首页 > 最新文献

Washington University in St. Louis School of Law Legal Studies Research Paper Series最新文献

英文 中文
Unbelievable: ERISA's Broken Promise [ver. 4.0; August 2021] 难以置信:ERISA的破碎的承诺。4.0;2021年8月)
Peter J. Wiedenbeck
A central but generally neglected objective of federal regulation of pension and welfare benefit plans was to improve overall economic efficiency by providing workers with accessible and reliable information on which to base their career and financial planning. Simple dissemination of plan terms and financial data (full disclosure) cannot achieve that objective because few workers are equipped with the skills needed to evaluate the costs and benefits of complex retirement saving or health care programs. For that reason ERISA, the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974, requires curated disclosure of plan-related information: it must be presented a format that is both understandable to the average plan participant and sufficiently complete to empower workers to make best use of the program. The length and complexity of most employee benefit plans creates tension between understandability and completeness, calling for tradeoffs to achieve optimal disclosure. As implemented ERISA’s understandability standard has been jettisoned by plan sponsors seeking protection from liability for failing to tell workers enough. Required plan summaries became unreadable, but plan sponsors could get away with that, both because there was no administrative or judicial enforcement of the understandability standard, and because they could tout the advantages of their benefit plans to workers by means of unregulated informal communications. The demise of understandability is only half the story. Federal courts also degraded the reliability of mandatory disclosures by finding that the obligation to provide reasonably accurate and complete information is enforceable only in a suit for appropriate equitable relief. In consequence, disclosure defects are often presented as estoppel claims, which triggers search for individual detrimental reliance, and translates into widespread under-enforcement of the reliability standard. This article explores the policy dimension of ERISA disclosure law and chronicles the decay of the equilibrium Congress envisioned. From the perspective of workers it is a saga of disappointment, disillusionment, and defeat. The new balance serves the interests of federal courts (reduced caseload) and some employers (increased flexibility), but likely contributes to the increasing standardization of employee benefit plans, decreasing their utility as instruments of workforce management. Far worse, it abandons ERISA’s goal of improved economic performance through better-informed career and financial planning. Yet those costs are not immutable: employers’ liability exposure could be recalibrated by regulation to revive understandability and approach optimal disclosure.
联邦管理养恤金和福利计划的一个中心但通常被忽视的目标是通过向工人提供可获得和可靠的信息来提高总体经济效率,以便他们根据这些信息进行职业和财务规划。简单地传播计划条款和财务数据(全面披露)无法实现这一目标,因为很少有工人具备评估复杂的退休储蓄或医疗保健计划的成本和收益所需的技能。因此,1974年颁布的《雇员退休收入保障法》(ERISA)要求有计划地披露与计划相关的信息:它必须以一种既能让普通计划参与者理解,又能让员工充分利用该计划的格式呈现。大多数员工福利计划的长度和复杂性造成了可理解性和完整性之间的紧张关系,要求权衡以实现最佳披露。由于ERISA的可理解性标准已被计划发起人抛弃,他们寻求保护,以免因未能充分告知工人而承担责任。要求的计划摘要变得难以读懂,但计划发起人可以摆脱这种情况,一方面是因为没有行政或司法强制执行可理解性标准,另一方面是因为他们可以通过不受监管的非正式沟通向工人兜售他们的福利计划的优势。可理解性的消亡只是故事的一半。联邦法院还裁定,提供合理准确和完整的信息的义务只有在要求适当衡平法上的救济的诉讼中才能强制执行,从而降低了强制性披露的可靠性。因此,披露缺陷通常以禁止反悔的形式提出,这引发了对个人有害依赖的搜索,并转化为可靠性标准的普遍执行不足。本文探讨了ERISA披露法的政策维度,并记录了国会所设想的平衡的衰落。从工人的角度来看,这是一个充满失望、幻灭和失败的传奇。新的平衡服务于联邦法院(减少案件量)和一些雇主(增加灵活性)的利益,但可能有助于员工福利计划的日益标准化,降低其作为劳动力管理工具的效用。更糟糕的是,它放弃了ERISA的目标,即通过更明智的职业和财务规划来改善经济表现。然而,这些成本并非不可改变:监管机构可以重新调整雇主的责任敞口,以恢复可理解性,并接近最佳披露。
{"title":"Unbelievable: ERISA's Broken Promise [ver. 4.0; August 2021]","authors":"Peter J. Wiedenbeck","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3900735","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3900735","url":null,"abstract":"A central but generally neglected objective of federal regulation of pension and welfare benefit plans was to improve overall economic efficiency by providing workers with accessible and reliable information on which to base their career and financial planning. Simple dissemination of plan terms and financial data (full disclosure) cannot achieve that objective because few workers are equipped with the skills needed to evaluate the costs and benefits of complex