首页 > 最新文献

POL: Government Regulation (Topic)最新文献

英文 中文
Board Structure, Payout Policy, and Performance during the Crisis: An Unintended Consequence of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act and the Exchange Listing Rules 危机期间的董事会结构、派息政策和业绩:萨班斯-奥克斯利法案和交易所上市规则的意外后果
Pub Date : 2019-10-17 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3694823
Jie Chen, Woon Sau Leung
Non-compliant firms required to raise board independence by the 2003 NYSE and NASDAQ listing rules significantly increased their dividend payouts and held less cash reserves. As the crisis unfolded, they were more likely to reduce investment and ultimately under-performed compliant firms. The under-performance was more severe for non-compliant firms facing higher costs of external financing and those with greater growth opportunities. Our evidence suggests that regulations requiring independent boards facilitate higher dividends and thereby mitigate agency costs of free cash flow. However, they may also make firms more dependent on external financing and more susceptible to adverse external financing shocks.
不遵守2003年纽交所和纳斯达克上市规则要求提高董事会独立性的公司显著增加了派息,并持有较少的现金储备。随着危机的展开,他们更有可能减少投资,最终导致合规公司表现不佳。对于那些面临更高外部融资成本的不合规公司和那些拥有更大增长机会的公司来说,业绩不佳更为严重。我们的证据表明,要求独立董事会的法规促进了更高的股息,从而降低了自由现金流的代理成本。然而,它们也可能使企业更加依赖外部融资,更容易受到不利的外部融资冲击。
{"title":"Board Structure, Payout Policy, and Performance during the Crisis: An Unintended Consequence of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act and the Exchange Listing Rules","authors":"Jie Chen, Woon Sau Leung","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3694823","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3694823","url":null,"abstract":"Non-compliant firms required to raise board independence by the 2003 NYSE and NASDAQ listing rules significantly increased their dividend payouts and held less cash reserves. As the crisis unfolded, they were more likely to reduce investment and ultimately under-performed compliant firms. The under-performance was more severe for non-compliant firms facing higher costs of external financing and those with greater growth opportunities. Our evidence suggests that regulations requiring independent boards facilitate higher dividends and thereby mitigate agency costs of free cash flow. However, they may also make firms more dependent on external financing and more susceptible to adverse external financing shocks.","PeriodicalId":301403,"journal":{"name":"POL: Government Regulation (Topic)","volume":"42 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-10-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115326457","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Giving Fish or Teaching to Fish? An Empirical Study of the Effects of Government Research and Development Policies 授鱼还是授鱼?政府研发政策效应的实证研究
Pub Date : 2014-11-01 DOI: 10.1111/radm.12087
Kai Xu, Kuo-Feng Huang, Erming Xu
This study compares how government research and development (R&D) subsidy and knowledge transfer from universities and public research institutions stimulate a firm's new product development. More importantly, we emphasize that the effects of these governmental R&D policies on new product development can be achieved not only directly, but also via a mediating role – a firm's innovation capability. Furthermore, we test how other external knowledge sources (such as knowledge from universities and public research institutions) interact with government R&D support to stimulate new product development. The results, based on an investigation of 270 Chinese firms, suggest that both government R&D subsidy and knowledge transfer from universities and public research institutions enhance new product development. The results also show that although government R&D subsidy and knowledge transfer from universities and public research institutions has a direct impact on new product development, innovation capability does mediate the above relationships. Moreover, unlike the findings that other external knowledge sources have a direct influence on new product development as indicated by the previous literature, our findings suggest that external knowledge sources substitute with the government R&D subsidies and complement with knowledge transfer from universities and public research institutions. The results confirm the old sayings that teaching to fish (knowledge transfer from universities and public research institutions can complement with other external knowledge sources) is much better than giving fish (government R&D subsidies substitute other external knowledge sources). This paper enriches current literature of government R&D support policies to firm new product development by providing empirical evidences.
