学习型社会的动态能力——以台湾控制新冠肺炎疫情为例

Chan‐Yuan Wong
{"title":"学习型社会的动态能力——以台湾控制新冠肺炎疫情为例","authors":"Chan‐Yuan Wong","doi":"10.1080/18752160.2022.2069951","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"The development literature in the 1990s highlighted the role of business elites and the government in an endowed embedded autonomy for economic wealth generation that is coevolved with societal welfare (Evans, 1995), in turn leading to desired socioeconomic development. The observations in Breznitz (2007) and Amsden et al. (2012) imply the significance of upgrading allies of elites in an economy, and how the derived institution leads to productive outcomes—as opposed to a predatory state, which enables capture by elites and portends a regressive governing outcome. Elites are professionally trained and selected—thus, it is desirable to have them guard the established institution, as it is perceived that they do this selflessly unlike the “masses”. The national solidarity of ruling elites in governing affairs (e.g. socioeconomic, health, security, commerce, etc.) is not uncommon in many countries. In recent years, there has been a wave of realization countering the view on the supremacy of elites and the need to form an army of superordinates to develop an economy (e.g. Major and Machin 2018; Markovits 2019). The pursuit of upgrading by elites may lead to industrial growth—but what also follows are income inequality and discontent between classes (in a country) and between economies. Many (Barr 2016; Pleyers 2020; Tan 2012) began to realize that decisions made by the elites/technocrats which are supposed to bewell thought out and rationally calculated could—on some occasions—lead tomediocre (unimpressive) results or even disastrous outcomes. Taiwan—once recognized as a Tiger economy (Mathews and Cho 2000: 157– 202)—had its success attributed by many to the superordinate workforce that","PeriodicalId":45255,"journal":{"name":"East Asian Science Technology and Society-An International Journal","volume":"2 1","pages":"230 - 236"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7000,"publicationDate":"2022-04-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"1","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Dynamic Capabilities in a Learning Society—The Case of Taiwan in Controlling the Coronavirus Outbreak\",\"authors\":\"Chan‐Yuan Wong\",\"doi\":\"10.1080/18752160.2022.2069951\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"The development literature in the 1990s highlighted the role of business elites and the government in an endowed embedded autonomy for economic wealth generation that is coevolved with societal welfare (Evans, 1995), in turn leading to desired socioeconomic development. The observations in Breznitz (2007) and Amsden et al. (2012) imply the significance of upgrading allies of elites in an economy, and how the derived institution leads to productive outcomes—as opposed to a predatory state, which enables capture by elites and portends a regressive governing outcome. Elites are professionally trained and selected—thus, it is desirable to have them guard the established institution, as it is perceived that they do this selflessly unlike the “masses”. The national solidarity of ruling elites in governing affairs (e.g. socioeconomic, health, security, commerce, etc.) is not uncommon in many countries. In recent years, there has been a wave of realization countering the view on the supremacy of elites and the need to form an army of superordinates to develop an economy (e.g. Major and Machin 2018; Markovits 2019). The pursuit of upgrading by elites may lead to industrial growth—but what also follows are income inequality and discontent between classes (in a country) and between economies. Many (Barr 2016; Pleyers 2020; Tan 2012) began to realize that decisions made by the elites/technocrats which are supposed to bewell thought out and rationally calculated could—on some occasions—lead tomediocre (unimpressive) results or even disastrous outcomes. Taiwan—once recognized as a Tiger economy (Mathews and Cho 2000: 157– 202)—had its success attributed by many to the superordinate workforce that\",\"PeriodicalId\":45255,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"East Asian Science Technology and Society-An International Journal\",\"volume\":\"2 1\",\"pages\":\"230 - 236\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.7000,\"publicationDate\":\"2022-04-03\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"1\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"East Asian Science Technology and Society-An International Journal\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"90\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.1080/18752160.2022.2069951\",\"RegionNum\":4,\"RegionCategory\":\"社会学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q2\",\"JCRName\":\"AREA STUDIES\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"East Asian Science Technology and Society-An International Journal","FirstCategoryId":"90","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/18752160.2022.2069951","RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"AREA STUDIES","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

摘要

20世纪90年代的发展文献强调了商业精英和政府在与社会福利共同进化的经济财富创造中被赋予的嵌入式自治中的作用(Evans, 1995),进而导致理想的社会经济发展。Breznitz(2007)和Amsden等人(2012)的观察暗示了提升经济中精英盟友的重要性,以及衍生制度如何导致生产性结果,而不是掠夺性国家,后者使精英能够捕获并预示着一种倒退的治理结果。精英是经过专业训练和选拔的——因此,让他们保卫既定制度是可取的,因为他们被认为是无私的,不像“大众”。统治精英在管理事务(如社会经济、卫生、安全、商业等)方面的全国团结在许多国家并不罕见。近年来,出现了一波反对精英至上和需要组建一支上级军队来发展经济的观点的认识浪潮(例如,Major and Machin 2018;马可维兹2019)。精英阶层对升级的追求可能会导致工业增长,但随之而来的是收入不平等和(在一个国家)阶级之间以及经济之间的不满。许多(Barr 2016;Pleyers 2020;谭(2012)开始意识到,由精英/技术官僚做出的决策,应该是经过深思熟虑和理性计算的,在某些情况下,可能会导致平庸(不起眼)的结果,甚至是灾难性的结果。台湾——曾经被认为是经济之虎(Mathews and Cho 2000: 157 - 202)——它的成功被许多人归因于优秀的劳动力
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
Dynamic Capabilities in a Learning Society—The Case of Taiwan in Controlling the Coronavirus Outbreak
The development literature in the 1990s highlighted the role of business elites and the government in an endowed embedded autonomy for economic wealth generation that is coevolved with societal welfare (Evans, 1995), in turn leading to desired socioeconomic development. The observations in Breznitz (2007) and Amsden et al. (2012) imply the significance of upgrading allies of elites in an economy, and how the derived institution leads to productive outcomes—as opposed to a predatory state, which enables capture by elites and portends a regressive governing outcome. Elites are professionally trained and selected—thus, it is desirable to have them guard the established institution, as it is perceived that they do this selflessly unlike the “masses”. The national solidarity of ruling elites in governing affairs (e.g. socioeconomic, health, security, commerce, etc.) is not uncommon in many countries. In recent years, there has been a wave of realization countering the view on the supremacy of elites and the need to form an army of superordinates to develop an economy (e.g. Major and Machin 2018; Markovits 2019). The pursuit of upgrading by elites may lead to industrial growth—but what also follows are income inequality and discontent between classes (in a country) and between economies. Many (Barr 2016; Pleyers 2020; Tan 2012) began to realize that decisions made by the elites/technocrats which are supposed to bewell thought out and rationally calculated could—on some occasions—lead tomediocre (unimpressive) results or even disastrous outcomes. Taiwan—once recognized as a Tiger economy (Mathews and Cho 2000: 157– 202)—had its success attributed by many to the superordinate workforce that
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
1.60
自引率
12.50%
发文量
44
期刊最新文献
More Than Just Cultural Nationalism: A History of Traditional Chinese Medicine in China’s Manned Space Program Memes of Care: Good Morning Images and Digital Care among Older People in Taiwan Cranes, Cultivating a New Knowledge Practice in Late-Chosŏn Korea: Knowledge Transformations Connected by Things EUMENOL—Merck’s Patent Emmenagogue and its Chinese Connections (1896–1961) Can Coding Education Go Completely Online? Time, Work, and Relationship in Online Courses
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1