How Much More Secure does the SECURE Act make American Workers: Evidence from EBRI’s Retirement Security Projection Model®

Jack L. VanDerhei
{"title":"How Much More Secure does the SECURE Act make American Workers: Evidence from EBRI’s Retirement Security Projection Model®","authors":"Jack L. VanDerhei","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3548207","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"This Issue Brief uses EBRI’s Retirement Security Projection Model® (RSPM) to simulate the likely impact on retirement income adequacy of three of the Setting Every Community Up for Retirement Enhancement Act of 2019’s (SECURE Act’s) most important provisions: <br><br>Widening access to multiple employer plans (MEPs) through open MEPs.<br><br>Increasing the cap under which plan sponsors can automatically enroll workers in “safe harbor” retirement plans, from 10 percent of wages to 15 percent.<br><br>Covering long-term part-time employees.<br><br>The impact was measured with three different output metrics:<br><br>Retirement savings shortfalls give the present value of the simulated retirement deficits at retirement age (in 2019 dollars).<br><br>Retirement savings surpluses give the present value of simulated retirement surpluses at retirement age (in 2019 dollars).<br><br>Net retirement savings surpluses give the present value of simulated retirement surpluses less retirement deficits at retirement age (in 2019 dollars).<br><br>Given the lack of information currently available on likely take-up rates for open MEPs by small employers that do not currently offer a retirement plan, sensitivity analysis was performed utilizing a wide array of assumed take-up rates:<br><br>7.3 percent.<br><br>Baseline: 30–31 percent (depending on plan size).<br><br>66 percent.<br><br>100 percent.<br><br>In addition, the actual plan type of the open MEP was simulated three different ways:<br><br>Automatic enrollment (assuming a 90 percent participation rate).<br><br>Voluntary enrollment (assuming a 60 percent participation rate).<br><br>Baseline: A blended rate (assuming a 75 percent participation rate).<br><br>Together, the baseline adoption and non-participation scenarios form the baseline case scenario.<br><br>Overall Reductions in Retirement Savings Shortfalls From Open MEPs: Total Impact Aggregated Across All Age Cohorts<br><br>With adoption of open MEPs at approximately one-third and a non-participation rate of zero (everyone who is eligible chooses to participate), there is an overall 1.8 percent reduction in retirement savings deficit. One would assume that younger age cohorts would experience a larger impact from open MEPs given the longer time for which they may potentially benefit from the increased coverage. Indeed, this is what we find. Overall there is a 3.2 percent reduction in retirement deficit for those ages 35–39.<br><br>In the baseline case scenario there is approximately a one-third adoption rate and 25 percent non-participation: The reduction in retirement savings deficit is now 1.4 percent overall and 2.4 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>Impact of the Increased Cap on Contribution Escalation on the Baseline Case Scenario<br><br>The SECURE Act contains a provision that increases the cap on automatic contribution escalation within the 401(k) non-discrimination testing safe harbor from 10 to 15 percent of pay. Also taking into account the increased cap, the overall reduction in retirement savings deficit is 2.6 percent and 4.5 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>Impact of Coverage of Long-Term Part-Time Employees on the Baseline Case Scenario<br><br>The SECURE Act also contains a provision that requires coverage of long-term part-time employees. Also taking this into account, the reduction in retirement savings deficit is 3.0 percent overall and 5.3 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>Impact of Changes in Opt-Out Rates on Overall Reduction in Retirement Deficit<br><br>If we assume that all open MEPs under SECURE are designed with automatic enrollment, an automatic contribution escalation cap of 15 percent, coverage of long-term part-time employees, and an opt-out rate of 10 percent (typical of automatic enrollment plans):<br><br>The reduction in retirement savings deficit is 3.3 percent overall and 5.8 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The increase in retirement savings surplus