retirement saving or health care programs. For that reason ERISA, the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974, requires curated disclosure of plan-related information: it must be presented a format that is both understandable to the average plan participant and sufficiently complete to empower workers to make best use of the program. The length and complexity of most employee benefit plans creates tension between understandability and completeness, calling for tradeoffs to achieve optimal disclosure. As implemented ERISA’s understandability standard has been jettisoned by plan sponsors seeking protection from liability for failing to tell workers enough. Required plan summaries became unreadable, but plan sponsors could get away with that, both because there was no administrative or judicial enforcement of the understandability standard, and because they could tout the advantages of their benefit plans to workers by means of unregulated informal communications. The demise of understandability is only half the story. Federal courts also degraded the reliability of mandatory disclosures by finding that the obligation to provide reasonably accurate and complete information is enforceable only in a suit for appropriate equitable relief. In consequence, disclosure defects are often presented as estoppel claims, which triggers search for individual detrimental reliance, and translates into widespread under-enforcement of the reliability standard. This article explores the policy dimension of ERISA disclosure law and chronicles the decay of the equilibrium Congress envisioned. From the perspective of workers it is a saga of disappointment, disillusionment, and defeat. The new balance serves the interests of federal courts (reduced caseload) and some employers (increased flexibility), but likely contributes to the increasing standardization of employee benefit plans, decreasing their utility as instruments of workforce management. Far worse, it abandons ERISA’s goal of improved economic performance through better-informed career and financial planning. Yet those costs are not immutable: employers’ liability exposure could be recalibrated by regulation to revive understandability and approach optimal disclosure.","PeriodicalId":344149,"journal":{"name":"Washington University in St. Louis School of Law Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"41 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-08-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125174370","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Information-Forcing Dilemma in Damages Law 损害赔偿法中的信息强制困境
Tun-Jen Chiang
Courts assessing compensatory damages awards often lack adequate information to determine the value of a victim’s loss. A central reason for this problem, which the literature has thus far overlooked, is that courts face a dilemma when applying their standard information-forcing tool to the context of damages. Specifically, the standard method by which courts obtain information is through a burden of proof. In the context of assessing damages, this means a rule requiring plaintiffs to prove the value of a loss with precision. But courts will often face a situation where it is clear that the plaintiff has suffered a loss, but where the plaintiff cannot prove the exact amount of the loss. A court that strictly enforces the burden of proof would award zero damages in such a case, producing a harsh result. But a court that avoids this result by instead awarding its best guess at the correct amount — effectively forgiving the inadequacy of plaintiff’s proof — then undermines future incentives for plaintiffs to produce rigorous evidence.The result of this dilemma is that courts oscillate between strict and forgiving approaches, causing much confusion. Explaining the dilemma helps alleviate the confusion and points to a solution. In principle, courts should require a party to produce damages evidence if, and only if, the party is the lower cost provider of that evidence, and the benefit of having the evidence outweighs the cost of collecting it. The messy legal standards for calculating damages in various fields can be understood as clumsy attempts by courts to arrive at this unifying principle. Interpreting the vague and messy doctrine in light of this “cheaper cost-effective producer” principle thus helps make damages law more coherent.
