首页 > 最新文献

Florida State University Public Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series最新文献

英文 中文
Regional Energy Governance and U.S. Carbon Emissions 区域能源治理与美国碳排放
H. Wiseman, H. Osofsky
The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency’s final rule that limits carbon dioxide emissions from existing power plants — the Clean Power Plan — is an environmental regulation that powerfully influences energy law and forms a key part of the U.S. plan to meet its voluntary international commitments under the December 2015 Paris Agreement on climate change. Even if portions of the Plan are ultimately struck down, almost any viable pathway to lower carbon emissions will require greater integration of these two areas of law to address the large percentage of U.S. emissions from the energy sector. This integration produces both challenges and opportunities for governance. The Clean Power Plan (or similar regulations likely to be promulgated under the Clean Air Act in the future) must rely on an environmental-law cooperative federalist implementation structure in which states implement federal standards. However, electricity markets and governance are highly regional, and numerous studies show the economic benefits of interstate coordination, whether through governmental cooperation or trading among utilities. The project of energy-environment integration will benefit from existing regional energy-based institutions that already integrate electricity sources from different states. But it will require enhancement of existing regional approaches to generation capacity planning and transmission expansion, the interconnection of generators to lines, and energy markets. It also will require more interstate, state-regional-federal, and interregional cooperation.This Article systematically explores the opportunities for implementation of U.S. carbon emissions regulation presented by regional energy governance, using the Clean Power Plan as a case study. The Plan is not only the most ambitious effort at energy-environment integration to date, but also illustrates the need for enhanced regional governance. The Plan’s many options for interstate coordination — from multistate plans to utility trading — do not ensure alignment with existing regional markets because coordination will be difficult for states that choose different approaches to emissions accounting. The Article provides a timely analysis of (1) why enhanced regional governance of carbon emissions is needed, (2) what barriers it faces and opportunities it presents, and (3) how states could build from existing regional approaches in other contexts to create new mechanisms for cooperation and enhance regional governance structures. Addressing these governance issues effectively in the transition to a lower carbon economy will reduce the implementation costs of carbon emissions reduction and improve the reliability of the electricity system.
美国环境保护局限制现有发电厂二氧化碳排放的最终规定——清洁能源计划——是一项对能源法产生重大影响的环境法规,也是美国履行其根据2015年12月《巴黎气候变化协定》自愿作出的国际承诺计划的关键部分。即使该计划的部分内容最终被否决,几乎任何可行的降低碳排放的途径都需要将这两个领域的法律进行更大程度的整合,以解决美国能源部门排放的大部分问题。这种集成为治理带来了挑战和机遇。《清洁能源计划》(或未来可能根据《清洁空气法》颁布的类似法规)必须依赖于环境法合作的联邦主义实施结构,在该结构中,各州执行联邦标准。然而,电力市场和治理是高度区域化的,许多研究表明,无论是通过政府合作还是公用事业公司之间的交易,州际协调都能带来经济效益。能源-环境一体化项目将受益于现有的区域能源机构,这些机构已经整合了来自不同州的电力来源。但是,这将需要加强现有的区域发电能力规划和输电扩张、发电机与线路的互连以及能源市场的方法。它还需要更多的州际、州-地区-联邦以及地区间的合作。本文以清洁能源计划为例,系统探讨了区域能源治理为美国碳排放监管提供的实施机会。该计划不仅是迄今为止在能源-环境一体化方面最雄心勃勃的努力,而且表明需要加强区域治理。该计划的许多州际协调选择——从多州计划到公用事业交易——并不能确保与现有的区域市场保持一致,因为对于选择不同排放核算方法的州来说,协调将是困难的。本文及时分析了(1)为什么需要加强碳排放的区域治理,(2)它面临的障碍和它带来的机遇,以及(3)各国如何在其他背景下从现有的区域方法中建立新的合作机制并加强区域治理结构。在向低碳经济转型的过程中,有效解决这些治理问题将降低碳减排的实施成本,提高电力系统的可靠性。
{"title":"Regional Energy Governance and U.S. Carbon Emissions","authors":"H. Wiseman, H. Osofsky","doi":"10.15779/Z38400D","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.15779/Z38400D","url":null,"abstract":"The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency’s final rule that limits carbon dioxide emissions from existing power plants — the Clean Power Plan — is an environmental regulation that powerfully influences energy law and forms a key part of the U.S. plan to meet its voluntary international commitments under the December 2015 Paris Agreement on climate change. Even if portions of the Plan are ultimately struck down, almost any viable pathway to lower carbon emissions will require greater integration of these two areas of law to address the large percentage of U.S. emissions from the energy sector. This integration produces both challenges and opportunities for governance. The Clean Power Plan (or similar regulations likely to be promulgated under the Clean Air Act in the future) must rely on an environmental-law cooperative federalist implementation structure in which states implement federal standards. However, electricity markets and governance are highly regional, and numerous studies show the economic benefits of interstate coordination, whether through governmental cooperation or trading among utilities. The project of energy-environment integration will benefit from existing regional