本研究比较了政府研发补贴、大学和公共研究机构的知识转移对企业新产品开发的促进作用。更重要的是,我们强调这些政府研发政策对新产品开发的影响不仅可以直接实现,而且还可以通过企业创新能力的中介作用来实现。此外,我们还测试了其他外部知识来源(如来自大学和公共研究机构的知识)如何与政府研发支持相互作用,以刺激新产品开发。基于对270家中国企业的调查结果表明,政府研发补贴和大学和公共研究机构的知识转移都促进了新产品的开发。研究结果还表明,虽然政府研发补贴和高校及公共科研机构的知识转移对新产品开发有直接影响,但创新能力在二者之间起中介作用。此外,与以往文献认为其他外部知识来源对新产品开发有直接影响的研究结果不同,我们的研究结果表明,外部知识来源替代了政府研发补贴,并补充了大学和公共研究机构的知识转移。研究结果证实了“授鱼以教”(大学和公共研究机构的知识转移可以与其他外部知识来源互补)比“授鱼以治”(政府研发补贴可以替代其他外部知识来源)的老话。本文通过提供实证证据,丰富了现有政府研发支持政策对新产品开发的支持文献。
{"title":"Giving Fish or Teaching to Fish? An Empirical Study of the Effects of Government Research and Development Policies","authors":"Kai Xu, Kuo-Feng Huang, Erming Xu","doi":"10.1111/radm.12087","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/radm.12087","url":null,"abstract":"This study compares how government research and development (R&D) subsidy and knowledge transfer from universities and public research institutions stimulate a firm's new product development. More importantly, we emphasize that the effects of these governmental R&D policies on new product development can be achieved not only directly, but also via a mediating role – a firm's innovation capability. Furthermore, we test how other external knowledge sources (such as knowledge from universities and public research institutions) interact with government R&D support to stimulate new product development. The results, based on an investigation of 270 Chinese firms, suggest that both government R&D subsidy and knowledge transfer from universities and public research institutions enhance new product development. The results also show that although government R&D subsidy and knowledge transfer from universities and public research institutions has a direct impact on new product development, innovation capability does mediate the above relationships. Moreover, unlike the findings that other external knowledge sources have a direct influence on new product development as indicated by the previous literature, our findings suggest that external knowledge sources substitute with the government R&D subsidies and complement with knowledge transfer from universities and public research institutions. The results confirm the old sayings that teaching to fish (knowledge transfer from universities and public research institutions can complement with other external knowledge sources) is much better than giving fish (government R&D subsidies substitute other external knowledge sources). This paper enriches current literature of government R&D support policies to firm new product development by providing empirical evidences.","PeriodicalId":301403,"journal":{"name":"POL: Government Regulation (Topic)","volume":"107 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131723396","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 32
Multi-Networked Governance of Networks: Regulating Telecommunications in the United Kingdom 网络的多网络治理:英国的电信监管
Pub Date : 2014-06-25 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2504460
E. Sutherland
Opinion polls suggest Scotland will reject independence, opening the way to a review of economic governance in the United Kingdom, a complex quasi-federal, asymmetric system of administrations and parliaments, the result of ad hoc changes over decades. One party wants telecommunications “devolved” to Northern Ireland, other would leave it at the United Kingdom, where there is wide support for a voluntary “digital champion” to boost Internet adoption amongst the elderly and the poor. There is network governance economic regulation at the global, EU, ministerial and regulator levels, though generally excluding the four nations: England, Northern Ireland, Scotland and Wales. There are no formal mechanisms to involve the three devolved legislatures in telecommunications governance, which is complex and lies partially beyond democratic oversight and judicial review. Improvements are required to simplify, increase transparency (e.g., more use of open data) and the widen involvement, enabling oversight and review.
民意调查显示,苏格兰将拒绝独立,这为重新审视英国的经济治理开辟了道路。英国是一个复杂的准联邦、不对称的行政和议会体系,是几十年来临时变化的结果。一方希望将电信“下放”给北爱尔兰,另一方则希望将其留在英国。在英国,人们广泛支持一个自愿的“数字冠军”来促进老年人和穷人对互联网的采用。在全球、欧盟、部长级和监管机构层面都存在网络治理经济监管,但通常不包括英格兰、北爱尔兰、苏格兰和威尔士这四个国家。没有正式的机制让这三个权力下放的立法机构参与电信治理,这是复杂的,部分超出了民主监督和司法审查的范围。需要改进以简化、增加透明度(例如,更多地使用开放数据)和扩大参与,从而能够进行监督和审查。
{"title":"Multi-Networked Governance of Networks: Regulating Telecommunications in the United Kingdom","authors":"E. Sutherland","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2504460","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2504460","url":null,"abstract":"Opinion polls suggest Scotland will reject independence, opening the way to a review of economic governance in the United Kingdom, a complex quasi-federal, asymmetric system of administrations and parliaments, the result of ad hoc changes over decades. One party wants telecommunications “devolved” to Northern Ireland, other would leave it at the United Kingdom, where there is wide support for a voluntary “digital champion” to boost Internet adoption amongst the elderly and the poor. There is network