评估补偿性损害赔偿的法院往往缺乏足够的信息来确定受害者损失的价值。造成这一问题的一个核心原因是,法院在将其标准的信息强制工具应用于损害赔偿时面临两难境地,而这一问题迄今为止一直被文献所忽视。具体来说,法院获取信息的标准方法是通过举证责任。在评估损害赔偿的背景下,这意味着一条规则要求原告准确地证明损失的价值。但是,法院经常会遇到这样的情况:原告显然遭受了损失,但原告无法证明损失的确切数额。在这种情况下,严格执行举证责任的法院会判零损害赔偿,从而产生严厉的结果。但是,如果法院避免了这一结果,而是在正确的数额上给予最佳猜测——实际上是原谅了原告证据的不足——那么就会削弱原告未来提供严格证据的动力。这种困境的结果是法院在严格和宽容的方法之间摇摆不定,造成了很多混乱。解释这种困境有助于减轻困惑,并指出解决办法。原则上,法院应要求一方提供损害证据,当且仅当该方提供证据的成本较低,且获得证据的利益超过收集证据的成本。在不同领域计算损害赔偿的法律标准混乱不堪,这可以理解为法院试图达成统一原则的笨拙尝试。因此,根据这种“成本更低、成本更低的生产者”原则来解释模糊而混乱的原则,有助于使损害赔偿法更加连贯。
{"title":"The Information-Forcing Dilemma in Damages Law","authors":"Tun-Jen Chiang","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2829179","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2829179","url":null,"abstract":"Courts assessing compensatory damages awards often lack adequate information to determine the value of a victim’s loss. A central reason for this problem, which the literature has thus far overlooked, is that courts face a dilemma when applying their standard information-forcing tool to the context of damages. Specifically, the standard method by which courts obtain information is through a burden of proof. In the context of assessing damages, this means a rule requiring plaintiffs to prove the value of a loss with precision. But courts will often face a situation where it is clear that the plaintiff has suffered a loss, but where the plaintiff cannot prove the exact amount of the loss. A court that strictly enforces the burden of proof would award zero damages in such a case, producing a harsh result. But a court that avoids this result by instead awarding its best guess at the correct amount — effectively forgiving the inadequacy of plaintiff’s proof — then undermines future incentives for plaintiffs to produce rigorous evidence.The result of this dilemma is that courts oscillate between strict and forgiving approaches, causing much confusion. Explaining the dilemma helps alleviate the confusion and points to a solution. In principle, courts should require a party to produce damages evidence if, and only if, the party is the lower cost provider of that evidence, and the benefit of having the evidence outweighs the cost of collecting it. The messy legal standards for calculating damages in various fields can be understood as clumsy attempts by courts to arrive at this unifying principle. Interpreting the vague and messy doctrine in light of this “cheaper cost-effective producer” principle thus helps make damages law more coherent.","PeriodicalId":344149,"journal":{"name":"Washington University in St. Louis School of Law Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"34 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-08-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133338788","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 16
The Failure of Crits and Leftist Law Professors to Defend Progressive Causes 批评人士和左派法学教授捍卫进步事业的失败
B. Tamanaha
Future generations will look back at the first decade of the twenty-first century as a pivotal time when a huge economic barrier was erected to encumber the path to a legal career. The symbolic announcement of this barrier rang out when annual tuition crossed the $50,000 threshold, now exceeded at a dozen or so law schools. Including fees and living expenses, it costs well in excess of $200,000 to obtain a law degree at most of the nation’s highly regarded law schools and at a number of non-elite ones as well. Law schools thus impose a formidable entry fee on anyone who wishes to follow what, until recently, has long served as a means of upward mobility and access to power in American society. The pricing structure of legal education has profound class implications. High tuition will inhibit people from middle-class and poor families more than it will deter the offspring of the rich with ample resources. Law school scholarship policies, for reasons I will explain, in effect channel students with financial means to higher ranked law schools, reaping better opportunities, while sending students without money to lower law schools. A growing proportion of elite legal positions will be held by people from wealthy backgrounds as a result. For students who rely on borrowing to finance their legal education, the heavy debt they carry will dictate the types of jobs they seek and constrain the career they go on to have. Liberal law professors often express concerns about class in American society — championing access to the legal profession and the provision of legal services for underserved communities. Yet as law school tuition rose to its current extraordinary heights, progressive law professors did nothing to resist it. This Article explores what happened and why. This is offered in the spirit of critical legal studies — as a critical self-examination of the failure of leftist law professors. The Crits were highly critical of complacent liberal academics of their day, arguing that they had a hand in perpetuating an unjust legal system; here I charge liberal legal academia — including the Crits — with perpetuating the profoundly warped and harmful economics of legal education. What follows will offend many of my fellow liberals. It may even lose me some friends. Liberal law professors must see past their anger to reflect on whether there is a core truth to my arguments, to take personal responsibility for what has happened, and to engage in collective action to do something to alter the economics of our operation. If not, the current economic barrier to a legal career may become permanent.
