首页 > 最新文献

Theories of Choice最新文献

英文 中文
Game Theory and the Law 博弈论和法律
Pub Date : 2021-01-14 DOI: 10.1093/OSO/9780198863175.003.0004
Marlies Ahlert
Classical game theory analyses strategic interactions under extreme idealisations. It assumes cognitively unconstrained players with common knowledge concerning game forms, preferences, and rationality. Such ideal theory is highly relevant for human self-understanding as a rational being or what Selten called ‘rationology’. Yet, ideal theory is highly irrelevant for real actors who are in Selten’s sense boundedly rational. Starting from essential features of real bargaining problems, elements of Selten’s ‘micro-psychological’ and Raiffa’s ‘telescopic’ behavioural bargaining theory are introduced. From this, an outline of a workable rationality approach to bargaining emerges. It suggests relying on telescopic elements from Raiffa’s model to provide general outcome orientation and on insights from Selten’s aspiration adaptation model of individual decision making to develop process-sensitive action advice. A bird’s eye view of a prominent recent case of ‘bargaining in the shadow of the courts’ shows a surprisingly good fit of outcomes with the implications of Raiffa’s telescopic approach while remaining compatible with a Seltenian process. Though due to a lack of specific information because the micro-foundations for the telescopic theory cannot be provided, it is at least clear how further case studies and experiments might be put to work here.
经典博弈论分析极端理想化下的战略互动。它假设认知上不受约束的玩家具有关于游戏形式、偏好和合理性的常识。这种理想理论与人类作为理性存在的自我理解或Selten所说的“理性”高度相关。然而,理想理论与塞尔滕意义上的有限理性的现实行为者是高度无关的。从现实议价问题的本质特征出发,介绍了Selten的“微观心理”和Raiffa的“伸缩”行为议价理论的要素。由此,一个可行的理性议价方法的轮廓出现了。它建议依靠Raiffa模型中的伸缩元素来提供一般的结果导向,并根据Selten的个人决策的愿望适应模型的见解来制定过程敏感的行动建议。鸟瞰最近一个著名的“在法院的阴影下讨价还价”的案例,结果与Raiffa的望远镜方法的含义惊人地吻合,同时保持与Seltenian过程的兼容。虽然由于无法提供望远镜理论的微观基础而缺乏具体信息,但至少可以清楚地知道如何进一步进行案例研究和实验。
{"title":"Game Theory and the Law","authors":"Marlies Ahlert","doi":"10.1093/OSO/9780198863175.003.0004","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/OSO/9780198863175.003.0004","url":null,"abstract":"Classical game theory analyses strategic interactions under extreme idealisations. It assumes cognitively unconstrained players with common knowledge concerning game forms, preferences, and rationality. Such ideal theory is highly relevant for human self-understanding as a rational being or what Selten called ‘rationology’. Yet, ideal theory is highly irrelevant for real actors who are in Selten’s sense boundedly rational. Starting from essential features of real bargaining problems, elements of Selten’s ‘micro-psychological’ and Raiffa’s ‘telescopic’ behavioural bargaining theory are introduced. From this, an outline of a workable rationality approach to bargaining emerges. It suggests relying on telescopic elements from Raiffa’s model to provide general outcome orientation and on insights from Selten’s aspiration adaptation model of individual decision making to develop process-sensitive action advice. A bird’s eye view of a prominent recent case of ‘bargaining in the shadow of the courts’ shows a surprisingly good fit of outcomes with the implications of Raiffa’s telescopic approach while remaining compatible with a Seltenian process. Though due to a lack of specific information because the micro-foundations for the telescopic theory cannot be provided, it is at least clear how further case studies and experiments might be put to work here.","PeriodicalId":130127,"journal":{"name":"Theories of Choice","volume":"64 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124756783","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Proper Scope of Behavioural Law and Economics 行为法与经济学的适当范围
Pub Date : 2021-01-14 DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198863175.003.0002
C. Engel
Behavioural law and economics applies the conceptual tools of behavioural economics to the analysis of legal problems and legal intervention. These models, and the experiments to test them, assume an institution-free state of nature. In modern societies, the law’s subjects never see this state of nature. However, a rich arrangement of informal and formal institutions creates generalised trust. If individuals are sufficiently confident that nothing too detrimental will happen, they are freed up to interact with strangers as if they were in a state of nature. This willingness dramatically reduces transaction cost and enables division of labour. If generalised trust can be assumed, simple economic models are appropriate, but they must be behavioural, since otherwise individuals would not want to run the risk of interaction.