governance economic regulation at the global, EU, ministerial and regulator levels, though generally excluding the four nations: England, Northern Ireland, Scotland and Wales. There are no formal mechanisms to involve the three devolved legislatures in telecommunications governance, which is complex and lies partially beyond democratic oversight and judicial review. Improvements are required to simplify, increase transparency (e.g., more use of open data) and the widen involvement, enabling oversight and review.","PeriodicalId":301403,"journal":{"name":"POL: Government Regulation (Topic)","volume":"143 ","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-06-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"113993021","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Infrastructure Upgrades and Foreclosure with Coexistence of Service-Based and Facility-Based Firms 服务型企业与设施型企业并存的基础设施升级与止赎
Pub Date : 2012-12-09 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2187148
Noriaki Matsushima, Keizo Mizuno
We investigate the incentives for facility-based firms to invest in infrastructure upgrades and to foreclose service-based firms. We focus on asymmetric regulation regarding service-based firms' access to the infrastructure held by a facility-based firm. Spillovers from the infrastructure upgrades made by a regulated facility-based firm on service-based firms play a key role in the incentives for making these upgrades. The spillover effect can enhance the incentives for the regulated facility-based firm to make upgrades if access prices are not regulated. The existence of rival facility-based firms strengthens the incentives for a regulated facility-based firm to make infrastructure upgrades, especially when the spillover effect is significant. Furthermore, if access prices are not regulated, the existence of rival facility-based firms weakens the incentives for a regulated facility-based firm to foreclose service-based firms.
我们研究了设施型企业投资基础设施升级和取消服务型企业抵押品赎回权的激励机制。我们关注服务型公司使用设施型公司所拥有的基础设施的不对称监管。受监管的设施型企业对服务型企业进行基础设施升级所产生的溢出效应,在进行这些升级的激励机制中起着关键作用。在接入价格不受管制的情况下,溢出效应可以增强受管制设施型企业进行升级的激励。竞争对手设施企业的存在增强了受监管设施企业进行基础设施升级的激励,尤其是在溢出效应显著的情况下。此外,如果准入价格不受管制,竞争对手设施公司的存在削弱了受管制的设施公司取消服务型公司抵押品赎回权的动机。
{"title":"Infrastructure Upgrades and Foreclosure with Coexistence of Service-Based and Facility-Based Firms","authors":"Noriaki Matsushima, Keizo Mizuno","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2187148","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2187148","url":null,"abstract":"We investigate the incentives for facility-based firms to invest in infrastructure upgrades and to foreclose service-based firms. We focus on asymmetric regulation regarding service-based firms' access to the infrastructure held by a facility-based firm. Spillovers from the infrastructure upgrades made by a regulated facility-based firm on service-based firms play a key role in the incentives for making these upgrades. The spillover effect can enhance the incentives for the regulated facility-based firm to make upgrades if access prices are not regulated. The existence of rival facility-based firms strengthens the incentives for a regulated facility-based firm to make infrastructure upgrades, especially when the spillover effect is significant. Furthermore, if access prices are not regulated, the existence of rival facility-based firms weakens the incentives for a regulated facility-based firm to foreclose service-based firms.","PeriodicalId":301403,"journal":{"name":"POL: Government Regulation (Topic)","volume":"13 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2012-12-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125486303","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Quasi-Judicial Mechanisms in Asian Production Networks: Archetypes for Emerging Market Strategy 亚洲生产网络中的准司法机制:新兴市场战略的原型
Pub Date : 2012-06-13 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2083533
R. Galang
Despite their predominance in developing countries, production networks vary enormously among countries and yet attempts to systematically compare their nature have been done very sporadically in the literature. Drawing on relational contract theory, this paper presents a novel framework for analyzing the differences in the ways production networks organize themselves in emerging markets by utilizing successful Asian organizational structures to illustrate strategy archetypes. The paper analyzes three different relational employment and outsourcing contract forms through which the lead firm in a production network can maintain a quasi-judicial role in resolving the contracting problems inherent in multi-firm transactions. The production network templates embodied by Korean chaebols, Japanese keiretsus and Taiwanese guanxi relationships use different explicit and implicit contractual arrangements to adjudicate interparty disputes internally and can serve as more appropriate benchmarks for firms operating in emerging markets as opposed to existing templates based on mainstream strategy theories generated in developed countries.
