首页 > 最新文献

ERN: Other Microeconomics: Decision-Making under Risk & Uncertainty (Topic)最新文献

英文 中文
The Effect of Paper Versus Realized Losses on Subsequent Risktaking: Field Evidence From Casino Gambling 纸面损失与实际损失对后续风险承担的影响:来自赌场赌博的现场证据
Pub Date : 2020-01-08 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3515981
Philippe Meier, Raphael Flepp, M. Rüdisser, E. Franck
In this paper, we test the realization effect, i.e., that risk-taking increases after a paper loss, whereas risk-taking decreases after a realized loss, using gambling data from a real casino. During a particular casino visit, losses are likely perceived as paper losses because the chance to offset prior losses remains effective until leaving the casino. However, when casino customers leave the casino, the final account balance is realized. Using individual-level slot machine gambling records, we find that risk-taking after paper losses increases during a visit and that this effect is more pronounced for larger losses. Conversely, risk-taking across multiple visits is not altered if the realized losses are comparatively small, whereas risk-taking is reduced if realized losses are comparatively large.
在本文中,我们使用来自真实赌场的赌博数据来检验实现效应,即在账面损失后风险承担增加,而在实现损失后风险承担减少。在特定的赌场访问期间,损失可能被视为账面损失,因为抵销先前损失的机会在离开赌场之前仍然有效。然而,当赌场客户离开赌场时,最终的账户余额就实现了。使用个人层面的老虎机赌博记录,我们发现在访问期间,纸面损失后的冒险行为增加,并且这种影响对于较大的损失更为明显。相反,如果已实现的损失相对较小,则多次访问的风险承担不会改变,而如果已实现的损失相对较大,则风险承担会减少。
{"title":"The Effect of Paper Versus Realized Losses on Subsequent Risktaking: Field Evidence From Casino Gambling","authors":"Philippe Meier, Raphael Flepp, M. Rüdisser, E. Franck","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3515981","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3515981","url":null,"abstract":"In this paper, we test the realization effect, i.e., that risk-taking increases after a paper loss, whereas risk-taking decreases after a realized loss, using gambling data from a real casino. During a particular casino visit, losses are likely perceived as paper losses because the chance to offset prior losses remains effective until leaving the casino. However, when casino customers leave the casino, the final account balance is realized. Using individual-level slot machine gambling records, we find that risk-taking after paper losses increases during a visit and that this effect is more pronounced for larger losses. Conversely, risk-taking across multiple visits is not altered if the realized losses are comparatively small, whereas risk-taking is reduced if realized losses are comparatively large.","PeriodicalId":281936,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Microeconomics: Decision-Making under Risk & Uncertainty (Topic)","volume":"9 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-01-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123253065","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Pareto-Optimal Insurance Contracts With Premium Budget and Minimum Charge Constraints 具有保费预算和最低收费约束的帕累托最优保险契约
Pub Date : 2019-12-23 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3508838
Alexandru V. Asimit, K. Cheung, W. F. Chong, Junlei Hu
Abstract In view of the fact that minimum charge and premium budget constraints are natural economic considerations in any risk-transfer between the insurance buyer and seller, this paper revisits the optimal insurance contract design problem in terms of Pareto optimality with imposing these practical constraints. Pareto optimal insurance contracts, with indemnity schedule and premium payment, are solved in the cases when the risk preferences of the buyer and seller are given by Value-at-Risk or Tail Value-at-Risk. The effect of our constraints and the relative bargaining powers of the buyer and seller on the Pareto optimal insurance contracts are highlighted. Numerical experiments are employed to further examine these effects for some given risk preferences.