energy-based institutions that already integrate electricity sources from different states. But it will require enhancement of existing regional approaches to generation capacity planning and transmission expansion, the interconnection of generators to lines, and energy markets. It also will require more interstate, state-regional-federal, and interregional cooperation.This Article systematically explores the opportunities for implementation of U.S. carbon emissions regulation presented by regional energy governance, using the Clean Power Plan as a case study. The Plan is not only the most ambitious effort at energy-environment integration to date, but also illustrates the need for enhanced regional governance. The Plan’s many options for interstate coordination — from multistate plans to utility trading — do not ensure alignment with existing regional markets because coordination will be difficult for states that choose different approaches to emissions accounting. The Article provides a timely analysis of (1) why enhanced regional governance of carbon emissions is needed, (2) what barriers it faces and opportunities it presents, and (3) how states could build from existing regional approaches in other contexts to create new mechanisms for cooperation and enhance regional governance structures. Addressing these governance issues effectively in the transition to a lower carbon economy will reduce the implementation costs of carbon emissions reduction and improve the reliability of the electricity system.","PeriodicalId":133015,"journal":{"name":"Florida State University Public Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series","volume":"50 4-5 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-03-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"129442110","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Sharing of Cost Related Information Can Increase Consumer Welfare Under Risk-Aversion 风险规避下,成本相关信息共享可以增加消费者福利
Pub Date : 2015-08-15 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2644962
Murat C. Mungan
Existing literature suggests that the sharing of firm-specific information related to costs of production among Cournot competitors unambiguously reduces consumer welfare. This article shows that this result does not hold when at least one firm is risk-averse. Perhaps more importantly, if consumers are sufficiently risk-averse allowing information sharing leads to a Pareto improvement.
现有文献表明,在古诺竞争对手之间分享与生产成本相关的企业特定信息,无疑会降低消费者的福利。本文表明,当至少有一家公司是风险厌恶者时,这一结果并不成立。也许更重要的是,如果消费者足够厌恶风险,允许信息共享会导致帕累托改进。
{"title":"Sharing of Cost Related Information Can Increase Consumer Welfare Under Risk-Aversion","authors":"Murat C. Mungan","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2644962","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2644962","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000Existing literature suggests that the sharing of firm-specific information related to costs of production among Cournot competitors unambiguously reduces consumer welfare. This article shows that this result does not hold when at least one firm is risk-averse. Perhaps more importantly, if consumers are sufficiently risk-averse allowing information sharing leads to a Pareto improvement.","PeriodicalId":133015,"journal":{"name":"Florida State University Public Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series","volume":"10 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-08-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121872159","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Tax Credits on Federally Created Exchanges: Lessons from a Legislative Process Failure Theory of Statutory Interpretation 联邦创建交易所的税收抵免:来自立法程序失败理论的教训
Pub Date : 2015-01-15 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2550525
M. Seidenfeld
This Essay uses the “legislative process failure theory of statutory interpretation” to analyze whether the Affordable Care Act authorizes tax subsidies for individuals who enroll in health care plans through federally created American Health Benefit Exchanges. The Supreme Court recently granted cert. on this question, and a negative resolution by the Court could threaten the viability of the entire Act. The legislative process failure theory asserts that courts should use contextual evidence, including legislative history, of legislators’ likely understanding of a statute to resolve statutory meaning when there is reason to believe that a technical Textualist inquiry into the objective meaning leads to a different interpretation from that likely understanding and Congress was not aware of this potential difference. Applied to the question of the ACA subsidies on federally created exchanges, this analysis relies on the first-blush impression that federally created exchanges will substitute in all respects for state established ones, together with the absolute lack of any discussion of a contrary meaning in the legislative history or popular explanations of the Act, to conclude that the Court should interpret the ACA to authorize subsidies on federally created exchanges.