尽管生产网络在发展中国家占主导地位,但各国之间的生产网络差异很大,然而,文献中很少有人尝试系统地比较它们的性质。利用关系契约理论,本文提出了一个新的框架,通过利用成功的亚洲组织结构来说明战略原型,来分析新兴市场中生产网络组织方式的差异。本文分析了三种不同的关系雇佣和外包合同形式,通过这些形式,生产网络中的领导企业可以在解决多企业交易中固有的合同问题时保持准司法角色。韩国财阀、日本经社和台湾关系所体现的生产网络模板使用不同的显性和隐性合同安排来内部裁决当事人之间的纠纷,可以作为在新兴市场经营的公司更合适的基准,而不是基于发达国家产生的主流战略理论的现有模板。
{"title":"Quasi-Judicial Mechanisms in Asian Production Networks: Archetypes for Emerging Market Strategy","authors":"R. Galang","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2083533","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2083533","url":null,"abstract":"Despite their predominance in developing countries, production networks vary enormously among countries and yet attempts to systematically compare their nature have been done very sporadically in the literature. Drawing on relational contract theory, this paper presents a novel framework for analyzing the differences in the ways production networks organize themselves in emerging markets by utilizing successful Asian organizational structures to illustrate strategy archetypes. The paper analyzes three different relational employment and outsourcing contract forms through which the lead firm in a production network can maintain a quasi-judicial role in resolving the contracting problems inherent in multi-firm transactions. The production network templates embodied by Korean chaebols, Japanese keiretsus and Taiwanese guanxi relationships use different explicit and implicit contractual arrangements to adjudicate interparty disputes internally and can serve as more appropriate benchmarks for firms operating in emerging markets as opposed to existing templates based on mainstream strategy theories generated in developed countries.","PeriodicalId":301403,"journal":{"name":"POL: Government Regulation (Topic)","volume":"98 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2012-06-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131704004","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Fulfilling Kennedy’s Promise: Why the SEC Should Mandate Disclosure of Corporate Political Activity 履行肯尼迪的承诺:为什么证交会应该强制披露公司政治活动
Pub Date : 2011-07-27 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1923804
John C. Coates, IV, T. Lincoln
The Supreme Court’s Citizens United decision to let corporations spend unlimited sums in federal elections was premised on a pair of promises: Corporations would disclose expenditures, and shareholders would police such spending. Those promises remain unfulfilled: of $266 million spent by outside groups in 2010, half was spent by groups that revealed nothing about their funders, double the total spending by outside groups in 2006. The best chance to fulfill those promises may now rest with the SEC. Contrary to consensus views, SEC action may benefit owners of affected firms. We estimate industry-adjusted price-to-book ratios of 80 companies in the S&P 500 that have policies calling for disclosure of electioneering. After controlling for size, leverage, research and development, growth and political activity, we find disclosing companies had 7.5 percent higher ratios than other S&P 500 companies in 2010. Our data are inconsistent with claims that disclosure is harmful, and are consistent with the idea that well-managed companies responsive to shareholder concerns tend to be valued more highly than other companies.
最高法院“联合公民”(Citizens United)案允许企业在联邦选举中无限制支出的决定,是以两项承诺为前提的:企业将披露支出,股东将监督此类支出。这些承诺至今仍未兑现:2010年外部团体花费的2.66亿美元中,有一半是由对其资助者一无所知的团体花费的,是2006年外部团体总支出的两倍。实现这些承诺的最佳机会现在可能取决于SEC。与普遍观点相反,SEC的行动可能会使受影响公司的所有者受益。我们对标准普尔500指数中有80家公司进行了行业调整后的市净率估算,这些公司的政策要求披露竞选活动。在控制了规模、杠杆、研发、增长和政治活动后,我们发现,2010年,披露公司的比率比其他标准普尔500指数公司高7.5%。我们的数据与披露有害的说法不一致,却与管理良好、对股东关切做出回应的公司往往比其他公司估值更高的观点一致。
{"title":"Fulfilling Kennedy’s Promise: Why the SEC Should Mandate Disclosure of Corporate Political Activity","authors":"John C. Coates, IV, T. Lincoln","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1923804","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1923804","url":null,"abstract":"The Supreme Court’s Citizens United decision to let corporations spend unlimited sums in federal elections was premised on a pair of promises: Corporations would disclose expenditures, and shareholders would police such spending. Those promises remain unfulfilled: of $266 million spent by outside groups in 2010, half was spent by groups that revealed nothing about their funders, double the total spending by outside groups in 2006. The best chance to fulfill those promises may now rest with the SEC. Contrary to consensus views, SEC action may benefit owners of affected firms. We estimate industry-adjusted price-to-book ratios of 80 companies in the S&P 500 that have policies calling for disclosure of electioneering. After controlling for size, leverage, research and development, growth and political activity, we find disclosing companies had 7.5 percent higher ratios than other S&P 500 companies in 2010. Our data are inconsistent with claims that disclosure is harmful, and are consistent with the idea that well-managed companies responsive to shareholder concerns tend to be valued more highly than other companies.","PeriodicalId":301403,"journal":{"name":"POL: Government Regulation (Topic)","volume":"89 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2011-07-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127040318","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Appropriate Antitrust Policy Towards Single-Firm Conduct 针对单一企业行为的适当反垄断政策