行为法律与经济学将行为经济学的概念工具应用于分析法律问题和法律干预。这些模型,以及检验它们的实验,都假定了一种无制度的自然状态。在现代社会中,法律的主体从来没有看到过这种自然状态。然而,非正式和正式制度的丰富安排创造了普遍的信任。如果个人有足够的信心,不会发生什么太有害的事情,他们就可以自由地与陌生人互动,就好像他们处于自然状态一样。这种意愿极大地降低了交易成本,促进了劳动分工。如果可以假设普遍信任,那么简单的经济模型是合适的,但它们必须是行为模型,否则个人不会愿意冒互动的风险。
{"title":"The Proper Scope of Behavioural Law and Economics","authors":"C. Engel","doi":"10.1093/oso/9780198863175.003.0002","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/oso/9780198863175.003.0002","url":null,"abstract":"Behavioural law and economics applies the conceptual tools of behavioural economics to the analysis of legal problems and legal intervention. These models, and the experiments to test them, assume an institution-free state of nature. In modern societies, the law’s subjects never see this state of nature. However, a rich arrangement of informal and formal institutions creates generalised trust. If individuals are sufficiently confident that nothing too detrimental will happen, they are freed up to interact with strangers as if they were in a state of nature. This willingness dramatically reduces transaction cost and enables division of labour. If generalised trust can be assumed, simple economic models are appropriate, but they must be behavioural, since otherwise individuals would not want to run the risk of interaction.","PeriodicalId":130127,"journal":{"name":"Theories of Choice","volume":"6 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124595546","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Collective Intelligence 集体智慧
Pub Date : 2021-01-14 DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198863175.003.0010
A. Engert
The chapter provides an introduction to the social science of ‘collective intelligence’, the aggregation of individual judgments for purposes of collective decision making. It starts from the basic logic of the Condorcet jury theorem and summarises the main determinants of the accuracy of collective cognition. The recent research has focused on developing and refining formal aggregation methods beyond majority voting. The chapter presents the main findings on the two general approaches, surveying and prediction markets. It then contrasts these techniques with informal deliberation as a basic and prevalent aggregation mechanism. One conclusion is that while deliberation is prone to herding and can distort collective judgment, it is also more versatile and robust than formal mechanisms.
本章介绍了“集体智慧”的社会科学,即为集体决策而汇总个人判断。本文从孔多塞陪审团定理的基本逻辑出发,总结了集体认知准确性的主要决定因素。最近的研究主要集中在开发和完善多数投票之外的正式汇总方法。本章介绍了两种一般方法的主要发现,即调查和预测市场。然后将这些技术与非正式审议作为一种基本和普遍的聚集机制进行对比。一个结论是,虽然审议容易产生羊群效应,并可能扭曲集体判断,但它也比正式机制更通用、更强大。
{"title":"Collective Intelligence","authors":"A. Engert","doi":"10.1093/oso/9780198863175.003.0010","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/oso/9780198863175.003.0010","url":null,"abstract":"The chapter provides an introduction to the social science of ‘collective intelligence’, the aggregation of individual judgments for purposes of collective decision making. It starts from the basic logic of the Condorcet jury theorem and summarises the main determinants of the accuracy of collective cognition. The recent research has focused on developing and refining formal aggregation methods beyond majority voting. The chapter presents the main findings on the two general approaches, surveying and prediction markets. It then contrasts these techniques with informal deliberation as a basic and prevalent aggregation mechanism. One conclusion is that while deliberation is prone to herding and can distort collective judgment, it is also more versatile and robust than formal mechanisms.","PeriodicalId":130127,"journal":{"name":"Theories of Choice","volume":"71 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122885155","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Institutional Investor Voting Behaviour 机构投资者投票行为
Pub Date : 2021-01-14 DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198863175.003.0012
L. Enriques, A. Romano
