首页 > 最新文献

ERN: Production; Cost; Capital & Total Factor Productivity; Value Theory (Topic)最新文献

英文 中文
How Does 5s Implementation Affect Company Performance? A Case Study Applied to a Subsidiary of a Rubber Goods Manufacturer from Serbia 实施5s如何影响公司绩效?塞尔维亚一家橡胶制品生产商子公司的案例研究
Pub Date : 2017-06-01 DOI: 10.5755/J01.EE.28.3.16115
M. Todorović, Milan Čupić
5S can be viewed as a system of workplace rules devised to create a safe and productive work environment and to provide efficient and effective realization of business tasks. Its implementation is expected to reduce defects, improve quality, increase safety and the morale of the employees, and improve employees' productivity. It helps company identify problems, create a culture of discipline and make opportunities for improvements more visible. In the present paper, over the period of seven years, we investigate the case of a rubber goods manufacturer from Serbia which has implemented 5S in one of its subsidiaries. To assess the effects of the 5S implementation we use operational and financial performance indicators. Our results suggest that the implementation of 5S can contribute to performance of an organization only in the short and medium term. Relatively limited effects of the 5S implementation could be due to the financial crisis and the fact that the footwear subsidiary invested heavily during the analyzed period. In addition, 5S usually contributes to stabilization and efficiency increase of the business processes in only certain segments of the organization. Subsidiary in our study implemented TDABC to make possible production of information and reports important for efficient decision making and control in the new business environment. This finding points to the importance of the management accounting system improvements after the CIPs implementation.DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.5755/j01.ee.28.3.16115
5S可以被看作是一套工作场所规则,旨在创造一个安全和富有成效的工作环境,并提供高效和有效地实现业务任务。它的实施有望减少缺陷,提高质量,增加员工的安全和士气,提高员工的生产力。它有助于公司发现问题,创造一种纪律文化,并使改进的机会更加明显。在本文中,在七年的时间里,我们调查了塞尔维亚橡胶制品制造商的案例,该制造商在其子公司之一实施了5S。为了评估5S实施的效果,我们使用运营和财务绩效指标。我们的研究结果表明,5S的实施只能在短期和中期对组织的绩效做出贡献。实施5S的效果相对有限可能是由于金融危机和鞋业子公司在分析期间的大量投资。此外,5S通常只在组织的某些部分有助于业务流程的稳定和效率的提高。在我们的研究中,子公司实施了TDABC,以使信息和报告的生产成为可能,这对于在新的商业环境中有效的决策和控制很重要。这一发现指出了cip实施后管理会计制度改进的重要性。DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.5755/j01.ee.28.3.16115
{"title":"How Does 5s Implementation Affect Company Performance? A Case Study Applied to a Subsidiary of a Rubber Goods Manufacturer from Serbia","authors":"M. Todorović, Milan Čupić","doi":"10.5755/J01.EE.28.3.16115","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.5755/J01.EE.28.3.16115","url":null,"abstract":"5S can be viewed as a system of workplace rules devised to create a safe and productive work environment and to provide efficient and effective realization of business tasks. Its implementation is expected to reduce defects, improve quality, increase safety and the morale of the employees, and improve employees' productivity. It helps company identify problems, create a culture of discipline and make opportunities for improvements more visible. In the present paper, over the period of seven years, we investigate the case of a rubber goods manufacturer from Serbia which has implemented 5S in one of its subsidiaries. To assess the effects of the 5S implementation we use operational and financial performance indicators. Our results suggest that the implementation of 5S can contribute to performance of an organization only in the short and medium term. Relatively limited effects of the 5S implementation could be due to the financial crisis and the fact that the footwear subsidiary invested heavily during the analyzed period. In addition, 5S usually contributes to stabilization and efficiency increase of the business processes in only certain segments of the organization. Subsidiary in our study implemented TDABC to make possible production of information and reports important for efficient decision making and control in the new business environment. This finding points to the importance of the management accounting system improvements after the CIPs implementation.DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.5755/j01.ee.28.3.16115","PeriodicalId":237187,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Production; Cost; Capital & Total Factor Productivity; Value Theory (Topic)","volume":"75 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127410607","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 19
The Role of Foresight in Shaping the Next Production Revolution 远见在塑造下一次生产革命中的作用
Pub Date : 2017-05-10 DOI: 10.1787/9789264271036-EN
Attila Havas, Matthias Weber