Pub Date : 2008-03-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1111665
D. Carlton, K. Heyer
In this article we distinguish between two types of single-firm conduct. The first, which we call "extraction," is conduct engaged in by the firm to capture surplus from what the firm has itself created independent of the conduct’s effect on rivals. The second, which we call “extension," is single firm conduct that increases the firm’s profit by weakening or eliminating the competitive constraints provided by products of rivals. We propose as a fundamental antitrust policy towards single-firm conduct the following: Conduct merely to extract surplus the firm has created independent of the conduct’s effect on rivals should be permitted. Conversely, conduct that extends the firm’s market power by impairing the competitive constraints imposed by rivals presents a legitimate cause for concern. We subscribe strongly to the view that an essential element of appropriate antitrust policy is to allow a firm to capture as much of the surplus that, by its own investment, innovation, industry or foresight, the firm has itself brought into existence. We believe that alternative approaches to single-firm conduct, including in particular ones aiming to enhance static efficiency at the possible cost of dynamic efficiency and ones seeking to maximize overall welfare through more targeted intervention on a case-by-case basis (not to mention the use of competition policy to protect competitors rather than consumers) threaten seriously to impede economic growth and welfare over time. A policy that goes further, and which permits all unilateral conduct regardless of competitive effects (perhaps on grounds that "even more profit will generate even more innovation") is considered below and rejected as overly lenient, inconsistent with widely accepted presumptions in favor of inter-firm competition, and unwise, at least under the current state of economic knowledge. But we note that this conclusion is one based on our current economic knowledge and should remain a topic of ongoing research. It requires an empirical assessment of the gains from motivating more competition ex ante versus the subsequent loss of competition ex post.
在本文中,我们将区分两种类型的单一公司行为。第一种,我们称之为“榨取”,是指企业从事的行为,目的是从企业自己创造的产品中获取盈余,而不考虑这种行为对竞争对手的影响。第二种,我们称之为“延伸”,是单个企业的行为,通过削弱或消除竞争对手产品提供的竞争约束来增加企业利润。我们建议作为针对单一公司行为的基本反垄断政策如下:应该允许仅为提取公司创造的盈余而独立于其对竞争对手的影响的行为。相反,通过削弱竞争对手施加的竞争约束来扩大公司市场力量的行为,则是引起关注的合理原因。我们强烈赞同这样一种观点,即适当的反垄断政策的一个基本要素是允许一家公司通过自己的投资、创新、工业或远见,尽可能多地获取其自身产生的盈余。我们认为,针对单一企业行为的替代方法,特别是那些旨在以可能的动态效率为代价提高静态效率的方法,以及那些寻求通过逐案更有针对性的干预(更不用说使用竞争政策来保护竞争对手而不是消费者)来最大化整体福利的方法,随着时间的推移,可能会严重阻碍经济增长和福利。一种更进一步的政策,允许所有的单边行为,而不考虑竞争的影响(也许是基于“更多的利润将产生更多的创新”),被认为过于宽松,与广泛接受的支持企业间竞争的假设不一致,并且不明智,至少在当前的经济知识状态下。但我们注意到,这一结论是基于我们目前的经济知识得出的,应该继续作为研究的主题。它需要对事前激励更多竞争的收益与事后竞争的损失进行实证评估。
{"title":"Appropriate Antitrust Policy Towards Single-Firm Conduct","authors":"D. Carlton, K. Heyer","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1111665","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1111665","url":null,"abstract":"In this article we distinguish between two types of single-firm conduct. The first, which we call \"extraction,\" is conduct engaged in by the firm to capture surplus from what the firm has itself created independent of the conduct’s effect on rivals. The second, which we call “extension,\" is single firm conduct that increases the firm’s profit by weakening or eliminating the competitive constraints provided by products of rivals. We propose as a fundamental antitrust policy towards single-firm conduct the following: Conduct merely to extract surplus the firm has created independent of the conduct’s effect on rivals should be permitted. Conversely, conduct that extends the firm’s market power by impairing the competitive constraints imposed by rivals presents a legitimate cause for concern. We subscribe strongly to the view that an essential element of appropriate antitrust policy is to allow a firm to capture as much of the surplus that, by its own investment, innovation, industry or