is 6.1 percent overall and 15.3 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The increase in net retirement savings surplus is 6.9 percent overall and 18.6 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>If the non-participation rate is 25 percent:<br><br>The reduction in retirement savings deficit is 3.0 percent overall and 5.3 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The increase in retirement savings surplus is 5.9 percent overall and 14.4 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The increase in net retirement savings surplus is 6.6 percent overall and 17.5 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>If the non-participation rate is 40 percent (which is commensurate with voluntary enrollment plans):<br><br>The reduction in retirement savings deficit is 2.8 percent overall and 4.9 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The increase in retirement savings surplus is 5.6 percent overall and 13.9 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The increase in net retirement savings surplus is 6.3 percent overall and 16.8 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The Impact of Various Adoption Rates on Overall Reduction in Retirement Deficit<br><br>If we go back to the scenario above, where open MEPs are available, the cap on the automatic escalation of contributions in the 401(k) testing safe harbor is 15 percent, long-term part-time employees are covered, and non-participation rates are 25 percent of eligible employees, we can now test the impact of different adoption rates.<br><br>In a more aggressive adoption scenario, we assume adoption of open MEPs is 66 percent.<br><br>The reduction in retirement savings deficit is 4.4 percent overall and 7.5 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The increase in retirement savings surplus is 7.2 percent overall and 17.3 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The increase in net retirement savings surplus is 8.2 percent overall and 21.2 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>In our most aggressive scenario, we assume all employers with fewer than 500 employees that do not currently sponsor a retirement plan adopt an open MEP.<br><br>The reduction in retirement savings deficit is now 5.6 percent overall and 9.2 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The increase in retirement savings surplus is 8.7 percent overall and 20.2 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The increase in net retirement savings surplus is 9.9 percent overall and 24.8 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>Conversely, a “worst-case scenario” would assume 7 percent adoption of open MEPs.<br><br>The reduction in retirement savings deficit is 2.0 percent overall and 3.5 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The increase in retirement savings surplus is 4.9 percent overall and 12.3 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The increase in net retirement savings surplus is 5.4 percent overall and 14.8 percent for those ages 35–39.<br><br>The Impact of Auto Portability on Overall Reduction in Retirement Deficit<br><br>Of course, lack of coverage is not the only consideration in determining how well workers will fare in America’s retirement savings system. Studies have found that plan leakage through cashouts upon termination is another key variable in determining retirement savings outcomes, especially among workers with low plan balances. Auto portability seeks to address retirement plan cashouts by having terminated participants’ former employer accounts automatically combine with their active accounts in new employers’ plans. Where open MEPs are available, the cap on the automatic escalation of contributions in the 401(k) testing safe harbor is 15 percent, long-term part-time employees are covered, and non-participation rates are 25 percent of eligible employees; further assuming that, upon termination, participants would have auto portability, the overall reduction in retirement savings shortfalls is 10.0 percent.","PeriodicalId":366379,"journal":{"name":"SIRN: Pension Coverage (Sub-Topic)","volume":"31 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2020-03-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"SIRN: Pension Coverage (Sub-Topic)","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3548207","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