Foresight can be a highly useful tool to address the opportunities and challenges triggered by the next production revolution. As shown by the various country cases considered in this chapter, it facilitates debating and systemic thinking about multiple futures and helps shaping the future through the process of participation and engagement. Given its participatory nature, key actors are mobilised to form shared views about the future, negotiate their future stakes and interests, and agree on actions aligned to their shared vision. The next production revolution requires quick and proactive policy-making, as well as better orchestration across different policy domains. Foresight can assist policy-makers by providing foundations for robust policies, fostering new framing of policy issues, as well as translating long-term concerns into aligned policy priorities. Furthermore, policy implementation is likely to be faster and more effective when key stakeholders are involved early on in shaping these policies. Foresight benefits, however, are far from being automatic: the chapter considers eight factors critical to achieving those. An astute embedding of a foresight process into policy-making enhances the likelihood of impact, but foresight recommendations are no substitute for policy decisions and actions.
在应对下一次生产革命带来的机遇和挑战时,远见是非常有用的工具。正如本章所考虑的各种国家案例所示,它促进了对多种未来的辩论和系统思考,并通过参与和参与的过程帮助塑造未来。鉴于其参与性,主要行为体被动员起来形成对未来的共同看法,就其未来的利害关系和利益进行谈判,并就符合其共同愿景的行动达成一致。下一次生产革命需要快速和主动的政策制定,以及跨不同政策领域的更好的编排。远见可以为政策制定者提供强有力的政策基础,促进政策问题的新框架,并将长期关注转化为一致的政策重点。此外,如果关键利益相关者尽早参与制定这些政策,政策的实施可能会更快、更有效。然而,预见的好处远不是自动产生的:本章考虑了实现这些好处的八个关键因素。将预见过程巧妙地纳入决策过程可以提高产生影响的可能性,但预见建议不能替代政策决定和行动。
{"title":"The Role of Foresight in Shaping the Next Production Revolution","authors":"Attila Havas, Matthias Weber","doi":"10.1787/9789264271036-EN","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264271036-EN","url":null,"abstract":"Foresight can be a highly useful tool to address the opportunities and challenges triggered by the next production revolution. As shown by the various country cases considered in this chapter, it facilitates debating and systemic thinking about multiple futures and helps shaping the future through the process of participation and engagement. Given its participatory nature, key actors are mobilised to form shared views about the future, negotiate their future stakes and interests, and agree on actions aligned to their shared vision. The next production revolution requires quick and proactive policy-making, as well as better orchestration across different policy domains. Foresight can assist policy-makers by providing foundations for robust policies, fostering new framing of policy issues, as well as translating long-term concerns into aligned policy priorities. Furthermore, policy implementation is likely to be faster and more effective when key stakeholders are involved early on in shaping these policies. Foresight benefits, however, are far from being automatic: the chapter considers eight factors critical to achieving those. An astute embedding of a foresight process into policy-making enhances the likelihood of impact, but foresight recommendations are no substitute for policy decisions and actions.","PeriodicalId":237187,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Production; Cost; Capital & Total Factor Productivity; Value Theory (Topic)","volume":"34 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-05-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128367422","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 82
Markups, Productivity and the Financial Capability of Firms 加价、生产率和企业财务能力
C. Altomonte, Domenico Favoino, T. Sonno
We extend a framework of monopolistically competitive firms heterogeneous in productivity and with endogenous markups (as in Melitz and Ottaviano, 2008) to incorporate the presence of financial frictions. Before producing, firms need to obtain a loan necessary to cover part of production costs, for which they have to pledge collateral in the form of tangible assets. In addition to productivity, firms are also heterogeneous in their financial capability: some firms have access to collateral at lower costs. As a result, financial capability and collateral requirements enter together with productivity in the expression of the equilibrium firm-level markup. At the aggregate level, the model shows that tighter credit constraints in the form of higher collateral requirements mitigate the pro-competitive effect of trade. We validate our theoretical results capitalizing on a representative sample of manufacturing firms surveyed across a subset of European countries during the financial crisis. Guided by theory, we estimate for each firm financial capability, TFP and markups. We then employ those estimates to structurally retrieve from the model a firm-specific measure of collateral requirements (a proxy of credit constraint), and test our main propositions.
