Introduction: Think Tanks in Austria, Switzerland and Germany - A Recalibration of Corporatist Policy Making?

Sven Jochem, A. Vatter
{"title":"Introduction: Think Tanks in Austria, Switzerland and Germany - A Recalibration of Corporatist Policy Making?","authors":"Sven Jochem, A. Vatter","doi":"10.7892/BORIS.37430","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"The German-speaking countries share a multitude of commonalities which separate Germany, Austria and Switzerland from other developed democracies. One prominent commonality of the German-speaking \"family of nations\" (Castles 1993, 2004; cf. Armingeon/Freitag 1997) is the broad integration of interest organizations into the process of policy deliberation, policy decision-making and policy implementation (Katzenstein 1987). The dominant role of interest organizations in public policy making is, however, not mirrored in standard attempts to measure the integration of interest-groups or, as it is called, neo-corporatism. While Austria ranks very high in most of the various empirical investigations (cf. Lehmbruch 1984, Siaroff 1999, Traxler/Blaschke/Kittel 2001), Germany usually is positioned in the middle of the range. Switzerland ranks low in most cases or is perceived as representing a very specific form of corporatism. As Isabelle Steffen and Wolf Linder (in this volume) argue, core institutional features classically associated with corporatism, such as strong trade unions or centralized wage bargaining patterns, are missing in Switzerland. Nevertheless, there are some \"functional structures equivalent to neo-corporatist arrangements\" (Kriesi 1995: p. 342), such as the institutionalized consultation procedure in policy deliberations (\"Vernehmlassung\"), which together with other institutional arrangements fosters and stabilizes the crucial influence of interest groups on policy decisions in Switzerland. The same might be argued for Germany. In contrast to Nordic-style corporatism, German wage bargaining was never centralized, nor did powerful, centralized peak associations of labor and capital dominate German politics after World War II. Nevertheless, interest groups and especially those from capital and labor are deeply involved into public policy-making patterns, either through parliamentary commissions or through their powerful position in agencies that implement welfare policies in Germany. Furthermore, self steering of interest groups in several sectors of the German welfare state is a prominent feature of the German Model, such as in wage bargaining or vocational training, to mention only the most important examples (cf. Czada 2003, Siegel 2003, Streeck 1997, Thelen 2004). This meso-corporatist interest mediation is furthermore segmented between different policy fields, and as a consequence, different logics of interest mediation rule at the same time the development of the German democracy (Dohler/Manow 1997). The clearest example of classical corporatism in the German-speaking family of nations is Austria. As Karlhofer (this volume) summarizes, the Austrian case is a prominent example of institutional corporatism because of centralized wage bargaining patterns and, especially, the extensive chamber system. These chambers have quasi-public functions and channel the interest of associated interest groups directly into policy deliberations and policy decisions. At the same time, these chambers have far reaching competences, covering broad areas of the welfare state as well as economic policy making. This leads Karlhofer to conclude that Austria may indeed be called a \"Kammerstaat\" (state of chambers). Hence, the role of interest organization in public policy-making is an important feature in the democracies of Germany, Austria and Switzerland. Since the early 1980s, however, the traditions and institutions of corporatist interest mediation were challenged by several developments. Firstly, \"old\" interest groups from capital and labor had to face organizational problems. While German unification might be interpreted as a specific challenge to German trade unions and employers' associations to organize their own camps (Schroeder 2000), in all three countries membership figures and density rates stagnated or revealed a shrinking capability of the respective organizations to attract the rank-and-file. …","PeriodicalId":447682,"journal":{"name":"German policy studies","volume":"46 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2006-06-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"8","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"German policy studies","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.7892/BORIS.37430","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 8