本文运用“法定解释的立法程序失败理论”来分析《平价医疗法案》是否授权通过联邦政府创建的美国健康福利交易所(American health Benefit Exchanges)为参加医疗保健计划的个人提供税收补贴。最高法院最近对这个问题作出了肯定,法院的否定决议可能会威胁到整个法案的可行性。立法程序失败理论主张,当有理由相信技术文本主义者对客观意义的探究会导致与可能的理解不同的解释,而国会没有意识到这种潜在的差异时,法院应该使用上下文证据,包括立法历史,即立法者对法规的可能理解来解决法定意义。适用于ACA对联邦创建的交易所的补贴问题,这种分析依赖于第一印象,即联邦创建的交易所将在所有方面取代州建立的交易所,同时绝对缺乏对立法历史中相反含义的讨论或对该法案的流行解释,从而得出结论,法院应该解释ACA以授权对联邦创建的交易所的补贴。
{"title":"Tax Credits on Federally Created Exchanges: Lessons from a Legislative Process Failure Theory of Statutory Interpretation","authors":"M. Seidenfeld","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2550525","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2550525","url":null,"abstract":"This Essay uses the “legislative process failure theory of statutory interpretation” to analyze whether the Affordable Care Act authorizes tax subsidies for individuals who enroll in health care plans through federally created American Health Benefit Exchanges. The Supreme Court recently granted cert. on this question, and a negative resolution by the Court could threaten the viability of the entire Act. The legislative process failure theory asserts that courts should use contextual evidence, including legislative history, of legislators’ likely understanding of a statute to resolve statutory meaning when there is reason to believe that a technical Textualist inquiry into the objective meaning leads to a different interpretation from that likely understanding and Congress was not aware of this potential difference. Applied to the question of the ACA subsidies on federally created exchanges, this analysis relies on the first-blush impression that federally created exchanges will substitute in all respects for state established ones, together with the absolute lack of any discussion of a contrary meaning in the legislative history or popular explanations of the Act, to conclude that the Court should interpret the ACA to authorize subsidies on federally created exchanges.","PeriodicalId":133015,"journal":{"name":"Florida State University Public Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series","volume":"121 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-01-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128348870","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Reverse Payments, Perverse Incentives 反向支付,反常激励
Pub Date : 2013-02-08 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2214170
Murat C. Mungan
Issuing and enforcing prescription drug patents requires courts and legislatures to strike a delicate balance. A patent gives drug manufacturers a legal, if temporary, monopoly on sales of a drug; this encourages manufacturers to engage in costly research and development of new medicines. But not all patents issued by the Patent Office are ultimately deemed valid – generic drug manufacturers can infringe the patent, and, when sued, attack its validity in court on a variety of grounds, including obviousness. In recent years, patent holders have begun to settle these suits (which they initiated) by paying the alleged infringer. Not surprisingly, these reverse payment settlements (“RPSs”) have been challenged on antitrust grounds. The federal courts of appeals split over whether this practice is presumptively an illegal restraint of trade, and in December 2012 the Supreme Court agreed to decide the issue, granting a writ of certiorari in FTC v. Watson Pharmaceuticals. In light of the importance of the issue to both drug consumers and manufacturers, it is crucial to understand the economic effects of RPSs. Many courts, including the Second Circuit and the Eleventh Circuit, commentators and scholars have suggested that restricting RPSs would necessarily retard technological progress, by reducing the expected returns of becoming a patentee. In this Article, I show, with the help of a game-theoretical model, that this conclusion is unwarranted. Restricting RPSs has the effect of chilling generic entry when – and only when – the underlying patent is strong, or likely to be held valid and infringed. Therefore, restricting RPSs increases the expected returns of holding a strong patent by eliminating potential payments to generic entrants, while at the same time eliminating the possibility of monopoly profit-splitting between branded and generic manufacturers when the patent is weak. This reward shifting effect implies that restricting the use of RPSs is likely to foster more revolutionary innovations, which lead to stronger patents, while lowering R&D towards relatively obvious inventions, which lead to weaker patents. This reward shifting effect of restrictive rules on RPSs, to the best of my knowledge, has gone unnoticed in the past, and it should play an important role in the Supreme Court’s cost benefit analysis.
