首页 > 最新文献

National Economic Trends最新文献

英文 中文
The price puzzle: an update and a lesson 价格之谜:一个更新和教训
Pub Date : 1900-01-01 DOI: 10.20955/ES.2006.24
Michael J. Dueker
A fundamental tenet of monetary policymaking is that a surprise increase in the short-term interest rate will lower price inflation from what it otherwise would have been. Thus, it has been disconcerting to macroeconomists that many empirical estimates of the relationship between the federal funds rate and inflation have suggested that a surprise interest rate hike is followed immediately by a sustained increase in the inflation rate. This result has become known as the “price puzzle,” starting with Eichenbaum (1992). Hanson (2004) showed that it is not easy to explain away the price puzzle, especially in the pre-1980 period. The attached chart highlights circumstances in which the price puzzle flourished; specifically, it shows the tendency of the federal funds rate to precede change in inflation in the same direction during the 1970s. Interpretations of the price puzzle can differ in an important aspect: A conventional view is that nobody should believe that surprise interest rate hikes are ever inflationary in reality. Accord ing to this view, any empirical finding of the price puzzle is necessarily a false reading and a sign of a problem with the empirical model that generated such a result. A relatively new explanation for the price puzzle admits the possibility that surprise interest rate hikes really could be inflationary in some circumstances. The view that the price puzzle is a genuine phenomenon—especially in the pre-1980 period—can be based on indeterminacy. Loosely speaking, an economy’s characteristics correspond to indeterminacy when there is no way to identify the exact sources of forecast errors (for inflation and GDP, for example) in terms of clearly identifiable sources of shocks (such as surprise changes in the federal funds rate and productivity surprises). In general, it is possible to show in a macroeconomic model that some combinations of characteristics (such as how risk-averse people are, how sticky prices are updated, and how monetary policy is set) pertain to “determinacy” and others pertain to “indeterminacy.” Lubik and Schorfheide (2003) provided the necessary tools to allow for empirical estimates of an economy under indeterminacy. Hence, only recently have macroeconomists been able to explore how closely the data from a given time period conform to determinacy or indeterminacy. Belaygorod and Dueker (2006) estimate a model of the U.S. economy that also attempts to discern the precise period when indeterminacy was relevant. Their estimates suggest that the indeterminacy period was roughly from 1972 through 1981. Importantly for the price puzzle, the model estimates imply that in this period of indeterminacy, inflation would rise immediately and in a sustained fashion in response to an interest rate hike. Reassuringly for monetary policymakers, the model estimates for both determinacy periods— before 1972 and after 1981—suggest that increases in the federal funds rate unambiguously help rein in inflation. In the type
货币政策制定的一个基本原则是,短期利率的意外上调将降低物价通胀。因此,让宏观经济学家感到不安的是,许多对联邦基金利率和通货膨胀之间关系的实证估计表明,突然加息之后,通货膨胀率会立即持续上升。从Eichenbaum(1992)开始,这个结果被称为“价格之谜”。Hanson(2004)表明,要解释价格之谜并不容易,尤其是在1980年之前的时期。所附图表突出了价格谜题盛行的情况;具体来说,它显示了20世纪70年代联邦基金利率在同一方向上先于通货膨胀变化的趋势。对价格谜题的解释可能在一个重要方面有所不同:传统观点认为,没有人应该相信意外加息在现实中会导致通胀。根据这一观点,任何关于价格之谜的实证发现都必然是错误的解读,并且表明产生这种结果的实证模型存在问题。对价格之谜的一种相对较新的解释承认,在某些情况下,突然加息确实可能导致通胀。认为价格之谜是一种真实现象的观点——尤其是在1980年之前的时期——可以建立在不确定性的基础上。粗略地说,当无法确定预测错误的确切来源(例如通货膨胀和GDP)时,经济特征对应于不确定性,因为可以明确识别的冲击来源(例如联邦基金利率的意外变化和生产率的意外变化)。一般来说,在宏观经济模型中有可能显示出某些特征组合(例如人们如何规避风险,价格的粘性如何更新,以及货币政策如何制定)属于“确定性”,而其他特征属于“不确定性”。Lubik和Schorfheide(2003)提供了必要的工具,允许对不确定性下的经济进行经验估计。因此,直到最近,宏观经济学家才能够探索给定时间段的数据与确定性或不确定性的关系有多密切。Belaygorod和Dueker(2006)估计了一个美国经济模型,该模型也试图辨别不确定性相关的精确时期。他们的估计表明,不确定期大约是从1972年到1981年。对于价格谜题来说,重要的是,模型估计表明,在这段不确定时期,通胀将立即持续上升,以应对加息。令货币政策制定者放心的是,模型对两个确定期(1972年之前和1981年之后)的估计表明,提高联邦基金利率无疑有助于控制通胀。在Belaygorod和Dueker估计的模型类型中,当货币政策在提高联邦基金利率以应对通货膨胀上升方面过于被动时,就会出现不确定性。因此,对20世纪70年代和80年代初的大通胀的一种理解可能来自于价格之谜的不确定性解释,即货币政策制定者在将经济从不确定性中解脱出来的过程中遇到了困难。一旦经济中的人们开始相信价格之谜——即加息会导致通胀——货币政策制定者如何说服人们再次相信加息会降低通胀的确定性机制?政策制定者似乎已经吸取的教训是,为了避免这个陷阱,首先要保持积极的通胀斗士,以保持人们对确定性的信念。
{"title":"The price puzzle: an update and a lesson","authors":"Michael J. Dueker","doi":"10.20955/ES.2006.24","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.20955/ES.2006.24","url":null,"abstract":"A fundamental tenet of monetary policymaking is that a surprise increase in the short-term interest rate will lower price inflation from what it otherwise would have been. Thus, it has been disconcerting to macroeconomists that many empirical estimates of the relationship between the federal funds rate and inflation have suggested that a surprise interest rate hike is followed immediately by a sustained increase in the inflation rate. This result has become known as the “price puzzle,” starting with Eichenbaum (1992). Hanson (2004) showed that it is not easy to explain away the price puzzle, especially in the pre-1980 period. The attached chart highlights circumstances in which the price puzzle flourished; specifically, it shows the tendency of the federal funds rate to precede change in inflation in the same direction during the 1970s. Interpretations of the price puzzle can differ in an important aspect: A conventional view is that nobody should believe that surprise interest rate hikes are ever inflationary in reality. Accord ing to this view, any empirical finding of the price puzzle is necessarily a false reading and a sign of a problem with the empirical model that generated such a result. A relatively new explanation for the price puzzle admits the possibility that surprise interest rate hikes really could be inflationary in some circumstances. The view that the price puzzle is a genuine phenomenon—especially in the pre-1980 period—can be based on indeterminacy. Loosely speaking, an economy’s characteristics correspond to indeterminacy when there is no way to identify the exact sources of forecast errors (for inflation and GDP, for example) in terms of clearly identifiable sources of shocks (such as surprise changes in the federal funds rate and productivity surprises). In