Abstract

The German-speaking countries share a multitude of commonalities which separate Germany, Austria and Switzerland from other developed democracies. One prominent commonality of the German-speaking "family of nations" (Castles 1993, 2004; cf. Armingeon/Freitag 1997) is the broad integration of interest organizations into the process of policy deliberation, policy decision-making and policy implementation (Katzenstein 1987). The dominant role of interest organizations in public policy making is, however, not mirrored in standard attempts to measure the integration of interest-groups or, as it is called, neo-corporatism. While Austria ranks very high in most of the various empirical investigations (cf. Lehmbruch 1984, Siaroff 1999, Traxler/Blaschke/Kittel 2001), Germany usually is positioned in the middle of the range. Switzerland ranks low in most cases or is perceived as representing a very specific form of corporatism. As Isabelle Steffen and Wolf Linder (in this volume) argue, core institutional features classically associated with corporatism, such as strong trade unions or centralized wage bargaining patterns, are missing in Switzerland. Nevertheless, there are some "functional structures equivalent to neo-corporatist arrangements" (Kriesi 1995: p. 342), such as the institutionalized consultation procedure in policy deliberations ("Vernehmlassung"), which together with other institutional arrangements fosters and stabilizes the crucial influence of interest groups on policy decisions in Switzerland. The same might be argued for Germany. In contrast to Nordic-style corporatism, German wage bargaining was never centralized, nor did powerful, centralized peak associations of labor and capital dominate German politics after World War II. Nevertheless, interest groups and especially those from capital and labor are deeply involved into public policy-making patterns, either through parliamentary commissions or through their powerful position in agencies that implement welfare policies in Germany. Furthermore, self steering of interest groups in several sectors of the German welfare state is a prominent feature of the German Model, such as in wage bargaining or vocational training, to mention only the most important examples (cf. Czada 2003, Siegel 2003, Streeck 1997, Thelen 2004). This meso-corporatist interest mediation is furthermore segmented between different policy fields, and as a consequence, different logics of interest mediation rule at the same time the development of the German democracy (Dohler/Manow 1997). The clearest example of classical corporatism in the German-speaking family of nations is Austria. As Karlhofer (this volume) summarizes, the Austrian case is a prominent example of institutional corporatism because of centralized wage bargaining patterns and, especially, the extensive chamber system. These chambers have quasi-public functions and channel the interest of associated interest groups directly into policy deliberations and policy decisions. At the same time, these chambers have far reaching competences, covering broad areas of the welfare state as well as economic policy making. This leads Karlhofer to conclude that Austria may indeed be called a "Kammerstaat" (state of chambers). Hence, the role of interest organization in public policy-making is an important feature in the democracies of Germany, Austria and Switzerland. Since the early 1980s, however, the traditions and institutions of corporatist interest mediation were challenged by several developments. Firstly, "old" interest groups from capital and labor had to face organizational problems. While German unification might be interpreted as a specific challenge to German trade unions and employers' associations to organize their own camps (Schroeder 2000), in all three countries membership figures and density rates stagnated or revealed a shrinking capability of the respective organizations to attract the rank-and-file. …
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
简介:奥地利、瑞士和德国的智库——社团主义政策制定的重新校准?
德语国家有许多共同之处,这些共同之处使德国、奥地利和瑞士有别于其他发达的民主国家。德语“国际大家庭”的一个突出共性(Castles 1993,2004;(参见Armingeon/Freitag 1997)是利益组织在政策审议、政策决策和政策实施过程中的广泛整合(Katzenstein 1987)。然而,利益组织在公共政策制定中的主导作用并没有反映在衡量利益集团整合的标准尝试中,也就是所谓的新社团主义。虽然奥地利在各种实证调查中排名很高(参见Lehmbruch 1984, Siaroff 1999, Traxler/Blaschke/Kittel 2001),但德国通常处于中间位置。瑞士在大多数情况下排名较低,或者被认为代表了一种非常特殊的社团主义形式。正如伊莎贝尔•斯特芬(Isabelle Steffen)和沃尔夫•林德(Wolf Linder)在本书中所指出的那样,瑞士缺少与社团主义相关的核心制度特征,比如强大的工会或集中的工资谈判模式。然而,有一些“相当于新社团主义安排的功能结构”(Kriesi 1995:第342页),例如政策审议中的制度化协商程序(“Vernehmlassung”),它与其他制度安排一起促进和稳定了利益集团对瑞士政策决定的关键影响。同样的道理也适用于德国。与北欧式的社团主义不同,德国的工资谈判从来没有集中过,二战后,强大的、集中的劳资高峰协会也没有主宰过德国的政治。然而,利益集团,特别是来自资本和劳工的利益集团,通过议会委员会或通过他们在德国实施福利政策的机构中的强大地位,深深地卷入了公共决策模式。此外,在德国福利国家的几个部门中,利益集团的自我导向是德国模式的一个突出特征,例如工资谈判或职业培训,仅举最重要的例子(参见Czada 2003, Siegel 2003, Streeck 1997, Thelen 2004)。这种中社团主义的利益调解被进一步分割为不同的政策领域,因此,不同的利益调解逻辑同时支配着德国民主的发展(Dohler/Manow 1997)。在德语国家大家庭中,古典社团主义最明显的例子是奥地利。正如卡尔霍夫(本卷)所总结的那样,奥地利的案例是制度社团主义的一个突出例子,因为它的工资谈判模式集中,尤其是广泛的商会制度。这些商会具有准公共职能,并将相关利益集团的利益直接纳入政策审议和政策决定。与此同时,这些商会具有深远的能力,涵盖福利国家和经济政策制定的广泛领域。这使得卡尔霍夫得出结论,奥地利确实可以被称为“Kammerstaat”(议院国家)。因此,利益组织在公共决策中的作用是德国、奥地利和瑞士民主制度的一个重要特征。然而,自20世纪80年代初以来,社团主义利益调解的传统和制度受到了一些发展的挑战。首先,来自劳资双方的“老”利益集团不得不面临组织问题。虽然德国统一可能被解释为对德国工会和雇主协会组织自己的营地的具体挑战(Schroeder 2000),但在这三个国家,会员人数和密度率都停滞不前,或者显示出各自组织吸引普通员工的能力在萎缩。…
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
The Status of Ideas in Controversies on Public Policy. Analyzing Beliefs as Dependent Variables: A Case study on Harm Reduction Policies in Switzerland Introduction: Think Tanks in Austria, Switzerland and Germany - A Recalibration of Corporatist Policy Making? The Third Sector and Labour Market Policy in Germany
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1