我们扩展了垄断竞争企业生产率异质性和内生加价的框架(如Melitz和Ottaviano, 2008),以纳入金融摩擦的存在。在生产之前,企业需要获得必要的贷款来支付部分生产成本,为此他们必须以有形资产的形式担保。除了生产率,企业的财务能力也各不相同:一些企业能够以较低的成本获得抵押品。因此,财务能力和抵押品要求与生产率一起进入均衡企业水平加价的表达。在总体水平上,该模型表明,以更高抵押品要求的形式出现的更严格的信贷约束减轻了贸易的促进竞争效应。我们验证了我们的理论结果资本化的制造业企业的代表性样本调查在一个子集的欧洲国家在金融危机期间。在理论的指导下,我们估计了每家公司的财务能力、TFP和利润率。然后,我们利用这些估计从模型中结构化地检索企业特定的抵押品要求度量(信贷约束的代理),并测试我们的主要命题。
{"title":"Markups, Productivity and the Financial Capability of Firms","authors":"C. Altomonte, Domenico Favoino, T. Sonno","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2973195","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2973195","url":null,"abstract":"We extend a framework of monopolistically competitive firms heterogeneous in productivity and with endogenous markups (as in Melitz and Ottaviano, 2008) to incorporate the presence of financial frictions. Before producing, firms need to obtain a loan necessary to cover part of production costs, for which they have to pledge collateral in the form of tangible assets. In addition to productivity, firms are also heterogeneous in their financial capability: some firms have access to collateral at lower costs. As a result, financial capability and collateral requirements enter together with productivity in the expression of the equilibrium firm-level markup. At the aggregate level, the model shows that tighter credit constraints in the form of higher collateral requirements mitigate the pro-competitive effect of trade. We validate our theoretical results capitalizing on a representative sample of manufacturing firms surveyed across a subset of European countries during the financial crisis. Guided by theory, we estimate for each firm financial capability, TFP and markups. We then employ those estimates to structurally retrieve from the model a firm-specific measure of collateral requirements (a proxy of credit constraint), and test our main propositions.","PeriodicalId":237187,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Production; Cost; Capital & Total Factor Productivity; Value Theory (Topic)","volume":"45 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116344454","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Testing R&D-Based Endogenous Growth Models 基于研发的内生增长模型检验
P. Kruse-Andersen
R&D-based growth models are tested using US data for the period 1953-2014. A general growth model is developed which nests the model varieties of interest. The model implies a cointegrating relationship between multifactor productivity, research intensity, and employment. This relationship is estimated using cointegrated VAR models. The results provide evidence against the widely used fully endogenous variety and in favor of the semi-endogenous variety. Forecasts based on the empirical estimates suggest that the slowdown in US productivity growth will continue. Particularly, the annual long-run growth rate of GDP per worker converges to between zero and 1.1 pct.