This chapter shows how network theory can improve our understanding of institutional investors’ voting behaviour and, more generally, their role in corporate governance. The standard idea is that institutional investors compete against each other on relative performance and hence might not cast informed votes, due to rational apathy and rational reticence. In other words, institutional investors have incentives to free-ride instead of ‘cooperating’ and casting informed votes. We show that connections of various kinds among institutional investors, whether from formal networks, geographical proximity, or common ownership, and among institutional investors and other agents, such as proxy advisors, contribute to shaping institutional investors’ incentives to vote ‘actively’. They also create intricate competition dynamics: competition takes place not only among institutional investors (and their asset managers) but also at the level of their employees and among ‘cliques’ of institutional investors. Employees, who strive for better jobs, are motivated to obtain more information on portfolio companies than may be strictly justified from their employer institution’s perspective, and to circulate it within their network. Cliques of institutional investors compete against each other. Because there are good reasons to believe that cliques of cooperators outperform cliques of non-cooperators, the network-level competition might increase the incentives of institutional investors to collect information. These dynamics can enhance institutional investors’ engagement in portfolio companies and also shed light on some current policy issues such as the antitrust effects of common ownership and mandatory disclosures of institutional investors’ voting.
本章展示了网络理论如何能够提高我们对机构投资者投票行为的理解,以及更广泛地说,它们在公司治理中的作用。标准的观点是,机构投资者在相对表现上相互竞争,因此,由于理性的冷漠和理性的沉默,他们可能不会在知情的情况下投票。换句话说,机构投资者有搭便车的动机,而不是“合作”和明智地投票。我们表明,机构投资者之间的各种联系,无论是来自正式网络、地理邻近还是共同所有权,以及机构投资者和其他代理人(如代理顾问)之间的联系,都有助于形成机构投资者“积极”投票的动机。它们还创造了复杂的竞争动态:竞争不仅发生在机构投资者(及其资产管理公司)之间,也发生在其雇员层面和机构投资者“小集团”之间。为了更好的工作而奋斗的员工,有动力去获取更多关于投资组合公司的信息,而不是从雇主机构的角度来看严格合理的信息,并在他们的网络中传播这些信息。机构投资者集团之间相互竞争。因为有充分的理由相信,合作集团优于非合作集团,网络层面的竞争可能会增加机构投资者收集信息的动机。这些动态可以增强机构投资者对投资组合公司的参与,也有助于解决当前的一些政策问题,如共同所有权的反垄断效应和机构投资者投票的强制性披露。
{"title":"Institutional Investor Voting Behaviour","authors":"L. Enriques, A. Romano","doi":"10.1093/oso/9780198863175.003.0012","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/oso/9780198863175.003.0012","url":null,"abstract":"This chapter shows how network theory can improve our understanding of institutional investors’ voting behaviour and, more generally, their role in corporate governance. The standard idea is that institutional investors compete against each other on relative performance and hence might not cast informed votes, due to rational apathy and rational reticence. In other words, institutional investors have incentives to free-ride instead of ‘cooperating’ and casting informed votes. We show that connections of various kinds among institutional investors, whether from formal networks, geographical proximity, or common ownership, and among institutional investors and other agents, such as proxy advisors, contribute to shaping institutional investors’ incentives to vote ‘actively’. They also create intricate competition dynamics: competition takes place not only among institutional investors (and their asset managers) but also at the level of their employees and among ‘cliques’ of institutional investors. Employees, who strive for better jobs, are motivated to obtain more information on portfolio companies than may be strictly justified from their employer institution’s perspective, and to circulate it within their network. Cliques of institutional investors compete against each other. Because there are good reasons to believe that cliques of cooperators outperform cliques of non-cooperators, the network-level competition might increase the incentives of institutional investors to collect information. These dynamics can enhance institutional investors’ engagement in portfolio companies and also shed light on some current policy issues such as the antitrust effects of common ownership and mandatory disclosures of institutional investors’ voting.","PeriodicalId":130127,"journal":{"name":"Theories of Choice","volume":"41 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116317121","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Did You Say ‘Theories of Choice’? 你是说“选择理论”吗?