general, it is possible to show in a macroeconomic model that some combinations of characteristics (such as how risk-averse people are, how sticky prices are updated, and how monetary policy is set) pertain to “determinacy” and others pertain to “indeterminacy.” Lubik and Schorfheide (2003) provided the necessary tools to allow for empirical estimates of an economy under indeterminacy. Hence, only recently have macroeconomists been able to explore how closely the data from a given time period conform to determinacy or indeterminacy. Belaygorod and Dueker (2006) estimate a model of the U.S. economy that also attempts to discern the precise period when indeterminacy was relevant. Their estimates suggest that the indeterminacy period was roughly from 1972 through 1981. Importantly for the price puzzle, the model estimates imply that in this period of indeterminacy, inflation would rise immediately and in a sustained fashion in response to an interest rate hike. Reassuringly for monetary policymakers, the model estimates for both determinacy periods— before 1972 and after 1981—suggest that increases in the federal funds rate unambiguously help rein in inflation. In the type ","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"19 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126897881","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Look who's still working now 看看谁还在工作
Pub Date : 1900-01-01 DOI: 10.20955/ES.2007.14
Kristie M. Engemann, Michael T. Owyang
{"title":"Look who's still working now","authors":"Kristie M. Engemann, Michael T. Owyang","doi":"10.20955/ES.2007.14","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.20955/ES.2007.14","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"84 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123709756","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Your current job probably won't be your last 你现在的工作可能不会是最后一份
Pub Date : 1900-01-01 DOI: 10.20955/ES.2004.5
Kristie M. Engemann, Michael T. Owyang
NationalEconomicTrends Views expressed do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System. P revious generations of workers held lifelong jobs. Today's workers no longer expect to work for the same employer for their entire career. Even in the past 20 years, expected job tenure has declined in the United States, with a few differences between the trends for men and women. Some notable trends in job tenure, and their potential causes, may provide some insight into the employment landscape of the future. Friedberg and Owyang (2002) use data from the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) to find job tenure trends. 1 According to the SCF, from 1983 to 1998, average expected remaining tenure—how long a worker expects to continue working for his current employer—for full-time male employees declined from 18.6 to 14.7 years. The trend for female workers is similar. Their expected remaining tenure starts at 15.9 in 1983 and eventually falls to 12.8 years in 1998. 2 The accompanying graph shows these numbers broken down by years of experience at workers' current jobs. Note that for nearly every subsample, expected remaining tenure has decreased. An interesting trend arises with the percentage of employees aged 25 and older who have been with their current employer for at least ten years. The total percentage of men in this group decreased by nearly 5 points from 1983 to 2002, whereas the opposite holds for women— their percentage increased by almost 4 points. All age groups for men saw declines, but those affected most negatively were men aged 40-44, 45-49, and, especially, 60-64. In contrast, the percentage of women aged 35-54 with ten-year tenure or longer increased, but the remaining age groups suffered the same fate as the men's age groups. 3 What could have brought about these trends? Changing labor market characteristics in the past couple of decades have had pronounced effects on tenure. For instance, countering the general decreasing tenure trend, women's rising labor force participation beginning in the 1980s undoubtedly contributed to the proportion of 35-to 54-year-olds with ten years of tenure. In the graph, these same women demonstrate their growing attachment to the workforce through their increased expected remaining tenure. Numerous factors have contributed to the decline in job tenure. The composition of payroll employment has shifted to more heavily favor service jobs at manufactur-ing's expense. Because the median tenure for a worker in manufacturing exceeds that …
本文所表达的观点不一定反映联邦储备系统的官方立场。前几代工人从事终身工作。今天的工人不再期望在他们的整个职业生涯中为同一个雇主工作。即使在过去的20年里,美国的预期工作任期也在下降,男女之间的趋势略有不同。工作任期的一些显著趋势及其潜在原因,可能会为未来的就业前景提供一些见解。Friedberg和Owyang(2002)使用来自消费者财务调查(SCF)的数据来发现工作任期趋势。根据SCF的数据,从1983年到1998年,全职男性员工的平均预期剩余任期(员工希望继续为当前雇主工作的时间)从18.6年下降到14.7年。女性员工也有类似的趋势。他们的预期剩余任期从1983年的15.9年开始,最终降至1998年的12.8年。随附的图表显示了这些数字按工人目前工作的经验年数进行了细分。请注意,对于几乎每个子样本,预期剩余任期都减少了。一个有趣的趋势是,在25岁及以上的雇员中,为现在的雇主工作至少10年的比例有所上升。从1983年到2002年,这一群体中男性的总比例下降了近5个百分点,而女性的情况正好相反——她们的比例上升了近4个百分点。所有年龄段的男性都出现了下降,但受影响最大的是40-44岁、45-49岁,尤其是60-64岁的男性。相比之下,35岁至54岁的女性任职10年或更长时间的比例有所增加,但其余年龄组的命运与男性年龄组相同。是什么导致了这些趋势?在过去的几十年里,不断变化的劳动力市场特征对任期产生了明显的影响。例如,与任期普遍减少的趋势相反,从20世纪80年代开始,女性劳动力参与率的上升无疑促进了35至54岁的人拥有10年任期的比例。在图表中,同样是这些女性,通过她们预期的剩余任期增加,表明她们对劳动力的依赖日益增加。许多因素导致了工作任期的缩短。受薪就业的构成已经转向更偏重于服务业工作,牺牲了制造业的利益。因为制造业工人的平均任期超过了这个数字……
{"title":"Your current job probably won't be your last","authors":"Kristie M. Engemann, Michael T. Owyang","doi":"10.20955/ES.2004.5","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.20955/ES.2004.5","url":null,"abstract":"NationalEconomicTrends Views expressed do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System. P revious generations of workers held lifelong jobs. Today's workers no longer expect to work for the same employer for their entire career. Even in the past 20 years, expected job tenure has declined in the United States, with a few differences between the trends for men and women. Some notable trends in job tenure, and their potential causes, may provide some insight into the employment landscape of the future. Friedberg and Owyang (2002) use data from the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) to find job tenure trends. 