摘要:考虑到最低费用和保费预算约束是保险买卖双方风险转移的自然经济考虑因素,本文从帕累托最优的角度重新研究了在这些实际约束条件下的最优保险契约设计问题。当买卖双方的风险偏好分别由风险价值或尾部风险价值给出时,求解了具有赔付额和赔付额的帕累托最优保险契约。强调了约束条件和买卖双方的相对议价能力对帕累托最优保险契约的影响。数值实验采用进一步检验这些影响对某些给定的风险偏好。
{"title":"Pareto-Optimal Insurance Contracts With Premium Budget and Minimum Charge Constraints","authors":"Alexandru V. Asimit, K. Cheung, W. F. Chong, Junlei Hu","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3508838","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3508838","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract In view of the fact that minimum charge and premium budget constraints are natural economic considerations in any risk-transfer between the insurance buyer and seller, this paper revisits the optimal insurance contract design problem in terms of Pareto optimality with imposing these practical constraints. Pareto optimal insurance contracts, with indemnity schedule and premium payment, are solved in the cases when the risk preferences of the buyer and seller are given by Value-at-Risk or Tail Value-at-Risk. The effect of our constraints and the relative bargaining powers of the buyer and seller on the Pareto optimal insurance contracts are highlighted. Numerical experiments are employed to further examine these effects for some given risk preferences.","PeriodicalId":281936,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Microeconomics: Decision-Making under Risk & Uncertainty (Topic)","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-12-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128444341","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 8
Paradoxes with Optimal Investment Rules 最优投资规则的悖论
Pub Date : 2019-12-16 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3504401
H. Levy
Assuming risk aversion, the Second degree Stochastic Dominance (SSD) criterion is employed for prospect ranking. However, in some cases the optimal SSD rule cannot distinguish between two alternative prospects when it is obvious that one prospect is preferred by practically all risk averters-a paradoxical result. The optimal Almost SSD (ASSD) rule which aims to avoid such paradoxical results also fails to do so. We suggest a new rule, the General ASSD rule (GASSD) to replace the ASSD rule, which in turn, solves the SSD as well the ASSD existing and potential paradoxes. The GASSD rule, unlike the SSD and ASSD rules, takes into account the magnitude of the mean return difference of the two prospects under consideration. The ASSD and the GASSD rules coincide only when these two means are equal.
在风险规避的前提下,采用二次随机优势(SSD)准则进行前景排序。然而,在某些情况下,最优SSD规则不能区分两个备选前景,因为很明显,几乎所有风险规避者都偏爱其中一个前景——这是一个矛盾的结果。旨在避免这种矛盾结果的最优几乎SSD (ASSD)规则也未能做到这一点。我们建议一个新的规则,通用ASSD规则(GASSD)来取代ASSD规则,这反过来又解决了SSD以及ASSD现有和潜在的悖论。与SSD和ASSD规则不同,GASSD规则考虑了所考虑的两个前景的平均回报差异的大小。只有当这两个平均值相等时,ASSD和GASSD规则才会重合。
{"title":"Paradoxes with Optimal Investment Rules","authors":"H. Levy","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3504401","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3504401","url":null,"abstract":"Assuming risk aversion, the Second degree Stochastic Dominance (SSD) criterion is employed for prospect ranking. However, in some cases the optimal SSD rule cannot distinguish between two alternative prospects when it is obvious that one prospect is preferred by practically all risk averters-a paradoxical result. The optimal Almost SSD (ASSD) rule which aims to avoid such paradoxical results also fails to do so. We suggest a new rule, the General ASSD rule (GASSD) to replace the ASSD rule, which in turn, solves the SSD as well the ASSD existing and potential paradoxes. The GASSD rule, unlike the SSD and ASSD rules, takes into account the magnitude of the mean return difference of the two prospects under consideration. The ASSD and the GASSD rules coincide only when these two means are equal.","PeriodicalId":281936,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Microeconomics: Decision-Making under Risk & Uncertainty (Topic)","volume":"7 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-12-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126723786","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Funding Conditions and Insurance Stock Returns: Do Insurance Stocks Really Benefit from Rising Interest Rate Regimes? 融资条件与保险股回报:保险股真的受益于利率上升机制吗?
Tyler K. Jensen, Robert R. Johnson, Michael J. McNamara
We examine funding conditions and U.S. insurance company stock returns. Although constrained funding conditions, signaled by restrictive Federal Reserve monetary policy, correspond with increases in the future payouts of fixed‐income securities held by insurance firms and potentially provide value through the liability side of insurer balance sheets, they also decrease the values of securities currently held in insurer portfolios. Prior research finds that restrictive policy has a negative effect on equity returns in general. Our results suggest the negative impacts of constrained funding environments outweigh the potential positives, as insurance company stock returns are significantly lower during periods of constrained funding. This effect varies within a given funding state and also across insurer type. The effect is strongest during the first 3 months of a constrained funding environment and for life and health insurers—insurer types with longer portfolio durations. For property and liability (P&L) insurers, lower stock return performance only exists in the first 3 months of a constrained funding environment. In the subsequent months, P&L insurers actually have higher stock returns during constrained periods, consistent with their typically shorter duration asset portfolios, which are more quickly rolled over into new higher‐yielding securities.