This Issue Brief uses EBRI’s Retirement Security Projection Model® (RSPM) to simulate the likely impact on retirement income adequacy of three of the Setting Every Community Up for Retirement Enhancement Act of 2019’s (SECURE Act’s) most important provisions:

Widening access to multiple employer plans (MEPs) through open MEPs.

Increasing the cap under which plan sponsors can automatically enroll workers in “safe harbor” retirement plans, from 10 percent of wages to 15 percent.

Covering long-term part-time employees.

The impact was measured with three different output metrics:

Retirement savings shortfalls give the present value of the simulated retirement deficits at retirement age (in 2019 dollars).

Retirement savings surpluses give the present value of simulated retirement surpluses at retirement age (in 2019 dollars).

Net retirement savings surpluses give the present value of simulated retirement surpluses less retirement deficits at retirement age (in 2019 dollars).

Given the lack of information currently available on likely take-up rates for open MEPs by small employers that do not currently offer a retirement plan, sensitivity analysis was performed utilizing a wide array of assumed take-up rates:

7.3 percent.

Baseline: 30–31 percent (depending on plan size).

66 percent.

100 percent.

In addition, the actual plan type of the open MEP was simulated three different ways:

Automatic enrollment (assuming a 90 percent participation rate).

Voluntary enrollment (assuming a 60 percent participation rate).

Baseline: A blended rate (assuming a 75 percent participation rate).

Together, the baseline adoption and non-participation scenarios form the baseline case scenario.

Overall Reductions in Retirement Savings Shortfalls From Open MEPs: Total Impact Aggregated Across All Age Cohorts

With adoption of open MEPs at approximately one-third and a non-participation rate of zero (everyone who is eligible chooses to participate), there is an overall 1.8 percent reduction in retirement savings deficit. One would assume that younger age cohorts would experience a larger impact from open MEPs given the longer time for which they may potentially benefit from the increased coverage. Indeed, this is what we find. Overall there is a 3.2 percent reduction in retirement deficit for those ages 35–39.

In the baseline case scenario there is approximately a one-third adoption rate and 25 percent non-participation: The reduction in retirement savings deficit is now 1.4 percent overall and 2.4 percent for those ages 35–39.

Impact of the Increased Cap on Contribution Escalation on the Baseline Case Scenario

The SECURE Act contains a provision that increases the cap on automatic contribution escalation within the 401(k) non-discrimination testing safe harbor from 10 to 15 percent of pay. Also taking into account the increased cap, the overall reduction in retirement savings deficit is 2.6 percent and 4.5 percent for those ages 35–39.

Impact of Coverage of Long-Term Part-Time Employees on the Baseline Case Scenario

The SECURE Act also contains a provision that requires coverage of long-term part-time employees. Also taking this into account, the reduction in retirement savings deficit is 3.0 percent overall and 5.3 percent for those ages 35–39.

Impact of Changes in Opt-Out Rates on Overall Reduction in Retirement Deficit

If we assume that all open MEPs under SECURE are designed with automatic enrollment, an automatic contribution escalation cap of 15 percent, coverage of long-term part-time employees, and an opt-out rate of 10 percent (typical of automatic enrollment plans):

The reduction in retirement savings deficit is 3.3 percent overall and 5.8 percent for those ages 35–39.

The increase in retirement savings surplus is 6.1 percent overall and 15.3 percent for those ages 35–39.

The increase in net retirement savings surplus is 6.9 percent overall and 18.6 percent for those ages 35–39.

If the non-participation rate is 25 percent:

The reduction in retirement savings deficit is 3.0 percent overall and 5.3 percent for those ages 35–39.

The increase in retirement savings surplus is 5.9 percent overall and 14.4 percent for those ages 35–39.

The increase in net retirement savings surplus is 6.6 percent overall and 17.5 percent for those ages 35–39.

If the non-participation rate is 40 percent (which is commensurate with voluntary enrollment plans):

The reduction in retirement savings deficit is 2.8 percent overall and 4.9 percent for those ages 35–39.

The increase in retirement savings surplus is 5.6 percent overall and 13.9 percent for those ages 35–39.

The increase in net retirement savings surplus is 6.3 percent overall and 16.8 percent for those ages 35–39.

The Impact of Various Adoption Rates on Overall Reduction in Retirement Deficit

If we go back to the scenario above, where open MEPs are available, the cap on the automatic escalation of contributions in the 401(k) testing safe harbor is 15 percent, long-term part-time employees are covered, and non-participation rates are 25 percent of eligible employees, we can now test the impact of different adoption rates.

In a more aggressive adoption scenario, we assume adoption of open MEPs is 66 percent.

The reduction in retirement savings deficit is 4.4 percent overall and 7.5 percent for those ages 35–39.

The increase in retirement savings surplus is 7.2 percent overall and 17.3 percent for those ages 35–39.