基于研发的增长模型使用1953年至2014年期间的美国数据进行了测试。建立了一个通用的增长模型,其中包含了感兴趣的模型品种。该模型表明,多要素生产率、科研强度和就业之间存在协整关系。这种关系是使用协整VAR模型估计的。结果表明,广泛使用的全内源品种是不利的,半内源品种是有利的。基于实证估计的预测表明,美国生产率增长的放缓将持续下去。特别是,人均GDP的长期年增长率在零到1.1%之间趋同。
{"title":"Testing R&D-Based Endogenous Growth Models","authors":"P. Kruse-Andersen","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2947528","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2947528","url":null,"abstract":"R&D-based growth models are tested using US data for the period 1953-2014. A general growth model is developed which nests the model varieties of interest. The model implies a cointegrating relationship between multifactor productivity, research intensity, and employment. This relationship is estimated using cointegrated VAR models. The results provide evidence against the widely used fully endogenous variety and in favor of the semi-endogenous variety. Forecasts based on the empirical estimates suggest that the slowdown in US productivity growth will continue. Particularly, the annual long-run growth rate of GDP per worker converges to between zero and 1.1 pct.","PeriodicalId":237187,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Production; Cost; Capital & Total Factor Productivity; Value Theory (Topic)","volume":"9 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-04-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130818186","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Competition for Global Value Added: Export and Domestic Market Shares 全球附加值的竞争:出口和国内市场份额
R. Cezar, Duguet Adrien, G. Gaulier, V. Vicard
We propose a new “global” market share indicator that complements the traditional export market share analysis by accounting for the foreign value added embodied in the production process and for the performance of national firms on their domestic market. We also consider all the income from activities used in the production to address the manufacturing final demand, namely all activities within the manufacturing value chain. Our results show that the role of services is growing in global value chains. Interestingly, considering our global indicator makes the dynamics of market shares converge among large economies, which can be explained by a de-correlation between national and export performances. This de-correlation appears to reflect greater specialization within global manufacturing value chains.
我们提出了一个新的“全球”市场份额指标,它通过考虑体现在生产过程中的外国附加值和国家公司在其国内市场上的表现来补充传统的出口市场份额分析。我们还考虑了用于解决制造最终需求的生产活动的所有收入,即制造价值链中的所有活动。我们的研究结果表明,服务业在全球价值链中的作用正在增强。有趣的是,考虑到我们的全球指标,大型经济体之间的市场份额动态趋于一致,这可以用国家和出口表现之间的去相关性来解释。这种去相关性似乎反映了全球制造业价值链中更大的专业化。
{"title":"Competition for Global Value Added: Export and Domestic Market Shares","authors":"R. Cezar, Duguet Adrien, G. Gaulier, V. Vicard","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2983674","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2983674","url":null,"abstract":"We propose a new “global” market share indicator that complements the traditional export market share analysis by accounting for the foreign value added embodied in the production process and for the performance of national firms on their domestic market. We also consider all the income from activities used in the production to address the manufacturing final demand, namely all activities within the manufacturing value chain. Our results show that the role of services is growing in global value chains. Interestingly, considering our global indicator makes the dynamics of market shares converge among large economies, which can be explained by a de-correlation between national and export performances. This de-correlation appears to reflect greater specialization within global manufacturing value chains.","PeriodicalId":237187,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Production; Cost; Capital & Total Factor Productivity; Value Theory (Topic)","volume":"25 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123710691","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
The Impact of Investment in Knowledge-Based Capital on Productivity: Firm-Level Evidence from Ireland 知识资本投资对生产力的影响:来自爱尔兰的企业层面证据
Mattia Di Ubaldo, Iulia Siedschlag
This paper examines the impact of investment in knowledge-based capital on firm productivity. The analysis is based on a dynamic econometric model estimated with micro-data from Ireland over the period 2006-2012. We use broad measures of investment in knowledge-based capital which include expenditures on R&D, and on non-R&D intangible assets such as computer software, copyrights, patents and licences, royalties and organisational capital. The results indicate that on average, over and above other factors, an increase in investment in knowledge-based capital of 10 per cent increases firm productivity by 2 per cent. The research results indicate that productivity gains linked to investment in KBC are larger for Irish-owned firms in comparison to foreign-owned firms. Further, the estimates indicate that firms’ productivity is more responsive to investment in R&D than to investment in non-R&D intangible assets.