我们考察了资金状况和美国保险公司的股票回报。尽管资金条件受限(美联储限制性货币政策的信号)与保险公司持有的固定收益证券的未来支出增加相对应,并可能通过保险公司资产负债表的负债部分提供价值,但它们也降低了保险公司投资组合中当前持有的证券的价值。以往的研究发现,限制性政策总体上对股权收益有负面影响。我们的研究结果表明,资金约束环境的负面影响超过了潜在的积极影响,因为保险公司的股票回报在资金约束期间显着降低。这种影响在给定的资助状态和不同的保险公司类型中是不同的。在资金环境受限的前3个月,以及投资组合存续期较长的人寿和健康保险公司,这种影响最为明显。对于财产和责任(P&L)保险公司来说,较低的股票回报表现只存在于资金环境受限的前3个月。在随后的几个月里,P&L保险公司在受限时期实际上有更高的股票回报,这与他们通常较短的资产组合一致,这些资产组合可以更快地转到新的更高收益的证券中。
{"title":"Funding Conditions and Insurance Stock Returns: Do Insurance Stocks Really Benefit from Rising Interest Rate Regimes?","authors":"Tyler K. Jensen, Robert R. Johnson, Michael J. McNamara","doi":"10.1111/rmir.12133","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/rmir.12133","url":null,"abstract":"We examine funding conditions and U.S. insurance company stock returns. Although constrained funding conditions, signaled by restrictive Federal Reserve monetary policy, correspond with increases in the future payouts of fixed‐income securities held by insurance firms and potentially provide value through the liability side of insurer balance sheets, they also decrease the values of securities currently held in insurer portfolios. Prior research finds that restrictive policy has a negative effect on equity returns in general. Our results suggest the negative impacts of constrained funding environments outweigh the potential positives, as insurance company stock returns are significantly lower during periods of constrained funding. This effect varies within a given funding state and also across insurer type. The effect is strongest during the first 3 months of a constrained funding environment and for life and health insurers—insurer types with longer portfolio durations. For property and liability (P&L) insurers, lower stock return performance only exists in the first 3 months of a constrained funding environment. In the subsequent months, P&L insurers actually have higher stock returns during constrained periods, consistent with their typically shorter duration asset portfolios, which are more quickly rolled over into new higher‐yielding securities.","PeriodicalId":281936,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Microeconomics: Decision-Making under Risk & Uncertainty (Topic)","volume":"279 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"114567179","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Competitive Information Discovery 竞争信息发现
Pub Date : 2019-12-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3035373
Michael Mandler
In classical models of markets, the state of nature is revealed regardless of the actions agents take. If instead agents can uncover information they will determine which states can be distinguished and thus which goods are traded. Competitive equilibria can then be inefficient. One source of inefficiency is self-confirmation: price expectations can dissuade agents from discovering the information that would invalidate their expectations. Inefficiency can also occur if agents have diverse priors or fail to be risk-averse, possibilities that normally would be irrelevant for the first welfare theorem. Restoring optimality requires these assumptions and a competitive price rule must hold: the prices anticipated when agents contemplate an information discovery must be proportional to the probabilities of the events that could be revealed. In the most important application of information discovery, experimenting with new technologies, our results show that competitive markets can lead firms to experiment efficiently.