颁发和执行处方药专利要求法院和立法机构取得微妙的平衡。专利赋予药品制造商合法的(即使是暂时的)药品销售垄断权;这鼓励制造商投入昂贵的新药研究和开发。但并不是专利局颁发的所有专利最终都被认为是有效的——仿制药制造商可以侵犯专利,当被起诉时,他们可以在法庭上以各种理由攻击专利的有效性,包括显而易见性。近年来,专利持有人已经开始通过向被指控的侵权者付款来解决这些诉讼(他们发起的)。毫不奇怪,这些反向支付协议(“RPSs”)受到了反垄断方面的挑战。联邦上诉法院在这种做法是否被推定为非法限制贸易的问题上存在分歧,2012年12月,最高法院同意就这一问题作出裁决,在联邦贸易委员会诉沃森制药公司一案中颁发了调卷令。鉴于该问题对药品消费者和制造商的重要性,了解RPSs的经济影响至关重要。包括第二巡回法院和第十一巡回法院在内的许多法院、评论员和学者都认为,限制RPSs必然会阻碍技术进步,因为这会降低成为专利权人的预期回报。在本文中,我将借助一个博弈论模型来证明这一结论是站不住脚的。当(且仅当)基础专利强大,或可能被认定有效并被侵权时,限制RPSs会产生抑制通用专利进入的效果。因此,限制RPSs通过消除对仿制药进入者的潜在支付,增加了持有强专利的预期回报,同时消除了专利弱时品牌和仿制药制造商之间垄断利润分配的可能性。这种奖励转移效应意味着,限制RPSs的使用可能会促进更多的革命性创新,从而导致更强的专利,同时降低对相对明显的发明的研发,从而导致更弱的专利。据我所知,限制性规则对rpg的奖励转移效应在过去被忽视了,它应该在最高法院的成本效益分析中发挥重要作用。
{"title":"Reverse Payments, Perverse Incentives","authors":"Murat C. Mungan","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2214170","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2214170","url":null,"abstract":"Issuing and enforcing prescription drug patents requires courts and legislatures to strike a delicate balance. A patent gives drug manufacturers a legal, if temporary, monopoly on sales of a drug; this encourages manufacturers to engage in costly research and development of new medicines. But not all patents issued by the Patent Office are ultimately deemed valid – generic drug manufacturers can infringe the patent, and, when sued, attack its validity in court on a variety of grounds, including obviousness. In recent years, patent holders have begun to settle these suits (which they initiated) by paying the alleged infringer. Not surprisingly, these reverse payment settlements (“RPSs”) have been challenged on antitrust grounds. The federal courts of appeals split over whether this practice is presumptively an illegal restraint of trade, and in December 2012 the Supreme Court agreed to decide the issue, granting a writ of certiorari in FTC v. Watson Pharmaceuticals. In light of the importance of the issue to both drug consumers and manufacturers, it is crucial to understand the economic effects of RPSs. Many courts, including the Second Circuit and the Eleventh Circuit, commentators and scholars have suggested that restricting RPSs would necessarily retard technological progress, by reducing the expected returns of becoming a patentee. In this Article, I show, with the help of a game-theoretical model, that this conclusion is unwarranted. Restricting RPSs has the effect of chilling generic entry when – and only when – the underlying patent is strong, or likely to be held valid and infringed. Therefore, restricting RPSs increases the expected returns of holding a strong patent by eliminating potential payments to generic entrants, while at the same time eliminating the possibility of monopoly profit-splitting between branded and generic manufacturers when the patent is weak. This reward shifting effect implies that restricting the use of RPSs is likely to foster more revolutionary innovations, which lead to stronger patents, while lowering R&D towards relatively obvious inventions, which lead to weaker patents. This reward shifting effect of restrictive rules on RPSs, to the best of my knowledge, has gone unnoticed in the past, and it should play an important role in the Supreme Court’s cost benefit analysis.","PeriodicalId":133015,"journal":{"name":"Florida State University Public Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series","volume":"71 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2013-02-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123823082","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Deconstructing Haig-Simons Income and Reconstructing It as Objective Ability-to-Pay Income 海格-西蒙斯收入的解构与客观支付能力收入的重构
Pub Date : 2012-05-07 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2053275
Joseph M. Dodge
The Haig-Simons concept of income has for roughly fifty years been a gold standard of income tax theory and policy discussion. This article argues that the classic Haig-Simons formulation of personal income, which consists of an individual’s consumption plus net increases in wealth for the taxable year, could not be maintained by Simons himself, is contrary to fundamental political values, is unnecessary, and is inferior to an objective ability-to-pay realization personal income tax. Specifically, the Haig-Simons concept simply gets it wrong insofar as it posits that consumption is an independent category of income. That leaves “consumption” as a deduction-disallowance principle, but in that respect the concept is ambiguous and insufficient. Finally, the notion of “changes in wealth” hasn’t made headway, due to the persistence of the realization principle. The problems attending the Haig-Simons income concept, as well as Simons’ goal of designing a redistributive tax, are resolved under an objective ability-to-pay personal income concept. Part I uncovers the basic ambiguity as to the role of “consumption” under the Haig-Simons concept of income, and demonstrates that consumption under the Haig-Simons concept should not be interpreted as a gross income principle. Thus, imputed income (and other intangible benefits received) are not properly viewed as gross income in the tax sense. Instead, consumption is merely a deduction-disallowance principle, and an insufficient (or incomplete) one at that. Part II discusses normative criteria underlying an income tax that point towards an objective ability-to-pay realization personal income tax. The notion of objective ability to pay is an internal-to-tax tax fairness norm that is constructed from the ground up by considering the role of taxation (in a liberal society) to raise cash revenue in an annual budget cycle. It also happens that an ability-to-pay personal income tax can, itself perform a mildly redistributive function. (Incidentally, it is argued in this part that indexing of basis is improper from a tax fairness perspective.) Part III follows with an outline of basic features of such a tax. Some controversial points raised in Part III include abolition of the accrual method of tax accounting, disallowing depreciation deductions, and a thorough revamping of the tax treatment of borrowing.
