreements: Relational Contracts with Endogenous Monitoring","authors":"Heidi Gjertsen, Theodore Groves, David A. Miller, E. Niesten, D. Squires, Joel Watson","doi":"10.1093/jleo/ewaa006","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewaa006","url":null,"abstract":"Author(s): Gjertsen, Heidi; Groves, Theodore; Miller, David A; Niesten, Eduard; Squires, Dale; Watson, Joel | Abstract: Abstract This article examines the structure and performance of conservation agreements, which are relational contracts used across the world to protect natural resources. Key elements of these agreements are (1) they are ongoing arrangements between a local community and an outside party, typically a nongovernmental organization (NGO); (2) they feature payments in exchange for conservation services; (3) the prospects for success depend on the NGO engaging in costly monitoring to detect whether the community is foregoing short-term gains to protect the resource; (4) lacking a strong external enforcement system, they rely on self-enforcement; and (5) the parties have the opportunity to renegotiate at any time. A repeated-game model is developed and utilized to organize an evaluation of real conservation agreements, using three case studies as representative examples. (JEL D74, D86, Q20, Q56)","PeriodicalId":47987,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Law Economics & Organization","volume":"183 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2020-06-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"81582171","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Worker Trust in Management and Delegation in Organizations 员工对管理层的信任与组织中的授权
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-06-13 DOI: 10.1093/jleo/ewaa008
Kieron J. Meagher, A. Wait
Using a unique employee–establishment survey, we find a causal relationship between an individual employee’s trust of management and their decision-making rights (delegation). We utilize both fixed effects (FE) and instrumental variables to control for unobserved factors: establishment-level FE control for management quality, practices, culture, and other characteristics; our instruments of inherited trust in management, and trust of equivalent workers in a different but similar country address the possible endogeneity of employee trust. Across all specifications, we find that delegation to a worker is more likely if that employee trusts management. In our preferred model, which includes establishment FE and accounts for endogeneity, we find a 1 standard deviation (SD) increase in employee trust increases delegation by approximately 0.6 of 1 SD. Our results are robust to the inclusion of worker preferences for individualism (which favors delegation), incentives/bonuses, and alternative measures of decision authority. (JEL D23, L22, L23).
通过一项独特的员工建立调查,我们发现个体员工对管理层的信任与他们的决策权(授权)之间存在因果关系。我们利用固定效应(FE)和工具变量来控制未观察到的因素:建立水平的FE控制管理质量,实践,文化和其他特征;我们的工具继承了对管理的信任,以及对不同但相似国家的同等工人的信任,解决了员工信任的可能内生性。在所有规范中,我们发现,如果员工信任管理层,则更有可能将委托给员工。在我们的首选模型中,包括建立FE和内生性,我们发现员工信任每增加1个标准差(SD),授权就会增加约0.6个标准差。我们的结果是稳健的,包括工人对个人主义的偏好(倾向于授权),激励/奖金,以及决策权的替代措施。(jel d23, 22, 23)。
{"title":"Worker Trust in Management and Delegation in Organizations","authors":"Kieron J. Meagher, A. Wait","doi":"10.1093/jleo/ewaa008","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewaa008","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000 Using a unique employee–establishment survey, we find a causal relationship between an individual employee’s trust of management and their decision-making rights (delegation). We utilize both fixed effects (FE) and instrumental variables to control for unobserved factors: establishment-level FE control for management quality, practices, culture, and other characteristics; our instruments of inherited trust in management, and trust of equivalent workers in a different but similar country address the possible endogeneity of employee trust. Across all specifications, we find that delegation to a worker is more likely if that employee trusts management. In our preferred model, which includes establishment FE and accounts for endogeneity, we find a 1 standard deviation (SD) increase in employee trust increases delegation by approximately 0.6 of 1 SD. Our results are robust to the inclusion of worker preferences for individualism (which favors delegation), incentives/bonuses, and alternative measures of decision authority. (JEL D23, L22, L23).","PeriodicalId":47987,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Law Economics & Organization","volume":"4 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2020-06-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"82451762","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
期刊
Journal of Law Economics & Organization
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1