The increase in net retirement savings surplus is 8.2 percent overall and 21.2 percent for those ages 35–39.

In our most aggressive scenario, we assume all employers with fewer than 500 employees that do not currently sponsor a retirement plan adopt an open MEP.

The reduction in retirement savings deficit is now 5.6 percent overall and 9.2 percent for those ages 35–39.

The increase in retirement savings surplus is 8.7 percent overall and 20.2 percent for those ages 35–39.

The increase in net retirement savings surplus is 9.9 percent overall and 24.8 percent for those ages 35–39.

Conversely, a “worst-case scenario” would assume 7 percent adoption of open MEPs.

The reduction in retirement savings deficit is 2.0 percent overall and 3.5 percent for those ages 35–39.

The increase in retirement savings surplus is 4.9 percent overall and 12.3 percent for those ages 35–39.

The increase in net retirement savings surplus is 5.4 percent overall and 14.8 percent for those ages 35–39.

The Impact of Auto Portability on Overall Reduction in Retirement Deficit

Of course, lack of coverage is not the only consideration in determining how well workers will fare in America’s retirement savings system. Studies have found that plan leakage through cashouts upon termination is another key variable in determining retirement savings outcomes, especially among workers with low plan balances. Auto portability seeks to address retirement plan cashouts by having terminated participants’ former employer accounts automatically combine with their active accounts in new employers’ plans. Where open MEPs are available, the cap on the automatic escalation of contributions in the 401(k) testing safe harbor is 15 percent, long-term part-time employees are covered, and non-participation rates are 25 percent of eligible employees; further assuming that, upon termination, participants would have auto portability, the overall reduction in retirement savings shortfalls is 10.0 percent.
查看原文
分享 分享
微信好友 朋友圈 QQ好友 复制链接
本刊更多论文
《安全法案》让美国工人更安全:来自EBRI退休安全预测模型的证据