1 According to the SCF, from 1983 to 1998, average expected remaining tenure—how long a worker expects to continue working for his current employer—for full-time male employees declined from 18.6 to 14.7 years. The trend for female workers is similar. Their expected remaining tenure starts at 15.9 in 1983 and eventually falls to 12.8 years in 1998. 2 The accompanying graph shows these numbers broken down by years of experience at workers' current jobs. Note that for nearly every subsample, expected remaining tenure has decreased. An interesting trend arises with the percentage of employees aged 25 and older who have been with their current employer for at least ten years. The total percentage of men in this group decreased by nearly 5 points from 1983 to 2002, whereas the opposite holds for women— their percentage increased by almost 4 points. All age groups for men saw declines, but those affected most negatively were men aged 40-44, 45-49, and, especially, 60-64. In contrast, the percentage of women aged 35-54 with ten-year tenure or longer increased, but the remaining age groups suffered the same fate as the men's age groups. 3 What could have brought about these trends? Changing labor market characteristics in the past couple of decades have had pronounced effects on tenure. For instance, countering the general decreasing tenure trend, women's rising labor force participation beginning in the 1980s undoubtedly contributed to the proportion of 35-to 54-year-olds with ten years of tenure. In the graph, these same women demonstrate their growing attachment to the workforce through their increased expected remaining tenure. Numerous factors have contributed to the decline in job tenure. The composition of payroll employment has shifted to more heavily favor service jobs at manufactur-ing's expense. Because the median tenure for a worker in manufacturing exceeds that …","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"15 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115520466","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Recent movements in the Baltic Dry Index 波罗的海干散货运价指数近期走势
Pub Date : 1900-01-01 DOI: 10.20955/ES.2009.12
Rajdeep Sengupta, Y. Tam
T he Baltic Dry Index (BDI) is an index published daily by the Baltic Exchange in London, the leading global marketplace for brokering shipping contracts. Exchange members include companies from the international bulk-shipping industry, shipbrokers, freight derivative brokers, trading houses, shipowners, and other cargo interests.1 Every day, the Baltic Exchange asks brokers around the world the cost of booking cargo of various sizes to move raw materials across various ocean routes. The exchange uses this information to compute the BDI—an indicator of maritime transportation costs for major raw materials. The BDI has generated interest as a leading indicator of economic activity because manufacturers increase their demand for raw materials to meet expected increases in the demand for finished products.2 Likewise, a slowdown in economic activity reduces the demand for raw materials when manufacturers detect increases in unsold inventory. The BDI can be viewed as the equilibrium price of shipping raw materials, determined by the supply of cargo ships and the demand for transporting raw materials by ship. First, the supply of cargo ships is inelastic relative to demand because cargo ships are costly and time-consuming to build. In contrast, companies can simply stop booking cargo ships when demand drops. Second, the index is sensitive to changes in the price of crude oil. Fuel and port-related charges are significantly large components of the total cost of maritime shipping.3 Although port-related expenses such as dockage charges are relatively stable, oil prices are notoriously volatile. As a result, the BDI is sensitive to changes in the demand for raw materials and oil price changes. Movements in the BDI can be traced to changes in global demand for manufactured goods. In addition, this demand affects the price of crude oil, which in turn affects the cost of maritime shipping. Between January 2006 and October 2007, the BDI increased more than 400 percent, from 2,081 to 10,656 points (see chart). This steady rise was largely due to the significant growth in the global economy for manufactured products. The growth rate of total industrial production (excluding construction) for member countries of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and six major non-members (Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Russia, and South Africa) was more than 6 percent per annum from March 2006 to October 2007. Movements in this data series closely mirror the (lower) growth rate of industrial production of manufactured goods in the United States. Such high growth rates of industrial production around the world are likely to have also contributed to a surge in crude oil prices, which increased from $67 per barrel to $95 per barrel during the same period, thereby exacerbating the rise in the BDI. Recent Movements in the Baltic Dry Index
波罗的海干散货运价指数(BDI)是由位于伦敦的波罗的海交易所每天发布的一项指数,该交易所是全球领先的航运经纪合同市场。交易所成员包括来自国际散货运输业的公司、船舶经纪人、货运衍生品经纪人、贸易公司、船东和其他货物利益相关者波罗的海交易所(Baltic Exchange)每天都会向世界各地的经纪商询问预订不同尺寸货物、穿越不同海洋航线运送原材料的成本。交易所利用这些信息来计算bdi, bdi是衡量主要原材料海运成本的指标。BDI作为经济活动的领先指标引起了人们的兴趣,因为制造商增加了对原材料的需求,以满足对制成品需求的预期增长同样,当制造商发现未售出库存增加时,经济活动放缓会减少对原材料的需求。BDI可以看作是运输原材料的均衡价格,由货船的供给和运输原材料的需求决定。首先,货船的供应相对于需求缺乏弹性,因为货船的建造成本高昂且耗时。相比之下,当需求下降时,公司可以简单地停止预订货船。其次,该指数对原油价格的变化很敏感。燃料费和与港口有关的费用在海运总费用中占很大一部分虽然码头费等港口相关费用相对稳定,但油价的波动是出了名的。因此,BDI对原材料需求的变化和油价的变化非常敏感。BDI的变动可以追溯到全球制成品需求的变化。此外,这种需求会影响原油价格,进而影响海运成本。从2006年1月到2007年10月,BDI上涨了400%,从2081点涨到10656点(见图表)。这一稳定增长主要是由于全球经济对制成品的需求显著增长。从2006年3月到2007年10月,经济合作与发展组织(OECD)成员国和6个主要非成员国(巴西、中国、印度、印度尼西亚、俄罗斯、南非)的总工业生产(不包括建筑)增长率每年都超过6%。这一系列数据的变动密切反映了美国工业制成品生产(较低)的增长率。全球工业生产的高增长率也可能导致原油价格飙升,在同一时期从每桶67美元上涨到每桶95美元,从而加剧了BDI的上升。波罗的海干散货运价指数近期走势