大约50年来,海格-西蒙斯的收入概念一直是所得税理论和政策讨论的黄金标准。本文认为,经典的海格-西蒙斯个人收入公式,即个人消费加上应纳税年度的财富净增长,无法由西蒙斯本人维持,与基本的政治价值观相悖,是不必要的,并且不如客观的支付能力实现个人所得税。具体来说,海格-西蒙斯的概念完全错了,因为它假定消费是收入的一个独立类别。这使得“消费”成为一个扣除-不允许原则,但在这方面,这个概念是模糊和不充分的。最后,由于变现原则的坚持,“财富变化”的概念没有取得进展。海格-西蒙斯收入概念中的问题,以及西蒙斯设计再分配税的目标,在客观的个人收入支付能力概念下得到了解决。第一部分揭示了海格-西蒙斯收入概念下“消费”作用的基本歧义,并论证了海格-西蒙斯概念下的消费不应被解释为总收入原则。因此,在税收意义上,估算收入(和其他获得的无形利益)不能被恰当地视为总收入。相反,消费只是一个扣除-不允许原则,而且是一个不充分(或不完整)的原则。第二部分讨论了所得税的规范性标准,这些标准指向客观的支付能力实现个人所得税。客观支付能力的概念是一种内部税收公平规范,它是通过考虑税收(在自由社会中)在年度预算周期中提高现金收入的作用而从头开始构建的。碰巧的是,支付个人所得税的能力本身可以起到轻微的再分配作用。(顺便提一下,从税收公平的角度来看,本部分认为基础索引是不恰当的。)第三部分接着概述了这种税的基本特征。第三部分提出了一些有争议的观点,包括废除权责发生制税收会计,不允许折旧扣除,以及彻底改革借款的税收待遇。
{"title":"Deconstructing Haig-Simons Income and Reconstructing It as Objective Ability-to-Pay Income","authors":"Joseph M. Dodge","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2053275","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2053275","url":null,"abstract":"The Haig-Simons concept of income has for roughly fifty years been a gold standard of income tax theory and policy discussion. This article argues that the classic Haig-Simons formulation of personal income, which consists of an individual’s consumption plus net increases in wealth for the taxable year, could not be maintained by Simons himself, is contrary to fundamental political values, is unnecessary, and is inferior to an objective ability-to-pay realization personal income tax. Specifically, the Haig-Simons concept simply gets it wrong insofar as it posits that consumption is an independent category of income. That leaves “consumption” as a deduction-disallowance principle, but in that respect the concept is ambiguous and insufficient. Finally, the notion of “changes in wealth” hasn’t made headway, due to the persistence of the realization principle. The problems attending the Haig-Simons income concept, as well as Simons’ goal of designing a redistributive tax, are resolved under an objective ability-to-pay personal income concept. Part I uncovers the basic ambiguity as to the role of “consumption” under the Haig-Simons concept of income, and demonstrates that consumption under the Haig-Simons concept should not be interpreted as a gross income principle. Thus, imputed income (and other intangible benefits received) are not properly viewed as gross income in the tax sense. Instead, consumption is merely a deduction-disallowance principle, and an insufficient (or incomplete) one at that. Part II discusses normative criteria underlying an income tax that point towards an objective ability-to-pay realization personal income tax. The notion of objective ability to pay is an internal-to-tax tax fairness norm that is constructed from the ground up by considering the role of taxation (in a liberal society) to raise cash revenue in an annual budget cycle. It also happens that an ability-to-pay personal income tax can, itself perform a mildly redistributive function. (Incidentally, it is argued in this part that indexing of basis is improper from a tax fairness perspective.) Part III follows with an outline of basic features of such a tax. Some controversial points raised in Part III include abolition of the accrual method of tax accounting, disallowing depreciation deductions, and a thorough revamping of the tax treatment of borrowing.","PeriodicalId":133015,"journal":{"name":"Florida State University Public Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2012-05-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"129305254","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Background Principles, Takings, and Libertarian Property: A Reply to Professor Huffman 背景原则、征收与自由主义财产:对霍夫曼教授的回答
M. Blumm, J. Ruhl
One of the principal, if unexpected, results of the Supreme Court's 1992 decision in Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Commission is the rise of background principles of property and nuisance law as a categorical defense to takings claims. Our writings on the background principles defense have provoked Professor Huffman, a devoted advocate for an expanded use of regulatory takings to protect landowner development rights, to mistakenly charge us with arguing for the use of common law principles to circumvent the rule of law, Supreme Court intent, and the takings clause. Actually, ours was not a normative brief at all, but instead a positivistic explanation of takings cases in the lower courts since Lucas, which