本文考察了知识资本投资对企业生产率的影响。该分析基于爱尔兰2006-2012年期间微观数据估算的动态计量经济模型。我们采用广泛的方法来衡量知识资本的投资,包括研发支出,以及非研发无形资产(如计算机软件、版权、专利和许可、特许权使用费和组织资本)的支出。研究结果表明,在其他因素之外,平均而言,对知识资本的投资增加10%,企业生产率就会提高2%。研究结果表明,与外资企业相比,爱尔兰企业与知识资本投资相关的生产率提高幅度更大。此外,研究结果表明,企业生产率对研发投资的响应比对非研发无形资产投资的响应更大。
{"title":"The Impact of Investment in Knowledge-Based Capital on Productivity: Firm-Level Evidence from Ireland","authors":"Mattia Di Ubaldo, Iulia Siedschlag","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3021993","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3021993","url":null,"abstract":"This paper examines the impact of investment in knowledge-based capital on firm productivity. The analysis is based on a dynamic econometric model estimated with micro-data from Ireland over the period 2006-2012. We use broad measures of investment in knowledge-based capital which include expenditures on R&D, and on non-R&D intangible assets such as computer software, copyrights, patents and licences, royalties and organisational capital. The results indicate that on average, over and above other factors, an increase in investment in knowledge-based capital of 10 per cent increases firm productivity by 2 per cent. The research results indicate that productivity gains linked to investment in KBC are larger for Irish-owned firms in comparison to foreign-owned firms. Further, the estimates indicate that firms’ productivity is more responsive to investment in R&D than to investment in non-R&D intangible assets.","PeriodicalId":237187,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Production; Cost; Capital & Total Factor Productivity; Value Theory (Topic)","volume":"73 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125982744","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Distortions and the Structure of the World Economy 扭曲与世界经济结构
Lorenzo Caliendo, F. Parro, Aleh Tsyvinski
We model the world economy as one system of endogenous input-output relationships subject to frictions and study how the world’s input-output structure and world’s GDP change due to changes in frictions. We derive a sufficient statistic to identify frictions from the observed world input-output matrix, which we fully match for the year 2011. We show how changes in internal frictions impact the whole structure of the world’s economy and that they have a much larger effect on world’s GDP than external frictions. We also use our approach to study the role of internal frictions during the Great Recession of 2007–2009. (JEL D57, E16, E23, E32, F41, G01)
我们将世界经济建模为一个受摩擦影响的内生投入产出关系系统,并研究了世界投入产出结构和世界GDP如何随着摩擦的变化而变化。我们从观察到的世界投入产出矩阵中得出了一个足够的统计数据来识别摩擦,我们在2011年完全匹配。我们展示了内部摩擦的变化如何影响世界经济的整体结构,并且它们对世界GDP的影响要比外部摩擦大得多。我们还使用我们的方法研究了2007-2009年大衰退期间内部摩擦的作用。(jd57, e16, e23, e32, f41, g01)
{"title":"Distortions and the Structure of the World Economy","authors":"Lorenzo Caliendo, F. Parro, Aleh Tsyvinski","doi":"10.3386/W23332","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.3386/W23332","url":null,"abstract":"We model the world economy as one system of endogenous input-output relationships subject to frictions and study how the world’s input-output structure and world’s GDP change due to changes in frictions. We derive a sufficient statistic to identify frictions from the observed world input-output matrix, which we fully match for the year 2011. We show how changes in internal frictions impact the whole structure of the world’s economy and that they have a much larger effect on world’s GDP than external frictions. We also use our approach to study the role of internal frictions during the Great Recession of 2007–2009. (JEL D57, E16, E23, E32, F41, G01)","PeriodicalId":237187,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Production; Cost; Capital & Total Factor Productivity; Value Theory (Topic)","volume":"14 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123200872","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 31
The pure advantage of risk in production 风险在生产中的纯粹优势
Michael Mandler
Increases in the riskiness of the productivity of a technology bring a benefit along with the cost of raising the variability of consumption. If the productivity realization is large the technology will be used but if it is small the technology can be shelved in favor of other technologies. This asymmetry implies that increases in risk raise total expected output and can be Pareto-improving (even for risk-averse agents) in contrast to the effect of riskier endowments. The observed expected output of risky technologies, however, will be less than that of safer technologies: empirical estimates of expected output are therefore a poor measure of efficiency. Risky production sets can be placed into a classical general equilibrium model in which firms will appropriate the gains to greater risk and choose the riskier technologies. The gains to risk can thus be delivered by markets and do not have to spread as an externality.