foresight, the firm has itself brought into existence. We believe that alternative approaches to single-firm conduct, including in particular ones aiming to enhance static efficiency at the possible cost of dynamic efficiency and ones seeking to maximize overall welfare through more targeted intervention on a case-by-case basis (not to mention the use of competition policy to protect competitors rather than consumers) threaten seriously to impede economic growth and welfare over time. A policy that goes further, and which permits all unilateral conduct regardless of competitive effects (perhaps on grounds that \"even more profit will generate even more innovation\") is considered below and rejected as overly lenient, inconsistent with widely accepted presumptions in favor of inter-firm competition, and unwise, at least under the current state of economic knowledge. But we note that this conclusion is one based on our current economic knowledge and should remain a topic of ongoing research. It requires an empirical assessment of the gains from motivating more competition ex ante versus the subsequent loss of competition ex post.","PeriodicalId":301403,"journal":{"name":"POL: Government Regulation (Topic)","volume":"39 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130899512","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 16
The Effect of Disclosure Regulation on M&A Activity: Evidence from the Over-the-Counter Market 信息披露制度对并购活动的影响:来自场外交易市场的证据
Pub Date : 2007-05-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1032798
A. Uccellini
This paper tests the impact of mandated disclosure regulation on merger & acquisition (M&A) activity by studying the extension of the U.S. mandated disclosure regime to companies trading on the over-the-counter (OTC) securities market, the Securities Acts Amendments of 1964. The Securities Acts Amendments are an excellent test case of the effects on M&A activity due to (i) the large number of affected OTC companies, (ii) the typical paucity of disclosure among OTC companies before the passage of the legislation, (iii) the absence of any severe macroeconomic shocks during the test period and (iv) the natural control group provided by the non-OTC companies not affected by the Securities Acts Amendments. The paper tests the impact of mandated disclosure on M&A activity among OTC companies during the 1955-75 period in two ways, regression analysis and comparison with M&A activity among non-OTC companies. Both tests in the paper strongly support the views of several academics and practitioners that mandated disclosure provides useful information to the market and that this information encourages higher levels of M&A activity.
本文通过研究美国1964年《证券法修正案》将强制披露制度扩展到在场外证券市场交易的公司,来检验强制披露制度对并购活动的影响。由于(i)受影响的场外公司数量众多,(ii)立法通过前场外公司典型的信息披露不足,(iii)在测试期间没有任何严重的宏观经济冲击,以及(iv)未受证券法修正案影响的非场外公司提供的自然对照组,《证券法修正案》是对并购活动影响的极好测试案例。本文通过回归分析和与非OTC公司并购活动的比较两种方法检验了1955- 1975年期间强制披露对OTC公司并购活动的影响。论文中的两项测试都有力地支持了一些学者和从业者的观点,即强制性披露为市场提供了有用的信息,这些信息鼓励了更高水平的并购活动。
{"title":"The Effect of Disclosure Regulation on M&A Activity: Evidence from the Over-the-Counter Market","authors":"A. Uccellini","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1032798","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1032798","url":null,"abstract":"This paper tests the impact of mandated disclosure regulation on merger & acquisition (M&A) activity by studying the extension of the U.S. mandated disclosure regime to companies trading on the over-the-counter (OTC) securities market, the Securities Acts Amendments of 1964. The Securities Acts Amendments are an excellent test case of the effects on M&A activity due to (i) the large number of affected OTC companies, (ii) the typical paucity of disclosure among OTC companies before the passage of the legislation, (iii) the absence of any severe macroeconomic shocks during the test period and (iv) the natural control group provided by the non-OTC companies not affected by the Securities Acts Amendments. The paper tests the impact of mandated disclosure on M&A activity among OTC companies during the 1955-75 period in two ways, regression analysis and comparison with M&A activity among non-OTC companies. Both tests in the paper strongly support the views of several academics and practitioners that mandated disclosure provides useful information to the market and that this information encourages higher levels of M&A activity.","PeriodicalId":301403,"journal":{"name":"POL: Government Regulation (Topic)","volume":"152 8 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2007-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116701186","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
POL: Government Regulation (Topic)
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1