{"title":"Recent movements in the Baltic Dry Index","authors":"Rajdeep Sengupta, Y. Tam","doi":"10.20955/ES.2009.12","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.20955/ES.2009.12","url":null,"abstract":"T he Baltic Dry Index (BDI) is an index published daily by the Baltic Exchange in London, the leading global marketplace for brokering shipping contracts. Exchange members include companies from the international bulk-shipping industry, shipbrokers, freight derivative brokers, trading houses, shipowners, and other cargo interests.1 Every day, the Baltic Exchange asks brokers around the world the cost of booking cargo of various sizes to move raw materials across various ocean routes. The exchange uses this information to compute the BDI—an indicator of maritime transportation costs for major raw materials. The BDI has generated interest as a leading indicator of economic activity because manufacturers increase their demand for raw materials to meet expected increases in the demand for finished products.2 Likewise, a slowdown in economic activity reduces the demand for raw materials when manufacturers detect increases in unsold inventory. The BDI can be viewed as the equilibrium price of shipping raw materials, determined by the supply of cargo ships and the demand for transporting raw materials by ship. First, the supply of cargo ships is inelastic relative to demand because cargo ships are costly and time-consuming to build. In contrast, companies can simply stop booking cargo ships when demand drops. Second, the index is sensitive to changes in the price of crude oil. Fuel and port-related charges are significantly large components of the total cost of maritime shipping.3 Although port-related expenses such as dockage charges are relatively stable, oil prices are notoriously volatile. As a result, the BDI is sensitive to changes in the demand for raw materials and oil price changes. Movements in the BDI can be traced to changes in global demand for manufactured goods. In addition, this demand affects the price of crude oil, which in turn affects the cost of maritime shipping. Between January 2006 and October 2007, the BDI increased more than 400 percent, from 2,081 to 10,656 points (see chart). This steady rise was largely due to the significant growth in the global economy for manufactured products. The growth rate of total industrial production (excluding construction) for member countries of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and six major non-members (Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Russia, and South Africa) was more than 6 percent per annum from March 2006 to October 2007. Movements in this data series closely mirror the (lower) growth rate of industrial production of manufactured goods in the United States. Such high growth rates of industrial production around the world are likely to have also contributed to a surge in crude oil prices, which increased from $67 per barrel to $95 per barrel during the same period, thereby exacerbating the rise in the BDI. Recent Movements in the Baltic Dry Index","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"4 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123335255","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
A case for oil 支持石油的理由
Pub Date : 1900-01-01 DOI: 10.20955/es.2003.14
R. Anderson, Michelle T. Meisch
Views expressed do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System. A Case for Oil? As economic growth slowed during the first half of 2003, many analysts again focused on increases in the price of oil. In the United States, increases in the price of oil generally have preceded business-cycle downturns since World War II.1 In late February, oil prices were close to $40 as oil supplies were throttled in Venezuela and Nigeria and the world anticipated war in the Middle East. Some analysts feared prices could reach $50 if the war in Iraq bogged down into an urban guerilla conflict or spread to other nearby oil-producing nations. At the same time, nuclear power-supply troubles in Japan and unusually cold weather in the United States boosted demand. Fears of further sharp oil price increases seemed well-founded. An extensive economics literature has explored the various mechanisms whereby higher oil prices affect economic activity.2 One of the more plausible mechanisms operates by means of the postponement effect. In this scenario, increases in the current price of oil increase uncertainty about future oil prices which, in turn, causes households and businesses to postpone purchases of durable goods and equipment. Unraveling the economy’s recent performance depends, at least in part, on understanding the extent to which businesses and consumers believed that this year’s oil price increases would be reversed in the near future. If this belief was widely held, then oil prices might have affected business and consumer spending very little— and the economy’s slow growth might have been signaling broader underlying weakness. It seems plausible that many firms and households judged world events during 2002-03 by comparing them to those that surrounded the first Gulf War. Looking back, oil price movements during 2002-03 in fact were quite similar to those during the 1990-91 Iraqi invasion of Kuwait and subsequent Gulf War, albeit with somewhat different timing. The figure shows the spot price for benchmark Texas-type light, sweet crude oil before and after the peak price observed during each period. (We aligned the prices based on the peak price because of the differing timing of events.) In 1990, prices peaked after the Kuwait invasion but well before the beginning of the American liberation of Kuwait. In 2003, similarly, prices rose sharply during the military buildup, when uncertainty regarding war was high, and then decreased after the degree of uncertainty was reduced by the American entry into Iraq. During both episodes, oil futures prices (not shown) moved in similar patterns; indeed, even during 2003, futures prices generally remained below the spot price, suggesting that the price run-up would be short-lived. The similarity of oil price movements during 1990-91 and 2002-03 suggests that the slow pace of economic activity during this year’s first-half should not be attributed to higher oil prices. It also suggests that the re