一项技术的生产力风险的增加带来了好处,同时也增加了消费可变性的成本。如果生产力实现大,技术将被使用,但如果它是小的,技术可以搁置,有利于其他技术。这种不对称意味着,与风险禀赋的影响相比,风险的增加提高了总预期产出,并且可能是帕累托改善的(即使对风险厌恶者也是如此)。然而,观察到的风险技术的预期产出将少于安全技术的预期产出:因此,对预期产出的经验估计是衡量效率的不良指标。风险生产集可以被置于经典的一般均衡模型中,在该模型中,企业将把收益用于更大的风险,并选择风险更高的技术。因此,风险收益可以由市场传递,而不必作为外部性扩散。
{"title":"The pure advantage of risk in production","authors":"Michael Mandler","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2707786","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2707786","url":null,"abstract":"Increases in the riskiness of the productivity of a technology bring a benefit along with the cost of raising the variability of consumption. If the productivity realization is large the technology will be used but if it is small the technology can be shelved in favor of other technologies. This asymmetry implies that increases in risk raise total expected output and can be Pareto-improving (even for risk-averse agents) in contrast to the effect of riskier endowments. The observed expected output of risky technologies, however, will be less than that of safer technologies: empirical estimates of expected output are therefore a poor measure of efficiency. Risky production sets can be placed into a classical general equilibrium model in which firms will appropriate the gains to greater risk and choose the riskier technologies. The gains to risk can thus be delivered by markets and do not have to spread as an externality.","PeriodicalId":237187,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Production; Cost; Capital & Total Factor Productivity; Value Theory (Topic)","volume":"10 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130782468","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
How Downstream Retailer Merger Affects Upstream Manufacture and Downstream Retail Markets? A Generalized Theorem and Applications to Different Market Types 下游零售商合并如何影响上游制造业和下游零售市场?一个广义定理及其在不同市场类型中的应用
Ziyi Qiu
This paper studies how the merger of downstream retail firms shall affect the market structures in both the upstream manufacture and downstream retail markets. By allowing downstream retail firms to merge, this paper studies the upstream manufacture firms' endogenous choices of product qualities and downstream retail firms' endogenous choices of retail prices pre- and post-merger. The paper finds that the post-merger retail prices shall increase for both the merged and non-merging products. The market shares shall decrease for the merged products and shall increase for the non-merging products. The adjustments of post-merger product qualities shall depend on the pre-merger market shares, consumer's preference over product quality and upstream manufacture firms' marginal and fixed costs of production. A generalized theorem is provided to characterize conditions to predict all possible post-merger changes of market shares, product qualities and retail prices for both the merged and non-merging products, under the cases when retail firms sell either single or multiple products. The paper also applies the general theorem to study particular market types: information goods and service goods markets.