在经典的市场模型中,无论主体采取何种行动,自然状态都会被揭示出来。相反,如果代理人能够发现信息,他们将决定哪些州可以区分,从而决定哪些商品可以交易。因此,竞争均衡可能是低效的。低效率的一个来源是自我确认:价格预期可以阻止代理人发现会使他们的预期无效的信息。如果代理人有不同的先验或不能规避风险,效率低下也会发生,这些可能性通常与第一个福利定理无关。恢复最优性需要这些假设,并且竞争性价格规则必须成立:当代理考虑信息发现时,预期的价格必须与可能揭示的事件的概率成正比。在信息发现最重要的应用——新技术实验中,我们的研究结果表明,竞争市场可以引导企业进行有效的实验。
{"title":"Competitive Information Discovery","authors":"Michael Mandler","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3035373","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3035373","url":null,"abstract":"In classical models of markets, the state of nature is revealed regardless of the actions agents take. If instead agents can uncover information they will determine which states can be distinguished and thus which goods are traded. Competitive equilibria can then be inefficient. One source of inefficiency is self-confirmation: price expectations can dissuade agents from discovering the information that would invalidate their expectations. Inefficiency can also occur if agents have diverse priors or fail to be risk-averse, possibilities that normally would be irrelevant for the first welfare theorem. Restoring optimality requires these assumptions and a competitive price rule must hold: the prices anticipated when agents contemplate an information discovery must be proportional to the probabilities of the events that could be revealed. In the most important application of information discovery, experimenting with new technologies, our results show that competitive markets can lead firms to experiment efficiently.","PeriodicalId":281936,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Microeconomics: Decision-Making under Risk & Uncertainty (Topic)","volume":"126 2 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"129754764","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
On the Need for an Extensive Revision of the ‘Imprecise Probabilities’ Entry regarding Boole and Keynes in The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Spring, 2019 Edition) in the ‘ Supplement to Imprecise Probabilities-Historical appendix: Theories of Imprecise Belief.’ 《斯坦福大学哲学百科全书》(2019年春季版)“不精确概率补充——历史附录:不精确信念理论”中关于布尔和凯恩斯的“不精确概率”条目需要进行广泛修订。
Pub Date : 2019-11-30 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3495817
M. E. Brady
The "Supplement to Imprecise Probabilities-Historical appendix: Theories of imprecise belief " presents a severely inaccurate representation of Keynes’s contributions to imprecise probability. It also completely ignores the seminal, path breaking contributions to imprecise probability made by George Boole in his 1854 The Laws of Thought in chapters 16-21. The error is compounded with regard to Keynes because Keynes’s entire system of logical probability in the A Treatise on Probability is built on Boole’s exposition of lower (greatest lower bound)-upper (least upper bound) probabilities that Keynes used in Parts II and III of the A Treatise on Probability to develop his method of inexact measurement and approximation using interval valued probability.

It is in chapter 15 of the TP on pp. 161-163, as well as in chapter 16, 17, 20 and 22 of the TP, in a very detailed, mathematical analysis of his earlier, brief, graphical exposition in chapter III of the TP, that an analysis of imprecise probability was provided by Keynes. Keynes, through his adaptation of Boole’s original approach, that Keynes had adapted and improved upon in the same manner that Wilbraham had improved the Boolean approach in 1854, allowed for him to provide an explicit, imprecise approach to probability showing the importance of non additivity in 1921.

In 1986 and 1996,Theodore Hailparin showed decisively that the Boole-Keynes approach involved the use of an early version of linear programming techniques, using an initial, basic, feasible solution, involving primal and dual maximization and minimization problems with constraints that were both equalities (linear) and inequalities (nonlinear) [Keynes’s inequations].

Keynes had already solved the mystery of the diagram on page 39 of chapter III in 1921(Actually,the same analysis is provided by Keynes in the 1908 Cambridge Fellowship Dissertation. This Fellowship Dissertation would have earned Keynes a Ph.D in Applied Mathematics at any University in the world at that time if he had been interested in obtaining a Ph.D,which he was not) in chapter 15 with additional problems solved in chapters 16, 17, 20, and 22 of the TP.

Keynes’s analysis on pp.161-163 is straightforward if the reader of the TP has the requisite mathematical training and knowledge.It is highly likely that no economist ,who has written on Keynes’s TP,has such knowledge.

The presentation of Keynes’s theory in the appendix to the entry on’ Imprecise Probability’ is completely misleading. The failure to mention Boole’s path breaking work is a lacuna that can only be remedied by an extensive revision. Hopefully,such a revision will finally set right the historical record regarding the original and detailed mathematical and logical contributions made by Keynes in 1907,1908 and 1921, and by Boole in 1854.