本文所表达的观点不一定反映联邦储备系统的官方立场。支持石油?随着2003年上半年经济增长放缓,许多分析师再次关注油价上涨。在美国,自第二次世界大战以来,石油价格的上涨通常在商业周期衰退之前出现。2月下旬,由于委内瑞拉和尼日利亚的石油供应受到限制,以及世界预期的中东战争,油价接近40美元。一些分析师担心,如果伊拉克战争陷入城市游击战的泥潭,或者蔓延到附近的其他产油国,油价可能会升至50美元。与此同时,日本的核电供应问题和美国异常寒冷的天气刺激了需求。对油价进一步大幅上涨的担忧似乎是有根据的。大量的经济学文献探讨了高油价影响经济活动的各种机制一种比较合理的机制是通过延迟效应来运作的。在这种情况下,当前油价的上涨增加了未来油价的不确定性,进而导致家庭和企业推迟购买耐用品和设备。解读经济近期的表现,至少在一定程度上取决于企业和消费者在多大程度上相信今年的油价上涨将在不久的将来逆转。如果人们普遍持有这种观点,那么油价对企业和消费者支出的影响可能很小,而经济的缓慢增长可能预示着更广泛的潜在疲软。许多公司和家庭通过与第一次海湾战争前后的事件进行比较来判断2002-03年的世界事件,这似乎是合理的。回顾过去,2002年至2003年期间的油价走势实际上与1990年至1991年伊拉克入侵科威特以及随后的海湾战争期间非常相似,尽管时间有所不同。该图显示了在每个时间段观察到的峰值价格前后的基准德克萨斯轻质低硫原油现货价格。(由于事件发生的时间不同,我们根据峰值价格调整了价格。)1990年,油价在入侵科威特之后达到顶峰,但远在美国解放科威特之前。同样,2003年,在军事集结期间,价格急剧上涨,当时战争的不确定性很高,然后在美国进入伊拉克后不确定性程度降低后价格下降。在这两次事件中,石油期货价格(未显示)以相似的模式波动;事实上,即使在2003年,期货价格也普遍低于现货价格,这表明价格上涨将是短暂的。1990-91年和2002-03年期间油价走势的相似性表明,今年上半年经济活动放缓不应归咎于油价上涨。它还表明,最近油价回落至更正常的水平,可能只会对今年晚些时候的经济增长起到小小的推动作用。
{"title":"A case for oil","authors":"R. Anderson, Michelle T. Meisch","doi":"10.20955/es.2003.14","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.20955/es.2003.14","url":null,"abstract":"Views expressed do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System. A Case for Oil? As economic growth slowed during the first half of 2003, many analysts again focused on increases in the price of oil. In the United States, increases in the price of oil generally have preceded business-cycle downturns since World War II.1 In late February, oil prices were close to $40 as oil supplies were throttled in Venezuela and Nigeria and the world anticipated war in the Middle East. Some analysts feared prices could reach $50 if the war in Iraq bogged down into an urban guerilla conflict or spread to other nearby oil-producing nations. At the same time, nuclear power-supply troubles in Japan and unusually cold weather in the United States boosted demand. Fears of further sharp oil price increases seemed well-founded. An extensive economics literature has explored the various mechanisms whereby higher oil prices affect economic activity.2 One of the more plausible mechanisms operates by means of the postponement effect. In this scenario, increases in the current price of oil increase uncertainty about future oil prices which, in turn, causes households and businesses to postpone purchases of durable goods and equipment. Unraveling the economy’s recent performance depends, at least in part, on understanding the extent to which businesses and consumers believed that this year’s oil price increases would be reversed in the near future. If this belief was widely held, then oil prices might have affected business and consumer spending very little— and the economy’s slow growth might have been signaling broader underlying weakness. It seems plausible that many firms and households judged world events during 2002-03 by comparing them to those that surrounded the first Gulf War. Looking back, oil price movements during 2002-03 in fact were quite similar to those during the 1990-91 Iraqi invasion of Kuwait and subsequent Gulf War, albeit with somewhat different timing. The figure shows the spot price for benchmark Texas-type light, sweet crude oil before and after the peak price observed during each period. (We aligned the prices based on the peak price because of the differing timing of events.) In 1990, prices peaked after the Kuwait invasion but well before the beginning of the American liberation of Kuwait. In 2003, similarly, prices rose sharply during the military buildup, when uncertainty regarding war was high, and then decreased after the degree of uncertainty was reduced by the American entry into Iraq. During both episodes, oil futures prices (not shown) moved in similar patterns; indeed, even during 2003, futures prices generally remained below the spot price, suggesting that the price run-up would be short-lived. The similarity of oil price movements during 1990-91 and 2002-03 suggests that the slow pace of economic activity during this year’s first-half should not be attributed to higher oil prices. It also suggests that the re","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"103 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115379170","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Was the recent economic downturn a recession 最近的经济衰退是经济衰退吗
Pub Date : 1900-01-01 DOI: 10.20955/es.2002.20
Jeremy Piger
L ate last year, the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) announced that the U.S. economy entered a recession in March 2001. Some have questioned whether the recent downturn really qualifies as a recession, as by some measures it has been quite mild. For example, the broadest measure of the economy’s output, real gross domestic prod uct (GDP), experienced only a modest decline in the current recession. However, given that more timely measures of economic activity are available, the NBER gives relatively little weight to GDP in determining recession dates. Instead, the NBER defines a recession as a “significant decline in activity spread across the economy, lasting more than a few months, visible in industrial production, employ ment, real income, and wholesale-retail sales.”1 To investigate whether the recent economic downturn meets this definition, I use past recessions as a yardstick. The table details the significance and length of decline in the four variables included in the NBER recession definition for each recession over the past 40 years. Signi fi cance is measured by the percentage decline in each variable from its individual peak to its individual trough. This is computed by finding the lowest point each variable reached during or a year following the recession (called the trough) and subtracting this value from the highest point the variable reached in the past (called the peak). Beside this statistic, in parentheses, is the time in months between individual peak and trough for each series, a mea sure of the length of the decline. The statistics for the current recession assume the troughs have been reached for all of these variables. The table shows that both employment and industrial production have experienced significant and lengthy declines in the current recession; the magnitudes of the declines are similar to those observed in several past recessions and lasted for 13 and 18 months, respectively, longer than the average of the previous recessions. The employment decline is of particular interest, as the NBER gives extra emphasis to employment movements in determining recession dates. The decline in sales during the current recession has been notably mild relative to previous recessions, dropping less than half as much as in the 1990-91 recession. Nevertheless, such a protracted sales decline has never occurred within any expansion. In the sample period considered here, there have been only three months not related to an NBER recession in which sales had declined 2.4 percent below their prior peak, the level reached in the current recession. In all three cases these episodes lasted just one month, with sales bouncing back above their peak in the following month. By contrast, sales in the current recession remained below their peak for 10 consecutive months before the trough was reached, suggesting the recent sales data have more in common with past recessions than past expansions. Finally, as in the 1960-61 and 1969-70 re