include judicial recognition of statutory background principles. In this article, we respond to Huffman, examining the continuing importance of the background principles defense and explaining the trouble with his vision of libertarian property and his peculiar notion of the rule of law. We focus especially on wetlands regulation, which Huffman thinks is a recent development when in fact its origins date to medieval England, and therefore is particularly suited to the background principles defense. We conclude that background principles, as "the logically antecedent inquiry" into the nature of a claimant's property interest, are now a permanent feature of the takings landscape.
最高法院1992年对卢卡斯诉南卡罗来纳海岸委员会一案的判决,产生了一个主要的、可能出乎意料的结果,那就是财产法和妨害法的背景原则的兴起,作为对征收索赔的绝对辩护。我们关于背景原则辩护的文章激怒了霍夫曼教授,这位致力于扩大使用监管征收来保护土地所有者发展权的倡导者,错误地指责我们主张使用普通法原则来规避法治、最高法院的意图和征收条款。实际上,我们的摘要根本不是规范性的摘要,而是对卢卡斯以来下级法院征收案件的实证解释,其中包括对法定背景原则的司法承认。在本文中,我们将对霍夫曼的观点做出回应,考察背景原则辩护的持续重要性,并解释他对自由主义财产的看法和他特有的法治概念所带来的麻烦。我们特别关注湿地法规,霍夫曼认为这是最近的发展,而实际上它的起源可以追溯到中世纪的英格兰,因此特别适合于背景原则辩护。我们得出的结论是,背景原则,作为对索赔人财产利益性质的“逻辑先行调查”,现在是征收景观的永久特征。
{"title":"Background Principles, Takings, and Libertarian Property: A Reply to Professor Huffman","authors":"M. Blumm, J. Ruhl","doi":"10.15779/Z38PV8Q","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.15779/Z38PV8Q","url":null,"abstract":"One of the principal, if unexpected, results of the Supreme Court's 1992 decision in Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Commission is the rise of background principles of property and nuisance law as a categorical defense to takings claims. Our writings on the background principles defense have provoked Professor Huffman, a devoted advocate for an expanded use of regulatory takings to protect landowner development rights, to mistakenly charge us with arguing for the use of common law principles to circumvent the rule of law, Supreme Court intent, and the takings clause. Actually, ours was not a normative brief at all, but instead a positivistic explanation of takings cases in the lower courts since Lucas, which include judicial recognition of statutory background principles. In this article, we respond to Huffman, examining the continuing importance of the background principles defense and explaining the trouble with his vision of libertarian property and his peculiar notion of the rule of law. We focus especially on wetlands regulation, which Huffman thinks is a recent development when in fact its origins date to medieval England, and therefore is particularly suited to the background principles defense. We conclude that background principles, as \"the logically antecedent inquiry\" into the nature of a claimant's property interest, are now a permanent feature of the takings landscape.","PeriodicalId":133015,"journal":{"name":"Florida State University Public Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2010-03-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130731464","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
The Limits of Bargaining Power as an Interpretive Aid 议价能力的局限性作为一种解释性援助
Pub Date : 2009-07-06 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1430704
Shawn J. Bayern
This is a short response to a recent essay by Omri Ben-Shahar ("A Bargaining Power Theory of Default Rules," 109 Colum. L. Rev. 396 (2009)). It is part of a broader forthcoming analysis of contract interpretation.Professor Ben-Shahar argues that evidence of bargaining power should inform courts when they fill contractual gaps. I make several observations in response: (1) a significant portion of Ben-Shahar's argument applies not to gaps but to other kinds of contractual questions, and it has less force for gaps; (2) reliable evidence about bargaining power is often unavailable; (3) contracts should not be interpreted, generally speaking, based on an analysis of how parties have divided contractual surplus, because an intent regarding general surplus division does not follow from evidence regarding specific surplus divisions; and (4) even when one party is strong enough to apparently dictate terms, there is no good general reason to allow it to dictate specific terms ex post. In principle, my analysis is not meant to refute Professor Ben-Shahar's general line of reasoning but to suggest that bargaining power, though important theoretically, is unlikely to be useful as an independent interpretive aid in contract law.