Pub Date : 2021-01-14 DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198863175.003.0007
Anne-Lise Sibony
This chapter takes up two difficult questions: ‘does the law contain one or more theories of choice?’ and, if it does, ‘is there a meta-theory to tell us which theory of choice to use in which cases?’ Even if one retains a loose definition of what counts as a ‘theory of choice’, there are reasons to be sceptical about the enterprise of mapping out theories of choice underpinning the law. This is because the supply of such theories is both abundant and incomplete while the demand is generally weak. Consumer protection, which purports to protect ‘consumer choice’, would seem to be a designated area of law to look for theories of (consumer) choice. However, an enquiry into legislative work on consumer protection reveals paradoxical efforts to confirm the theory that consumers do well with information rather than investigate alternative theories. It also appears that consumer law embeds several different conflicting theories of consumer choice without any sign of a meta-theory indicating which theory applies to which cases. In addition, where there is a theory of consumer harm justifying legislative intervention, it seems to matter little that we do not have a theory for how consumer choice is distorted. In short, the legislative appetite for theories of choice seems limited. Legal scholarship offers a different picture. A space has emerged in which to discuss theories of choice within legal analysis, which is still in the process of being shaped. Tentatively, it is suggested that the legal literature offers a contrast between deep and narrow discussions of theories of choice, and wide and shallow ones.
这一章讨论了两个难题:“法律是否包含一种或多种选择理论?”如果是的话,是否存在一个元理论告诉我们在哪些情况下使用哪种选择理论?即使一个人对什么是“选择理论”保留了一个宽松的定义,我们也有理由对制定支撑法律的选择理论的事业持怀疑态度。这是因为这些理论的供给既丰富又不完整,而需求却普遍疲软。旨在保护“消费者选择”的消费者保护似乎是寻找(消费者)选择理论的指定法律领域。然而,对消费者保护立法工作的调查揭示了自相矛盾的努力,即确认消费者善于利用信息的理论,而不是调查其他理论。消费者法似乎也包含了几种不同的相互冲突的消费者选择理论,但没有任何迹象表明哪种理论适用于哪种情况。此外,在有消费者损害理论为立法干预辩护的地方,我们没有一个关于消费者选择如何被扭曲的理论似乎无关紧要。简而言之,立法机构对选择理论的兴趣似乎有限。法律学术提供了一幅不同的图景。在法律分析中讨论选择理论的空间已经出现,这一空间仍在形成过程中。试探性地提出,法律文献对选择理论的深入和狭隘的讨论,以及广泛和肤浅的讨论进行了对比。
{"title":"Did You Say ‘Theories of Choice’?","authors":"Anne-Lise Sibony","doi":"10.1093/oso/9780198863175.003.0007","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/oso/9780198863175.003.0007","url":null,"abstract":"This chapter takes up two difficult questions: ‘does the law contain one or more theories of choice?’ and, if it does, ‘is there a meta-theory to tell us which theory of choice to use in which cases?’ Even if one retains a loose definition of what counts as a ‘theory of choice’, there are reasons to be sceptical about the enterprise of mapping out theories of choice underpinning the law. This is because the supply of such theories is both abundant and incomplete while the demand is generally weak. Consumer protection, which purports to protect ‘consumer choice’, would seem to be a designated area of law to look for theories of (consumer) choice. However, an enquiry into legislative work on consumer protection reveals paradoxical efforts to confirm the theory that consumers do well with information rather than investigate alternative theories. It also appears that consumer law embeds several different conflicting theories of consumer choice without any sign of a meta-theory indicating which theory applies to which cases. In addition, where there is a theory of consumer harm justifying legislative intervention, it seems to matter little that we do not have a theory for how consumer choice is distorted. In short, the legislative appetite for theories of choice seems limited. Legal scholarship offers a different picture. A space has emerged in which to discuss theories of choice within legal analysis, which is still in the process of being shaped. Tentatively, it is suggested that the legal literature offers a contrast between deep and narrow discussions of theories of choice, and wide and shallow ones.","PeriodicalId":130127,"journal":{"name":"Theories of Choice","volume":"126 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125776606","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Social Welfare Function 社会福利功能