去年年底,美国国家经济研究局(NBER)发表说,美国经济已于2001年3月进入衰退。一些人质疑最近的经济衰退是否真的符合经济衰退的标准,因为从某些方面来看,经济衰退相当温和。例如,衡量经济产出的最广泛指标——实际国内生产总值(GDP),在当前的衰退中只出现了轻微的下降。然而,鉴于有更及时的经济活动衡量指标,NBER在确定衰退日期时对GDP的权重相对较小。相反,NBER将经济衰退定义为“整个经济活动的显著下降,持续几个月以上,可见于工业生产、就业、实际收入和批发零售销售。”为了调查最近的经济衰退是否符合这一定义,我用过去的衰退作为衡量标准。该表详细说明了在过去40年中,NBER衰退定义中包含的四个变量的衰退的重要性和持续时间。显著性是通过每个变量从其个别峰值到个别低谷的百分比下降来衡量的。这是通过找出每个变量在衰退期间或之后一年内达到的最低点(称为低谷),并从该变量过去达到的最高点(称为峰值)中减去该值来计算的。在这个统计数据旁边,括号内是每个系列的个别峰值和低谷之间的月间隔时间,这意味着下降的长度。当前经济衰退的统计数据假设所有这些变量都已触底。该表显示,在当前的经济衰退中,就业和工业生产都经历了显著而漫长的下降;这次衰退的幅度与过去几次衰退中观察到的相似,分别持续了13个月和18个月,比之前几次衰退的平均时间要长。就业下降尤其令人感兴趣,因为NBER在确定衰退日期时特别强调了就业变动。与之前的经济衰退相比,当前经济衰退期间的销售下滑明显温和,降幅不到1990-91年衰退时的一半。然而,如此长期的销售下滑从未在任何扩张中发生过。在这里考虑的样本期内,只有三个月与NBER衰退无关,其中销售额比之前的峰值(当前衰退中达到的水平)下降了2.4%。在这三种情况下,这种情况只持续了一个月,销量在接下来的一个月反弹至峰值以上。相比之下,在本轮衰退中,销售在触底前连续10个月低于峰值水平,这表明近期销售数据与以往的衰退有更多共同点,而非以往的扩张。最后,与1960年至1961年和1969年至1970年的衰退一样,本次衰退期间个人收入没有出现持续下降。最近的经济衰退是经济衰退吗?这一证据表明,与以往的衰退相比,这次的衰退确实符合标准。2002年6月7日,国家经济研究局的商业周期测定程序。nber.org/cycles/recessions.html。最近的经济低迷是经济衰退吗?
{"title":"Was the recent economic downturn a recession","authors":"Jeremy Piger","doi":"10.20955/es.2002.20","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.20955/es.2002.20","url":null,"abstract":"L ate last year, the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) announced that the U.S. economy entered a recession in March 2001. Some have questioned whether the recent downturn really qualifies as a recession, as by some measures it has been quite mild. For example, the broadest measure of the economy’s output, real gross domestic prod uct (GDP), experienced only a modest decline in the current recession. However, given that more timely measures of economic activity are available, the NBER gives relatively little weight to GDP in determining recession dates. Instead, the NBER defines a recession as a “significant decline in activity spread across the economy, lasting more than a few months, visible in industrial production, employ ment, real income, and wholesale-retail sales.”1 To investigate whether the recent economic downturn meets this definition, I use past recessions as a yardstick. The table details the significance and length of decline in the four variables included in the NBER recession definition for each recession over the past 40 years. Signi fi cance is measured by the percentage decline in each variable from its individual peak to its individual trough. This is computed by finding the lowest point each variable reached during or a year following the recession (called the trough) and subtracting this value from the highest point the variable reached in the past (called the peak). Beside this statistic, in parentheses, is the time in months between individual peak and trough for each series, a mea sure of the length of the decline. The statistics for the current recession assume the troughs have been reached for all of these variables. The table shows that both employment and industrial production have experienced significant and lengthy declines in the current recession; the magnitudes of the declines are similar to those observed in several past recessions and lasted for 13 and 18 months, respectively, longer than the average of the previous recessions. The employment decline is of particular interest, as the NBER gives extra emphasis to employment movements in determining recession dates. The decline in sales during the current recession has been notably mild relative to previous recessions, dropping less than half as much as in the 1990-91 recession. Nevertheless, such a protracted sales decline has never occurred within any expansion. In the sample period considered here, there have been only three months not related to an NBER recession in which sales had declined 2.4 percent below their prior peak, the level reached in the current recession. In all three cases these episodes lasted just one month, with sales bouncing back above their peak in the following month. By contrast, sales in the current recession remained below their peak for 10 consecutive months before the trough was reached, suggesting the recent sales data have more in common with past recessions than past expansions. Finally, as in the 1960-61 and 1969-70 re","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"68 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128933126","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Look who's working now 看看现在是谁在工作
Pub Date : 1900-01-01 DOI: 10.20955/ES.2006.9
Kristie M. Engemann, Michael T. Owyang
{"title":"Look who's working now","authors":"Kristie M. Engemann, Michael T. Owyang","doi":"10.20955/ES.2006.9","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.20955/ES.2006.9","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"11 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125319697","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Japanese deflation loses something in the translation 日本的通货紧缩在翻译中失去了一些东西
Pub Date : 1900-01-01 DOI: 10.20955/es.2003.22
James Bullard, John Seiffertt
{"title":"Japanese deflation loses something in the translation","authors":"James Bullard, John Seiffertt","doi":"10.20955/es.2003.22","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.20955/es.2003.22","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"6 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122750281","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Are two employment surveys better than one 两份就业调查比一份好吗
Pub Date : 1900-01-01 DOI: 10.20955/ES.2006.27
Kevin L. Kliesen