这是对Omri Ben-Shahar最近的一篇文章的简短回应(“默认规则的议价能力理论”,109专栏)。Rev. 396(2009))。这是即将展开的更广泛的合同解释分析的一部分。本-沙哈尔教授认为,议价能力的证据应该为法院填补合同空白提供依据。作为回应,我提出了几点看法:(1)Ben-Shahar的论点的很大一部分并不适用于缺口,而是适用于其他类型的合同问题,而且它对缺口的影响力较小;(2)往往没有关于议价能力的可靠证据;(3)一般来说,不应该根据对当事人如何分割合同剩余的分析来解释合同,因为关于一般剩余分割的意图不能从关于具体剩余分割的证据中得出;(4)即使一方强大到足以明显地规定条款,也没有好的一般理由允许它在事后规定具体条款。原则上,我的分析并不是要反驳本-沙哈尔教授的一般推理思路,而是要表明,议价能力虽然在理论上很重要,但在合同法中不太可能作为一种独立的解释手段有用。
{"title":"The Limits of Bargaining Power as an Interpretive Aid","authors":"Shawn J. Bayern","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1430704","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1430704","url":null,"abstract":"This is a short response to a recent essay by Omri Ben-Shahar (\"A Bargaining Power Theory of Default Rules,\" 109 Colum. L. Rev. 396 (2009)). It is part of a broader forthcoming analysis of contract interpretation.Professor Ben-Shahar argues that evidence of bargaining power should inform courts when they fill contractual gaps. I make several observations in response: (1) a significant portion of Ben-Shahar's argument applies not to gaps but to other kinds of contractual questions, and it has less force for gaps; (2) reliable evidence about bargaining power is often unavailable; (3) contracts should not be interpreted, generally speaking, based on an analysis of how parties have divided contractual surplus, because an intent regarding general surplus division does not follow from evidence regarding specific surplus divisions; and (4) even when one party is strong enough to apparently dictate terms, there is no good general reason to allow it to dictate specific terms ex post. In principle, my analysis is not meant to refute Professor Ben-Shahar's general line of reasoning but to suggest that bargaining power, though important theoretically, is unlikely to be useful as an independent interpretive aid in contract law.","PeriodicalId":133015,"journal":{"name":"Florida State University Public Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series","volume":"28 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-07-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127712643","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Complexity Theory as a Paradigm for the Dynamical Law-and-Society System: A Wake-Up Call for Legal Reductionism and the Modern Administrative State 复杂性理论作为动态法律与社会系统的范式:为法律还原论和现代行政国家敲响警钟
J. Ruhl
This article is the first in my series of articles exploring the application of complex adaptive systems (CAS) theory to legal systems. It builds the basic model of CAS and maps it onto legal systems, offering some suggestions for what it means in terms of legal institution and instrument design.