本问题简报使用EBRI的退休保障预测模型®(RSPM)来模拟2019年“建立每个社区退休增强法案”(“安全法案”)最重要的三个条款对退休收入充足性的可能影响:通过开放的mep扩大获得多雇主计划(mep)的机会。提高计划发起人自动将员工纳入“安全港”退休计划的上限,从工资的10%提高到15%。涵盖长期兼职雇员。这种影响是用三种不同的产出指标来衡量的:退休储蓄缺口给出了退休年龄时模拟退休赤字的现值(以2019年美元计算)。退休储蓄盈余给出了退休年龄时模拟退休盈余的现值(以2019年美元计算)。净退休储蓄盈余给出了模拟退休盈余减去退休年龄退休赤字的现值(以2019年美元计算)。鉴于目前缺乏关于目前不提供退休计划的小型雇主对开放式欧洲议会议员的可能接受率的信息,利用一系列假定的接受率进行敏感性分析:7.3%。基准:30 - 31%(取决于计划规模)。66%。100%。此外,还以三种不同的方式模拟了开放MEP的实际计划类型:自动注册(假设参与率为90%)。自愿登记(假设参与率为60%)。基线:混合比率(假设参与率为75%)。基线采用场景和不参与场景共同构成基线用例场景。开放欧洲议会的退休储蓄缺口总体减少:所有年龄段的总影响总和开放欧洲议会的采用率约为三分之一,非参与率为零(每个有资格的人都选择参加),退休储蓄赤字总体减少1.8%。人们会认为,年龄较小的人群将受到开放的欧洲议会议员的更大影响,因为他们可能从增加的覆盖范围中受益的时间更长。的确,这就是我们的发现。总体而言,35-39岁人群的退休赤字减少了3.2%。在基线情况下,大约有三分之一的采用率和25%的不参与率:退休储蓄赤字现在减少了1.4%,35-39岁的人减少了2.4%。提高缴费上限对基准情景的影响《安全法案》包含一项条款,将401(k)非歧视测试安全港自动缴费上限从工资的10%提高到15%。考虑到上调上限,35 ~ 39岁的退休储蓄赤字将分别减少2.6%和4.5%。长期兼职雇员覆盖率对基线情景的影响《安全法案》还包含一项规定,要求将长期兼职雇员纳入保险范围。考虑到这一点,退休储蓄赤字总体减少3.0%,35 ~ 39岁年龄段减少5.3%。如果我们假设所有在SECURE下开放的mep都设计了自动注册,自动缴款上限为15%,覆盖长期兼职雇员,选择退出率为10%(自动注册计划的典型):退休储蓄赤字总体减少3.3%,35-39岁的人减少5.8%。退休储蓄余额整体增加6.1%,35-39岁年龄段增加15.3%。退休储蓄净额总体增长6.9%,35-39岁年龄段增长18.6%。如果不参加率为25%,那么退休储蓄赤字将减少3.0%,35-39岁的退休储蓄赤字将减少5.3%。退休储蓄余额整体增加5.9%,35 ~ 39岁增加14.4%。退休储蓄净额总体增长6.6%,35-39岁人群增长17.5%。如果不参保率为40%(与自愿参保计划相当),退休储蓄赤字总体减少2.8%,35-39岁人群减少4.9%。退休储蓄盈余的总体增长率为5.6%,35-39岁年龄段的增长率为13.9%。退休储蓄净额总体增长6.3%,35-39岁年龄段增长16.8%。 不同采用率对整体减少退休赤字的影响如果我们回到上面的场景,其中开放的mep可用,401(k)测试安全港中自动升级缴款的上限为15%,长期兼职员工被覆盖,不参与率为合格员工的25%,我们现在可以测试不同采用率的影响。在更积极的采用场景中,我们假设开放mep的采用率为66%。退休储蓄赤字总体减少4.4%,35-39岁年龄段减少7.5%。退休储蓄盈余的总体增长率为7.2%,35-39岁年龄段的增长率为17.3%。退休储蓄净额总体增长8.2%,35-39岁年龄段增长21.2%。在我们最激进的情况下,我们假设所有员工少于500人的雇主目前没有赞助退休计划,采用开放的MEP。退休储蓄赤字的总体降幅为5.6%,35-39岁年龄段的降幅为9.2%。退休储蓄盈余总体增加8.7%,35-39岁年龄段增加20.2%。退休储蓄净额总体增长9.9%,35-39岁年龄段增长24.8%。相反,“最坏的情况”是假设开放的欧洲议会的采用率为7%。退休储蓄赤字总体减少2.0%,35 ~ 39岁年龄段减少3.5%。退休储蓄盈余总体增加4.9%,35-39岁年龄段增加12.3%。退休储蓄净额总体增长5.4%,35-39岁人群增长14.8%。当然,缺乏保险并不是决定工人在美国退休储蓄体系中生活得如何的唯一考虑因素。研究发现,计划终止后因提现而导致的计划泄漏是决定退休储蓄结果的另一个关键变量,尤其是在计划余额较低的员工中。Auto portability旨在通过终止参与者的前雇主账户自动与他们在新雇主计划中的活跃账户相结合,来解决退休计划的兑现问题。在开放的MEPs中,401(k)测试安全港的自动升级缴款上限为15%,长期兼职员工包括在内,不参与率为合格员工的25%;进一步假设,在终止时,参与者将拥有汽车可携性,退休储蓄缺口的总体减少幅度为10.0%。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
期刊最新文献
Trends in Noncovered Employment and Earnings Among Employees of State and Local Governments, 1994 to 2018 What Jobs Do Employers Want Older Workers to Do? How Much More Secure does the SECURE Act make American Workers: Evidence from EBRI’s Retirement Security Projection Model® Do Pension Cuts for Current Employees Increase Separation? Retiring Employees, Unretired Debt: The Surprising Hidden Cost of Federal Employee Pensions
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
已复制链接
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
×
扫码分享
扫码分享
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1