Economic analysts and policymakers pay a great deal of attention to employment data. The Bureau of Labor Statistics’ monthly employment report is often taken as a key early indicator of aggregate economic activity. Moreover, the National Bureau of Economic Research’s business cycle dating committee uses employment to help determine business cycle peaks and troughs. Thus, changes in employment can reflect the economy’s evolving strength or weakness over the near-term. (Over longer periods, the change in employment depends more on trend growth of labor productivity and labor force participation rates.) When using employment to predict near-term economic growth, analysts must choose which employment survey to use. The Bureau of Labor Statistics presents two measures of employment: one from the Current Population Survey (CPS), with about 60,000 households; the other from the Current Employment Statistics (CES), with about 400,000 establishments, which cover about a third of all nonfarm payroll workers. Although the household and establishment measures of employment differ considerably, they tend to show similar growth trends over longer periods of time.1 The two series had been moving in two distinct patterns: From January 1994 to March 2001, the establishment survey averaged about 233,000 additional jobs per month, while the household survey averaged only about 184,000 per month. But, since the recession trough in November 2001, the opposite has occurred—household employment has increased more, by an average of about 148,000 per month, while payroll employment has increased by only 82,000 per month. So, should analysts continue to rely more on the payroll survey or put more weight on the household survey? The table shows simple correlations between the growth of two measures of economic activity—industrial production and real GDP—and three measures of labor input: the CES, the CPS, and the average of the two surveys over three separate periods. The 1994 breakpoint is chosen because the CPS was changed in several important ways; the 2001 break point was chosen because it is the peak of the 1991-2001 expansion. The table shows that the correlation between employment growth and industrial production is generally stronger than between employment and real GDP. Second, from 1950 to 1993, the correlation between the growth of payroll employment and real output was larger than the correlation between the growth of household employment and output; this is consistent with the conventional wisdom noted earlier. Third, the correlation between output growth and either measure of employment growth was much weaker during the 1990s, possibly due to the increase in the trend growth of labor productivity and the sharp rise in stock prices. For the most recent period, the CPS is more highly correlated with industrial production growth (0.77) than is the CES (0.67). An interesting finding is that, since 2001, the correlation between the growth of the combined CES and C
经济分析师和政策制定者非常关注就业数据。美国劳工统计局(Bureau of Labor Statistics)的月度就业报告通常被视为总体经济活动的关键早期指标。此外,美国国家经济研究局(National Bureau of Economic Research)的商业周期确定委员会利用就业情况来帮助确定商业周期的高峰和低谷。因此,就业的变化可以反映经济在短期内的强弱变化。(在较长时期内,就业的变化更多地取决于劳动生产率和劳动力参与率的趋势增长。)当使用就业预测近期经济增长时,分析师必须选择使用哪种就业调查。美国劳工统计局(Bureau of Labor Statistics)提供了两种就业衡量标准:一种来自当前人口调查(CPS),涉及约6万户家庭;另一个来自当前就业统计(CES),大约有40万家企业,覆盖了大约三分之一的非农业就业人员。虽然家庭和企业的就业指标差别很大,但它们往往在较长时期内显示出类似的增长趋势从1994年1月到2001年3月,机构调查平均每月增加约23.3万个工作岗位,而住户调查平均每月仅增加约18.4万个工作岗位。但是,自2001年11月经济衰退达到低谷以来,情况正好相反——家庭就业人数增加得更多,平均每月增加约14.8万人,而工资单就业人数每月只增加8.2万人。那么,分析师应该继续更多地依赖于就业调查,还是更看重家庭调查?该表显示了两种衡量经济活动的指标——工业生产和实际gdp——和三种衡量劳动力投入的指标——消费消费指数(CES)、CPS,以及三个独立时期两次调查的平均值之间的简单相关性。之所以选择1994年的断点,是因为CPS在几个重要方面发生了变化;之所以选择2001年这个断点,是因为它是1991-2001年经济扩张的峰值。该表显示,就业增长与工业生产之间的相关性通常强于就业与实际GDP之间的相关性。第二,从1950年到1993年,工资单就业增长与实际产出之间的相关性大于家庭就业增长与产出之间的相关性;这与前面提到的传统智慧是一致的。第三,在20世纪90年代,产出增长与就业增长之间的相关性要弱得多,这可能是由于劳动生产率趋势增长的增加和股票价格的急剧上涨。在最近的一段时间里,CPS与工业生产增长的相关性(0.77)比CES(0.67)更高。一个有趣的发现是,自2001年以来,综合CES和CPS措施的增长与实际GDP之间的相关性大于单独的机构或家庭措施之间的相关性,这与最近的结果一致因此,经济分析师可能希望使用工资和家庭调查的平均值来衡量潜在的就业趋势,从而衡量近期实际GDP增长的趋势。这些相关性的变化可能是由个体经营的相对增长引起的,这在CPS中被计算,而在CES中没有被计算。从1994年1月到2001年11月,个体经营下降了1.6%。然而,自2001年11月以来,个体经营者增加了9.3%,达到约950万人;与此同时,家庭总就业人数只增加了6.3%。如果这种趋势继续下去,经济分析人士可能需要更密切地关注住户调查。
{"title":"Are two employment surveys better than one","authors":"Kevin L. Kliesen","doi":"10.20955/ES.2006.27","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.20955/ES.2006.27","url":null,"abstract":"Economic analysts and policymakers pay a great deal of attention to employment data. The Bureau of Labor Statistics’ monthly employment report is often taken as a key early indicator of aggregate economic activity. Moreover, the National Bureau of Economic Research’s business cycle dating committee uses employment to help determine business cycle peaks and troughs. Thus, changes in employment can reflect the economy’s evolving strength or weakness over the near-term. (Over longer periods, the change in employment depends more on trend growth of labor productivity and labor force participation rates.) When using employment to predict near-term economic growth, analysts must choose which employment survey to use. The Bureau of Labor Statistics presents two measures of employment: one from the Current Population Survey (CPS), with about 60,000 households; the other from the Current Employment Statistics (CES), with about 400,000 establishments, which cover about a third of all nonfarm payroll workers. Although the household and establishment measures of employment differ considerably, they tend to show similar growth trends over longer periods of time.1 The two series had been moving in two distinct patterns: From January 1994 to March 2001, the establishment survey averaged about 233,000 additional jobs per month, while the household survey averaged only about 184,000 per month. But, since the recession trough in November 2001, the opposite has occurred—household employment has increased more, by an average of about 148,000 per month, while payroll employment has increased by only 82,000 per month. So, should analysts continue to rely more on the payroll survey or put more weight on the household survey? The table shows simple correlations between the growth of two measures of economic activity—industrial production and real GDP—and three measures of labor input: the CES, the CPS, and the average of the two surveys