本文研究了下游零售企业合并对上游制造市场和下游零售市场的市场结构的影响。本文通过允许下游零售企业并购,研究了上游制造企业并购前后对产品质量的内生选择和下游零售企业并购前后对零售价格的内生选择。研究发现,合并后产品和未合并产品的零售价格都有上涨趋势。合并产品的市场份额减少,未合并产品的市场份额增加。并购后产品质量的调整取决于并购前的市场份额、消费者对产品质量的偏好以及上游制造企业的边际生产成本和固定生产成本。在零售企业销售单一或多种产品的情况下,提供了一个广义定理来描述条件,以预测合并后和非合并产品的市场份额、产品质量和零售价格的所有可能变化。本文还将一般定理应用于特定的市场类型:信息产品市场和服务产品市场。
{"title":"How Downstream Retailer Merger Affects Upstream Manufacture and Downstream Retail Markets? A Generalized Theorem and Applications to Different Market Types","authors":"Ziyi Qiu","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2994148","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2994148","url":null,"abstract":"This paper studies how the merger of downstream retail firms shall affect the market structures in both the upstream manufacture and downstream retail markets. By allowing downstream retail firms to merge, this paper studies the upstream manufacture firms' endogenous choices of product qualities and downstream retail firms' endogenous choices of retail prices pre- and post-merger. The paper finds that the post-merger retail prices shall increase for both the merged and non-merging products. The market shares shall decrease for the merged products and shall increase for the non-merging products. The adjustments of post-merger product qualities shall depend on the pre-merger market shares, consumer's preference over product quality and upstream manufacture firms' marginal and fixed costs of production. A generalized theorem is provided to characterize conditions to predict all possible post-merger changes of market shares, product qualities and retail prices for both the merged and non-merging products, under the cases when retail firms sell either single or multiple products. The paper also applies the general theorem to study particular market types: information goods and service goods markets.","PeriodicalId":237187,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Production; Cost; Capital & Total Factor Productivity; Value Theory (Topic)","volume":"6 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130850466","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Characterizing Global Value Chains: Production Length and Upstreamness 全球价值链的特征:生产长度和上游
Zhi Wang, S. Wei, Xinding Yu, K. Zhu
We develop a new set of country-sector level indicators of Global Value Chains (GVCs) characteristics in terms of average production length, and relative “upstreamness” on a production network, which we argue are better than the existing ones in the literature. We distinguish production activities into four types: those whose value added is both generated and absorbed within the country, those whose value-added crosses borders only once for consumption, those whose value added crosses borders only once for production, and those whose value added crosses borders more than once. Based on such an accounting framework, we further decompose total production length into different segments. Using these measures, we characterize cross-country production sharing patterns and their evolution for 56 sectors and 44 countries over 2000-2014. While the production chain has become longer for the world as a whole, there are interesting variations across countries and sectors.
我们在平均生产长度和生产网络的相对“上游”方面开发了一套新的全球价值链(GVCs)特征的国家-部门层面指标,我们认为这些指标优于现有文献中的指标。我们将生产活动分为四种类型:那些附加值既在国内产生又在国内吸收的生产活动,那些附加值只跨越一次国界用于消费的生产活动,那些附加值只跨越一次国界用于生产的生产活动,以及那些附加值不止一次跨越国界的生产活动。基于这样的核算框架,我们进一步将总生产长度分解为不同的部分。利用这些措施,我们描述了2000-2014年间44个国家56个部门的跨国生产共享模式及其演变。虽然整个世界的生产链变得更长了,但不同国家和行业之间存在着有趣的差异。
{"title":"Characterizing Global Value Chains: Production Length and Upstreamness","authors":"Zhi Wang, S. Wei, Xinding Yu, K. Zhu","doi":"10.3386/W23261","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.3386/W23261","url":null,"abstract":"We develop a new set of country-sector level indicators of Global Value Chains (GVCs) characteristics in terms of average production length, and relative “upstreamness” on a production network, which we argue are better than the existing ones in the literature. We distinguish production activities into four types: those whose value added is both generated and absorbed within the country, those whose value-added crosses borders only once for consumption, those whose value added crosses borders only once for production, and those whose value added crosses borders more than once. Based on such an accounting framework, we further decompose total production length into different segments. Using these measures, we characterize cross-country production sharing patterns and their evolution for 56 sectors and 44 countries over 2000-2014. While the production chain has become longer for the world as a whole, there are interesting variations across countries and sectors.","PeriodicalId":237187,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Production; Cost; Capital & Total Factor Productivity; Value Theory (Topic)","volume":"151 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2017-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"132418574","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 161
期刊
ERN: Production; Cost; Capital & Total Factor Productivity; Value Theory (Topic)
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1