“对不精确概率的补充——历史附录:不精确信念的理论”对凯恩斯对不精确概率的贡献提出了严重不准确的表述。它也完全忽略了乔治·布尔(George Boole)在1854年出版的《思想法则》(the Laws of Thought)第16-21章中对不精确概率的开创性贡献。对于凯恩斯来说,这个错误是复杂的,因为凯恩斯在《概率论》中的整个逻辑概率系统是建立在布尔对下界(最大下界)-上界(最小上界)概率的阐述之上的,凯恩斯在《概率论》的第二部分和第三部分中使用了这种概率来发展他的不精确测量和使用区间值概率的近似方法。在第15章161-163页,以及第16,17,20和22章,在一个非常详细的数学分析中,在第3章,凯恩斯提供了一个不精确概率的分析。凯恩斯,通过他对布尔原始方法的改编,凯恩斯改编和改进了布尔方法的方式与1854年威尔伯拉罕改进布尔方法的方式相同,这使得他在1921年提供了一个明确的,不精确的概率方法,显示了不可加性的重要性。1986年和1996年,Theodore Hailparin果断地表明,布尔-凯恩斯方法涉及使用早期版本的线性规划技术,使用初始的、基本的、可行的解决方案,涉及具有等式(线性)和不等式(非线性)约束的原始和对偶最大化和最小化问题[凯恩斯不等式]。在1921年,凯恩斯已经解决了第三章第39页的图表之谜(实际上,凯恩斯在1908年的剑桥奖学金论文中提供了同样的分析。如果凯恩斯对获得博士学位感兴趣的话,这篇奖学金论文可以让他在当时世界上任何一所大学获得应用数学博士学位(他没有),在第15章中,在第16、17、20和22章中解决了额外的问题。如果读者具备必要的数学训练和知识,凯恩斯对第161-163页的分析就会一目了然。很有可能,没有一个写过凯恩斯理论的经济学家有这样的知识。凯恩斯的理论在“不精确概率”条目的附录中是完全误导的。没有提到布尔的开创性工作是一个空白,只能通过广泛的修订来弥补。有希望的是,这样的修订将最终纠正历史记录,关于凯恩斯在1907年、1908年和1921年以及布尔在1854年所做的原始而详细的数学和逻辑贡献。
{"title":"On the Need for an Extensive Revision of the ‘Imprecise Probabilities’ Entry regarding Boole and Keynes in The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Spring, 2019 Edition) in the ‘ Supplement to Imprecise Probabilities-Historical appendix: Theories of Imprecise Belief.’","authors":"M. E. Brady","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3495817","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3495817","url":null,"abstract":"The \"Supplement to Imprecise Probabilities-Historical appendix: Theories of imprecise belief \" presents a severely inaccurate representation of Keynes’s contributions to imprecise probability. It also completely ignores the seminal, path breaking contributions to imprecise probability made by George Boole in his 1854 The Laws of Thought in chapters 16-21. The error is compounded with regard to Keynes because Keynes’s entire system of logical probability in the A Treatise on Probability is built on Boole’s exposition of lower (greatest lower bound)-upper (least upper bound) probabilities that Keynes used in Parts II and III of the A Treatise on Probability to develop his method of inexact measurement and approximation using interval valued probability.<br><br>It is in chapter 15 of the TP on pp. 161-163, as well as in chapter 16, 17, 20 and 22 of the TP, in a very detailed, mathematical analysis of his earlier, brief, graphical exposition in chapter III of the TP, that an analysis of imprecise probability was provided by Keynes. Keynes, through his adaptation of Boole’s original approach, that Keynes had adapted and improved upon in the same manner that Wilbraham had improved the Boolean approach in 1854, allowed for him to provide an explicit, imprecise approach to probability showing the importance of non additivity in 1921.<br><br>In 1986 and 1996,Theodore Hailparin showed decisively that the Boole-Keynes approach involved the use of an early version of linear programming techniques, using an initial, basic, feasible solution, involving primal and dual maximization and minimization problems with constraints that were both equalities (linear) and inequalities (nonlinear) [Keynes’s inequations].<br><br>Keynes had already solved the mystery of the diagram on page 39 of chapter III in 1921(Actually,the same analysis is provided by Keynes in the 1908 Cambridge Fellowship Dissertation. This Fellowship Dissertation would have earned Keynes a Ph.D in Applied Mathematics at any University in the world at that time if he had been interested in obtaining a Ph.D,which he was not) in chapter 15 with additional problems solved in chapters 16, 17, 20, and 22 of the TP.<br><br>Keynes’s analysis on pp.161-163 is straightforward if the reader of the TP has the requisite mathematical training and knowledge.It is highly likely that no economist ,who has written on Keynes’s TP,has such knowledge.<br><br>The presentation of Keynes’s theory in the appendix to the entry on’ Imprecise Probability’ is completely misleading. The failure to mention Boole’s path breaking work is a lacuna that can only be remedied by an extensive revision. Hopefully,such a revision will finally set right the historical record regarding the original and detailed mathematical and logical contributions made by Keynes in 1907,1908 and 1921, and by Boole in 1854. <br><br>","PeriodicalId":281936,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Microeconomics: Decision-Making under Risk & Uncertainty (Topic)","volume":"74 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-11-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125869498","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