Pub Date : 2019-11-21 DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780190643027.003.0002
M. Adler
The social welfare function (‘SWF’) framework is a methodology for assessing governmental policies that originates in theoretical welfare economics and is now widely used in various economic literatures. The framework translates the possible outcomes of policy choice into patterns of well-being among the population of interest, represented by interpersonally comparable well-being numbers. Policies are then ranked in light of some rule for ordering these well-being patterns (such as a utilitarian or prioritarian rule), taking account of the probability that a given policy will lead to a given outcome. This chapter presents the SWF framework, illustrates how it can be used for regulatory policy analysis, and compares the methodology to cost-benefit analysis (‘CBA’), currently the dominant policy-analytic tool in governmental practice. CBA eschews interpersonal comparisons and, instead, translates policy impacts on each person into a monetary equivalent relative to the status quo; these monetary equivalents are then added up. While CBA and the SWF framework are broadly similar in being consequentialist and welfarist, and in adopting a preference view of well-being, they employ distinct analytic structures for integrating information about preferences and possible outcomes to arrive at an assessment of the various policies that government might adopt. As the chapter demonstrates, the structural differences between the SWF framework and CBA can yield significant divergence at the level of policy recommendation.
社会福利函数(“SWF”)框架是一种评估政府政策的方法,起源于理论福利经济学,现在广泛用于各种经济学文献。该框架将政策选择的可能结果转化为相关人群的福祉模式,由人际间可比较的福祉数字表示。然后根据对这些福利模式排序的一些规则(如功利主义或优先主义规则)对政策进行排序,考虑到给定政策将导致给定结果的概率。本章介绍了主权财富基金框架,说明了如何将其用于监管政策分析,并将其方法与目前在政府实践中占主导地位的政策分析工具成本效益分析(CBA)进行了比较。CBA避免了人与人之间的比较,而是将政策对每个人的影响转化为相对于现状的货币当量;然后把这些货币等价物加起来。虽然CBA和主权财富基金框架在结果主义和福利主义方面大致相似,并且在采用福祉的偏好观方面,它们采用不同的分析结构来整合有关偏好和可能结果的信息,从而对政府可能采取的各种政策进行评估。如本章所示,主权财富基金框架与CBA之间的结构性差异会在政策建议层面产生显著差异。
{"title":"The Social Welfare Function","authors":"M. Adler","doi":"10.1093/oso/9780190643027.003.0002","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/oso/9780190643027.003.0002","url":null,"abstract":"The social welfare function (‘SWF’) framework is a methodology for assessing governmental policies that originates in theoretical welfare economics and is now widely used in various economic literatures. The framework translates the possible outcomes of policy choice into patterns of well-being among the population of interest, represented by interpersonally comparable well-being numbers. Policies are then ranked in light of some rule for ordering these well-being patterns (such as a utilitarian or prioritarian rule), taking account of the probability that a given policy will lead to a given outcome. This chapter presents the SWF framework, illustrates how it can be used for regulatory policy analysis, and compares the methodology to cost-benefit analysis (‘CBA’), currently the dominant policy-analytic tool in governmental practice. CBA eschews interpersonal comparisons and, instead, translates policy impacts on each person into a monetary equivalent relative to the status quo; these monetary equivalents are then added up. While CBA and the SWF framework are broadly similar in being consequentialist and welfarist, and in adopting a preference view of well-being, they employ distinct analytic structures for integrating information about preferences and possible outcomes to arrive at an assessment of the various policies that government might adopt. As the chapter demonstrates, the structural differences between the SWF framework and CBA can yield significant divergence at the level of policy recommendation.","PeriodicalId":130127,"journal":{"name":"Theories of Choice","volume":"8 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-11-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"134052613","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Theories of Choice
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1