未来几代人在回顾21世纪的第一个十年时,会认为这是一个关键时期,当时竖起了一道巨大的经济障碍,阻碍了通往法律职业的道路。当每年的学费超过5万美元的门槛时,这一障碍的象征性宣告就响起了。现在,十几所法学院的学费都超过了这一门槛。包括学费和生活费在内,在美国大多数备受尊敬的法学院和一些非精英法学院获得法律学位的费用远远超过20万美元。因此,对于那些希望进入法学院学习的人来说,法学院收取了一笔高昂的入学费用。直到最近,法学院一直被视为美国社会向上流动和获得权力的途径。法律教育的定价结构具有深刻的阶级含义。高学费对中产阶级和贫困家庭学生的抑制作用,大于对资源丰富的富人子女的抑制作用。法学院奖学金政策,我将解释其原因,实际上是把有经济实力的学生送到排名较高的法学院,获得更好的机会,而把没有钱的学生送到排名较低的法学院。因此,越来越多的精英法律职位将由富有背景的人担任。对于那些依靠借贷来支付法律教育费用的学生来说,他们背负的沉重债务将决定他们寻找的工作类型,并限制他们未来的职业发展。自由派法学教授经常表达对美国社会阶级的担忧,他们支持进入法律行业,并为服务不足的社区提供法律服务。然而,当法学院的学费涨到目前这种异乎寻常的高度时,进步的法学教授们却没有采取任何抵抗措施。本文探讨了发生的事情及其原因。这是一种批判性法律研究的精神——对左派法学教授的失败进行批判性的自我反省。克里特夫妇对当时自满的自由派学者持高度批评态度,认为他们在延续不公正的法律体系方面发挥了作用;在这里,我指责自由派法律学术界——包括Crits——使法律教育中严重扭曲和有害的经济学永久化。接下来的内容将会冒犯我的许多自由主义者。它甚至可能使我失去一些朋友。自由派法学教授必须抛开他们的愤怒,反思我的论点是否有核心真理,为所发生的事情承担个人责任,并采取集体行动,做些什么来改变我们运作的经济状况。否则,目前阻碍律师职业发展的经济障碍可能会成为永久性障碍。
{"title":"The Failure of Crits and Leftist Law Professors to Defend Progressive Causes","authors":"B. Tamanaha","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2256725","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2256725","url":null,"abstract":"Future generations will look back at the first decade of the twenty-first century as a pivotal time when a huge economic barrier was erected to encumber the path to a legal career. The symbolic announcement of this barrier rang out when annual tuition crossed the $50,000 threshold, now exceeded at a dozen or so law schools. Including fees and living expenses, it costs well in excess of $200,000 to obtain a law degree at most of the nation’s highly regarded law schools and at a number of non-elite ones as well. Law schools thus impose a formidable entry fee on anyone who wishes to follow what, until recently, has long served as a means of upward mobility and access to power in American society. The pricing structure of legal education has profound class implications. High tuition will inhibit people from middle-class and poor families more than it will deter the offspring of the rich with ample resources. Law school scholarship policies, for reasons I will explain, in effect channel students with financial means to higher ranked law schools, reaping better opportunities, while sending students without money to lower law schools. A growing proportion of elite legal positions will be held by people from wealthy backgrounds as a result. For students who rely on borrowing to finance their legal education, the heavy debt they carry will dictate the types of jobs they seek and constrain the career they go on to have. Liberal law professors often express concerns about class in American society — championing access to the legal profession and the provision of legal services for underserved communities. Yet as law school tuition rose to its current extraordinary heights, progressive law professors did nothing to resist it. This Article explores what happened and why. This is offered in the spirit of critical legal studies — as a critical self-examination of the failure of leftist law professors. The Crits were highly critical of complacent liberal academics of their day, arguing that they had a hand in perpetuating an unjust legal system; here I charge liberal legal academia — including the Crits — with perpetuating the profoundly warped and harmful economics of legal education. What follows will offend many of my fellow liberals. It may even lose me some friends. Liberal law professors must see past their anger to reflect on whether there is a core truth to my arguments, to take personal responsibility for what has happened, and to engage in collective action to do something to alter the economics of our operation. If not, the current economic barrier to a legal career may become permanent.","PeriodicalId":344149,"journal":{"name":"Washington University in St. Louis School of Law Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2013-03-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128986329","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Invisible Pension Investments 无形养老金投资
Peter J. Wiedenbeck, R. Hinkle, Andrew D. Martin