over three separate periods. The 1994 breakpoint is chosen because the CPS was changed in several important ways; the 2001 break point was chosen because it is the peak of the 1991-2001 expansion. The table shows that the correlation between employment growth and industrial production is generally stronger than between employment and real GDP. Second, from 1950 to 1993, the correlation between the growth of payroll employment and real output was larger than the correlation between the growth of household employment and output; this is consistent with the conventional wisdom noted earlier. Third, the correlation between output growth and either measure of employment growth was much weaker during the 1990s, possibly due to the increase in the trend growth of labor productivity and the sharp rise in stock prices. For the most recent period, the CPS is more highly correlated with industrial production growth (0.77) than is the CES (0.67). An interesting finding is that, since 2001, the correlation between the growth of the combined CES and C","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"209 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126321791","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
How much have U.S. house prices fallen 美国房价下跌了多少
Pub Date : 1900-01-01 DOI: 10.20955/ES.2008.20
C. Aubuchon, David C. Wheelock
Views expressed do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System. House prices in the United States were 14.1 percent lower in the first quarter of 2008 than they were a year earlier, according to a widely cited measure of U.S. house prices, the SP it also showed a more rapid decline in house prices during 2007-08. The OFHEO index tracks the sales prices of houses financed with conforming, conventional mortgages purchased by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. In 2007, conforming loans were limited to a maximum of $417,000. Home purchases involving larger, “jumbo” mortgages, or unconventional mortgages— including many subprime mortgages—do not influence the OFHEO index. By contrast, the SP it includes data on houses financed by jumbo mortgages, subprime mortgages, and home purchases that do not involve a mortgage. The S&P/CS index is also value weighted: More expensive homes have relatively greater influence on the index, whereas the OFHEO index is unit weighted. Further more, the S&P/CS index assigns greater weight to census regions with greater total residential real estate value. The OFHEO index, by contrast, weights regions based on the number of residential units. Hence, regions with relatively higher average home prices have more influence on the S&P/CS index than on the OFHEO index.1 The S&P/CS index exhibited faster growth in house prices before 2006 because house prices rose more rapidly in the regions with more influence on that index. These regions also tended to have a higher percentage of transactions involving mortgages ineligible for purchase by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. The relatively rapid decline in house prices since 2006 in the West and East Coast regions, and the relatively greater weight given these regions in the S&P/CS index help explain why the S&P/CS index shows a more rapid decline in house prices for the United States as a whole.
本文所表达的观点不一定反映联邦储备系统的官方立场。根据一项被广泛引用的美国房价指标,2008年第一季美国房价较上年同期下跌14.1%。该指标还显示,2007-08年期间房价下跌速度加快。OFHEO指数追踪的是房利美和房地美购买的符合标准的传统抵押贷款融资房屋的销售价格。2007年,符合标准的贷款上限为41.7万美元。涉及较大的“巨额”抵押贷款或非常规抵押贷款(包括许多次级抵押贷款)的住房购买不影响OFHEO指数。相比之下,标准普尔指数包含了巨额抵押贷款、次级抵押贷款和不涉及抵押贷款的购房数据。S&P/CS指数也是价值加权的:更昂贵的房屋对指数的影响相对更大,而OFHEO指数是单位加权的。此外,S&P/CS指数赋予住宅房地产总价值较大的人口普查地区更大的权重。相比之下,OFHEO的指数是根据住宅单位数量对地区进行加权。因此,平均房价相对较高的地区对S&P/CS指数的影响大于对OFHEO指数的影响S&P/CS指数显示,2006年之前房价增长更快,因为对该指数影响更大的地区房价上涨更快。这些地区也往往有更高比例的交易涉及不符合房利美和房地美购买条件的抵押贷款。自2006年以来,西海岸和东海岸地区房价的相对快速下跌,以及这些地区在标普/CS指数中相对较大的权重,有助于解释为什么标普/CS指数显示美国整体房价下跌得更快。
{"title":"How much have U.S. house prices fallen","authors":"C. Aubuchon, David C. Wheelock","doi":"10.20955/ES.2008.20","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.20955/ES.2008.20","url":null,"abstract":"Views expressed do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System. House prices in the United States were 14.1 percent lower in the first quarter of 2008 than they were a year earlier, according to a widely cited measure of U.S. house prices, the SP it also showed a more rapid decline in house prices during 2007-08. The OFHEO index tracks the sales prices of houses financed with conforming, conventional mortgages purchased by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. In 2007, conforming loans were limited to a maximum of $417,000. Home purchases involving larger, “jumbo” mortgages, or unconventional mortgages— including many subprime mortgages—do not influence the OFHEO index. By contrast, the SP it includes data on houses financed by jumbo mortgages, subprime mortgages, and home purchases that do not involve a mortgage. The S&P/CS index is also value weighted: More expensive homes have relatively greater influence on the index, whereas the OFHEO index is unit weighted. Further more, the S&P/CS index assigns greater weight to census regions with greater total residential real estate value. The OFHEO index, by contrast, weights regions based on the number of residential units. Hence, regions with relatively higher average home prices have more influence on the S&P/CS index than on the OFHEO index.1 The S&P/CS index exhibited faster growth in house prices before 2006 because house prices rose more rapidly in the regions with more influence on that index. These regions also tended to have a higher percentage of transactions involving mortgages ineligible for purchase by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. The relatively rapid decline in house prices since 2006 in the West and East Coast regions, and the relatively greater weight given these regions in the S&P/CS index help explain why the S&P/CS index shows a more rapid decline in house prices for the United States as a whole.","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"97 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127386425","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
期刊
National Economic Trends
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1