本文是我探索复杂适应系统(CAS)理论在法律体系中的应用的系列文章中的第一篇。建立了CAS的基本模型,并将其映射到法律体系中,对其在法律制度和文书设计方面的意义提出了一些建议。
{"title":"Complexity Theory as a Paradigm for the Dynamical Law-and-Society System: A Wake-Up Call for Legal Reductionism and the Modern Administrative State","authors":"J. Ruhl","doi":"10.2307/1372975","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2307/1372975","url":null,"abstract":"This article is the first in my series of articles exploring the application of complex adaptive systems (CAS) theory to legal systems. It builds the basic model of CAS and maps it onto legal systems, offering some suggestions for what it means in terms of legal institution and instrument design.","PeriodicalId":133015,"journal":{"name":"Florida State University Public Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series","volume":"32 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1996-12-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123078163","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 74
RUPA and Fiduciary Duty: The Texture of Relationship RUPA与信义义务:关系的肌理
D. Weidner
The fiduciary duty rules in the Revised Uniform Partnership Act (1994) ("RUPA") have been criticized by some as being too contractarian and by others as being too paternalistic. Professor J. Dennis Hynes, whose agency and partnership casebook I have long admired, joins those who believe that RUPA is overly paternalistic. His thesis is that RUPA's fiduciary duty rules invite too much judicial intervention. He asserts that, unless the bargaining of the parties is flawed, courts should refrain from intervening in the resulting contract. Only if the bargaining process is flawed should "unconscionable" provisions be set aside.The essence of my response is that RUPA represents a major and sufficient move toward a contractarian statement of the law. In particular, I reject the assertion that partners should be free to contract away all fiduciary duties. First, individuals rarely "bargain" as equals for partnership agreements that completely define their relationship. The law should assume that the completely defined partnership relationship is the exception rather than the norm. It should also take into account the probability that the bargaining process involves human foible and important information asymmetries, if not outright fraud. Second, even apart from the imperfections of bargaining, prohibiting certain types of relationships is preferable to permitting them. Mandatory minima are designed to prevent types of relationships that would cost more than they would benefit. Finally, the language of fiduciary law, with its mandatory rules, is preferable to the language of the law of the sale of goods, with its mandatory rules. The language stating the minima among partners ought to reflect the texture of their relationship, which is one of a powerful mutual agency, ill-defined hierarchy, and joint and several liability. If the indeterminacy of the mimina is kept in check, the benefit of the mimina will far exceed the cost.
1994年修订的《统一合伙企业法》(“RUPA”)中的信义义务规则被一些人批评为过于契约主义,而另一些人则批评为过于家长式。J. Dennis Hynes教授,他的代理和合作案例手册我一直很欣赏,他加入了那些认为RUPA过于家长式的人的队伍。他的论点是RUPA的信义义务规则招致了过多的司法干预。他断言,除非双方的议价存在缺陷,否则法院不应干预由此产生的合同。只有在谈判过程存在缺陷的情况下,“不合理”的条款才应该被搁置一边。我的回答的本质是RUPA代表了向法律的契约声明的主要和充分的移动。我尤其反对这样一种说法,即合伙人应该可以自由地通过合同放弃所有受托责任。首先,个人很少平等地“讨价还价”,签订完全定义他们关系的伙伴关系协议。法律应当假定完全界定的合伙关系是例外而不是常态。它还应该考虑到议价过程中涉及人类弱点和重要信息不对称的可能性,如果不是彻头彻尾的欺诈的话。其次,即使不考虑讨价还价的不完美之处,禁止某些类型的关系也比允许它们更好。强制性最低限度是为了防止那种代价大于收益的关系。最后,具有强制性规则的信托法的语言比具有强制性规则的货物销售法的语言更可取。说明合伙人之间最低限度的语言应该反映他们关系的结构,即一种强大的相互代理、不明确的等级制度、连带责任。如果最小值的不确定性得到控制,最小值的收益将远远超过成本。
{"title":"RUPA and Fiduciary Duty: The Texture of Relationship","authors":"D. Weidner","doi":"10.2307/1192147","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2307/1192147","url":null,"abstract":"The fiduciary duty rules in the Revised Uniform Partnership Act (1994) (\"RUPA\") have been criticized by some as being too contractarian and by others as being too paternalistic. Professor J. Dennis Hynes, whose agency and partnership casebook I have long admired, joins those who believe that RUPA is overly paternalistic. His thesis is that RUPA's fiduciary duty rules invite too much judicial intervention. He asserts that, unless the bargaining of the parties is flawed, courts should refrain from intervening in the resulting contract. Only if the bargaining process is flawed should \"unconscionable\" provisions be set aside.The essence of my response is that RUPA represents a major and sufficient move toward a contractarian statement of the law. In particular, I reject the assertion that partners should be free to contract away all fiduciary duties. First, individuals rarely \"bargain\" as equals for partnership agreements that completely define their relationship. The law should assume that the completely defined partnership relationship is the exception rather than the norm. It should also take into account the probability that the bargaining process involves human foible and important information asymmetries, if not outright fraud. Second, even apart from the imperfections of bargaining, prohibiting certain types of relationships is preferable to permitting them. Mandatory minima are designed to prevent types of relationships that would cost more than they would benefit. Finally, the language of fiduciary law, with its mandatory rules, is preferable to the language of the law of the sale of goods, with its mandatory rules. The language stating the minima among partners ought to reflect the texture of their relationship, which is one of a powerful mutual agency, ill-defined hierarchy, and joint and several liability. If the indeterminacy of the mimina is kept in check, the benefit of the mimina will far exceed the cost.","PeriodicalId":133015,"journal":{"name":"Florida State University Public Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series","volume":"60 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"114382408","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Florida State University Public Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1