A large share of the more than $5.5 trillion in private pension plan assets is held in certain types of indirect investment vehicles. If those vehicles file their own annual return with the Department of Labor they are called "direct filing entities" (or DFEs), and pension plans that invest in them are excused from providing detailed information concerning the assets, liabilities, and investment performance of the DFEs. Consequently, the publicly-available summary financial information reported by pension plans investing through one or more DFEs is seriously incomplete: while a plan must identify the categorical nature of its direct investments (for example, as common or preferred stock, corporate or government debt, real estate, etc.), indirect investments through a DFE are reported only as interests in the DFE, without regard to the underlying nature of the DFE‘s assets and liabilities. Matching the DFE‘s return with the returns filed by plans that invest through the DFE is theoretically possible, but it is technically difficult and has not been comprehensively achieved.This study undertakes the task of linking returns filed by large private pension plans and DFEs in 2008. After explaining the types of DFEs, summary statistics on the extent of pension plan investment through DFEs and the composition of DFE portfolios are reported. The process employed to link the holdings of each DFE to its investor plans is described, followed by description and analysis of the results. Important differences in the asset allocations of pension plans of various types are revealed, and the portfolio compositions of plans that do and do not invest through DFEs are compared. Because 35 percent of plans that invest in a DFE are found to file internally inconsistent returns which preclude successful linking of DFE financial information to the investor plan, the plan characteristics associated with such deficient filings are investigated. Although the composition of DFE portfolios is currently invisible to plan participants and the general public, we find little evidence that DFEs have been systematically exploited to obscure the identity of pension plan investments. Finally, the results of this study are reviewed in light of the purposes of pension plan financial disclosure. Even if routine, accurate, and comprehensive matching of DFE financial information with investor plans were available, ERISA‘s text and policies support the regulatory formulation of a far more detailed digital disclosure regime.
在超过5.5万亿美元的私人养老金计划资产中,有很大一部分是由某些类型的间接投资工具持有的。如果这些工具向劳工部提交自己的年度报表,它们就被称为“直接申报实体”(dfe),投资于它们的养老金计划不必提供有关dfe的资产、负债和投资业绩的详细信息。因此,通过一个或多个DFE进行投资的养老金计划报告的公开财务信息摘要严重不完整:虽然计划必须确定其直接投资的分类性质(例如,普通股或优先股,公司或政府债务,房地产等),但通过DFE进行的间接投资仅报告为DFE的权益,而不考虑DFE资产和负债的潜在性质。将DFE的回报与通过DFE投资的计划提交的回报相匹配在理论上是可能的,但这在技术上是困难的,并且尚未全面实现。本研究承担了2008年大型私人养老金计划与DFEs申报收益的关联研究任务。在解释了DFE的类型之后,总结统计了通过DFE进行养老金计划投资的程度和DFE投资组合的构成。描述了将每个DFE的持股与其投资者计划联系起来的过程,然后对结果进行了描述和分析。揭示了不同类型养老金计划在资产配置上的重要差异,并比较了通过dfe进行投资和不通过dfe进行投资的计划的投资组合构成。由于35%的投资于DFE的计划被发现提交了内部不一致的回报,这阻碍了DFE财务信息与投资者计划的成功联系,因此对与此类缺陷提交相关的计划特征进行了调查。尽管DFE投资组合的构成目前对计划参与者和公众来说是不可见的,但我们发现很少有证据表明DFE被系统地利用来模糊养老金计划投资的身份。最后,根据养老金计划财务披露的目的对研究结果进行了回顾。即使DFE财务信息与投资者计划的常规、准确和全面匹配是可用的,ERISA的文本和政策也支持更详细的数字披露制度的监管制定。
{"title":"Invisible Pension Investments","authors":"Peter J. Wiedenbeck, R. Hinkle, Andrew D. Martin","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2079298","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2079298","url":null,"abstract":"A large share of the more than $5.5 trillion in private pension plan assets is held in certain types of indirect investment vehicles. If those vehicles file their own annual return with the Department of Labor they are called \"direct filing entities\" (or DFEs), and pension plans that invest in them are excused from providing detailed information concerning the assets, liabilities, and investment performance of the DFEs. Consequently, the publicly-available summary financial information reported by pension plans investing through one or more DFEs is seriously incomplete: while a plan must identify the categorical nature of its direct investments (for example, as common or preferred stock, corporate or government debt, real estate, etc.), indirect investments through a DFE are reported only as interests in the DFE, without regard to the underlying nature of the DFE‘s assets and liabilities. Matching the DFE‘s return with the returns filed by plans that invest through the DFE is theoretically possible, but it is technically difficult and has not been comprehensively achieved.This study undertakes the task of linking returns filed by large private pension plans and DFEs in 2008. After explaining the types of DFEs, summary statistics on the extent of pension plan investment through DFEs and the composition of DFE portfolios are reported. The process employed to link the holdings of each DFE to its investor plans is described, followed by description and analysis of the results. Important differences in the asset allocations of pension plans of various types are revealed, and the portfolio compositions of plans that do and do not invest through DFEs are compared. Because 35 percent of plans that invest in a DFE are found to file internally inconsistent returns which preclude successful linking of DFE financial information to the investor plan, the plan characteristics associated with such deficient filings are investigated. Although the composition of DFE portfolios is currently invisible to plan participants and the general public, we find little evidence that DFEs have been systematically exploited to obscure the identity of pension plan investments. Finally, the results of this study are reviewed in light of the purposes of pension plan financial disclosure. Even if routine, accurate, and comprehensive matching of DFE financial information with investor plans were available, ERISA‘s text and policies support the regulatory formulation of a far more detailed digital disclosure regime.","PeriodicalId":344149,"journal":{"name":"Washington University in St. Louis School of Law Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"51 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2012-06-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122877835","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Standards and Related Intellectual Property Issues for Climate Change Technology 气候变化技术的标准和相关知识产权问题
Pub Date : 2012-02-09 DOI: 10.4337/9781784719463.00025
J. Contreras
Almost every product sold today must conform to standards, whether relating to its design, manufacture, operation, testing, safety, sale or disposal, and sometimes to many of these at once. At their root, standards are no more than written requirements or design features of a product, service or other activity. They can be breathtakingly detailed or disarmingly general, ranging from thousands of pages in length to just a few sentences. Standards are set by a wide range of bodies, from governmental agencies to industry consortia to multinational treaty organizations. Some standards are adopted into local, state or federal legislation and attain the force of law, others remain voluntary, yet are adopted by entire industries. This chapter provides a brief overview of the standards development landscape as it pertains to climate change technologies, also sometimes referred to as "clean tech", "green tech" and sustainability technologies, as well as the critical intellectual property issues that affect standards setting today.
今天销售的几乎每一件产品都必须符合标准,无论是设计、制造、操作、测试、安全、销售还是处置,有时还要同时符合多项标准。从根本上说,标准只不过是产品、服务或其他活动的书面要求或设计特征。它们可以是惊人的详细,也可以是令人不寒而栗的笼统,从数千页的篇幅到只有几句话。标准由各种各样的机构制定,从政府机构到工业联盟,再到多国条约组织。一些标准被地方、州或联邦立法采纳并具有法律效力,另一些标准仍然是自愿的,但被整个行业采用。本章简要概述了与气候变化技术(有时也被称为“清洁技术”、“绿色技术”和可持续性技术)以及影响当今标准制定的关键知识产权问题有关的标准制定情况。
{"title":"Standards and Related Intellectual Property Issues for Climate Change Technology","authors":"J. Contreras","doi":"10.4337/9781784719463.00025","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.4337/9781784719463.00025","url":null,"abstract":"Almost every product sold today must conform to standards, whether relating to its design, manufacture, operation, testing, safety, sale or disposal, and sometimes to many of these at once. At their root, standards are no more than written requirements or design features of a product, service or other activity. They can be breathtakingly detailed or disarmingly general, ranging from thousands of pages in length to just a few sentences. Standards are set by a wide range of bodies, from governmental agencies to industry consortia to multinational treaty organizations. Some standards are adopted into local, state or federal legislation and attain the force of law, others remain voluntary, yet are adopted by entire industries. This chapter provides a brief overview of the standards development landscape as it pertains to climate change technologies, also sometimes referred to as \"clean tech\", \"green tech\" and sustainability technologies, as well as the critical intellectual property issues that affect standards setting today.","PeriodicalId":344149,"journal":{"name":"Washington University in St. Louis School of Law Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"568 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2012-02-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130076141","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Getting into the 'Spirit' of Innovative Things: Looking to Complementary and Substitute Properties to Shape Patent Protection for Improvements 进入创新事物的“精神”:寻求互补和替代属性以形成改进的专利保护
K. Collins
This Article both identifies and corrects a blind spot in the literature on optimal patent protection for improvements. Contemporary theories cannot explain why a set of easy cases - cases in which earlier inventors’ patent claims routinely do and should expand over time to encompass later-developed improvements - are easy cases. To explain these cases, patent theory must identify the inventions of earlier and later inventors in a different manner. Today, inventions are viewed simply as innovative things or sets of innovative things. This Article demonstrates that the locus of invention must be identified in a finer-grained manner: the inventions of the successive inventors in an improvement scenario must be identified as the particular properties of innovative things that make them innovative. Identifying innovative properties as the locus of invention has two principal benefits. First, it reduces the explanatory gap between the economic theory on patent protection for improvements and the uncontroversial reality of the contemporary patent regime. It reliably distinguishes the easy cases from the difficult ones, and it explains why the cases are either easy or difficult. Second, it allows the economic concepts of complements and substitutes to be brought to bear on the crafting of optimal claim scope - a task that these concepts have not previously been thought suitable to perform. The easy cases are cases in which the innovative properties of subsequent inventors are pure complements, and the difficult cases are cases in which the innovative properties of subsequent inventors are complement-substitute mixtures.
本文指出并纠正了文献中关于最佳专利保护的盲点。当代理论无法解释为什么一组简单的案例是简单的案例——早期发明者的专利要求通常会并且应该随着时间的推移而扩展,以包含后来开发的改进。为了解释这些案例,专利理论必须以不同的方式识别早期和后来的发明者的发明。今天,发明被简单地看作是创新的东西或一系列创新的东西。本文表明,必须以更细粒度的方式确定发明的轨迹:在改进场景中,连续发明人的发明必须被确定为创新事物的特定属性,使其具有创新性。将创新属性确定为发明所在地有两个主要好处。首先,它缩小了改进专利保护的经济理论与当代专利制度无可争议的现实之间的解释差距。它可靠地区分了容易的案例和困难的案例,并解释了为什么这些案例是容易的还是困难的。其次,它允许将互补和替代的经济概念引入到最佳权利要求范围的制定中-这些概念以前被认为不适合执行的任务。易案是后继发明人的创新特性是纯粹互补的情况,难案是后继发明人的创新特性是互补-替代混合的情况。
{"title":"Getting into the 'Spirit' of Innovative Things: Looking to Complementary and Substitute Properties to Shape Patent Protection for Improvements","authors":"K. Collins","doi":"10.15779/Z38VQ48","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.15779/Z38VQ48","url":null,"abstract":"This Article both identifies and corrects a blind spot in the literature on optimal patent protection for improvements. Contemporary theories cannot explain why a set of easy cases - cases in which earlier inventors’ patent claims routinely do and should expand over time to encompass later-developed improvements - are easy cases. To explain these cases, patent theory must identify the inventions of earlier and later inventors in a different manner. Today, inventions are viewed simply as innovative things or sets of innovative things. This Article demonstrates that the locus of invention must be identified in a finer-grained manner: the inventions of the successive inventors in an improvement scenario must be identified as the particular properties of innovative things that make them innovative. Identifying innovative properties as the locus of invention has two principal benefits. First, it reduces the explanatory gap between the economic theory on patent protection for improvements and the uncontroversial reality of the contemporary patent regime. It reliably distinguishes the easy cases from the difficult ones, and it explains why the cases are either easy or difficult. Second, it allows the economic concepts of complements and substitutes to be brought to bear on the crafting of optimal claim scope - a task that these concepts have not previously been thought suitable to perform. The easy cases are cases in which the innovative properties of subsequent inventors are pure complements, and the difficult cases are cases in which the innovative properties of subsequent inventors are complement-substitute mixtures.","PeriodicalId":344149,"journal":{"name":"Washington University in St. Louis School of Law Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"42 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2011-09-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116280512","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Washington University in St. Louis School of Law Legal Studies Research Paper Series
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1