On the Erroneous Heterodox and Post Keynesian Belief That Keynes’s Interval Valued Decision Theory in the A Treatise on Probability (1921) Was an Ordinal Theory of Probability 论1921年《概率论》中凯恩斯的区间值决策理论是序数概率论的错误异端和后凯恩斯主义信念
Pub Date : 2019-11-24 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3492506
M. E. Brady
Keynes’s initial, introductory presentation of his inexact measurement, approximation approach to interval valued probability occurred on pages 38-40 of chapter III of the A Treatise on Probability. Keynes used a simple diagram on page 38 to illustrate the non linear and non additive nature of interval valued probability. He also informed the reader on pages 37-38 that the introductory analysis on pp.38-40 would be a brief analysis whereas the analysis in Part II would be a detailed analysis. Post Keynesian, Institutionalist and heterodix economists have completely ignored Keynes’s warning and completely misinterpreted and misrepresented Keynes’s introductory analysis on interval valued probability as an ordinal theory of probability.

The result of this misinterpretation and misrepresentation of Keynes’s decision theory can be seen in the response of public officials, who have been exposed to the misinterpretations and misrepresentations of heterodox economists, when they are considering how to base their country’s monetary and fiscal policy proposals on an analysis that is supposed to incorporate Keynes’s crucial positions on uncertainty and expectations.
凯恩斯在《概率论》第三章第38-40页首次介绍了他对区间值概率的不精确测量和近似方法。凯恩斯在第38页使用了一个简单的图表来说明区间值概率的非线性和非可加性。他还在第37-38页告诉读者,第38-40页的介绍性分析将是一个简短的分析,而第二部分的分析将是一个详细的分析。后凯恩斯主义、制度主义和异质经济学家完全忽视了凯恩斯的警告,完全误解和歪曲了凯恩斯将区间值概率作为序数概率论的介绍性分析。这种对凯恩斯决策理论的误解和歪曲的结果可以从政府官员的反应中看到,他们已经暴露于异端经济学家的误解和歪曲,当他们考虑如何将他们国家的货币和财政政策建议建立在应该纳入凯恩斯关于不确定性和预期的关键立场的分析基础上时。
{"title":"On the Erroneous Heterodox and Post Keynesian Belief That Keynes’s Interval Valued Decision Theory in the A Treatise on Probability (1921) Was an Ordinal Theory of Probability","authors":"M. E. Brady","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3492506","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3492506","url":null,"abstract":"Keynes’s initial, introductory presentation of his inexact measurement, approximation approach to interval valued probability occurred on pages 38-40 of chapter III of the A Treatise on Probability. Keynes used a simple diagram on page 38 to illustrate the non linear and non additive nature of interval valued probability. He also informed the reader on pages 37-38 that the introductory analysis on pp.38-40 would be a brief analysis whereas the analysis in Part II would be a detailed analysis. Post Keynesian, Institutionalist and heterodix economists have completely ignored Keynes’s warning and completely misinterpreted and misrepresented Keynes’s introductory analysis on interval valued probability as an ordinal theory of probability.<br><br>The result of this misinterpretation and misrepresentation of Keynes’s decision theory can be seen in the response of public officials, who have been exposed to the misinterpretations and misrepresentations of heterodox economists, when they are considering how to base their country’s monetary and fiscal policy proposals on an analysis that is supposed to incorporate Keynes’s crucial positions on uncertainty and expectations.","PeriodicalId":281936,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Microeconomics: Decision-Making under Risk & Uncertainty (Topic)","volume":"96 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-11-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133236390","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Banker Compensation, Relative Performance, and Bank Risk 银行家薪酬、相对绩效和银行风险
Pub Date : 2019-11-05 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3485742
Arantxa Jarque, E. Prescott
A multi-agent, moral-hazard model of a bank operating under deposit insurance and limited liability is used to analyze the connection between compensation of bank employees (below CEO) and bank risk. Limited liability with deposit insurance is a force that distorts effort down. However, the need to increase compensation to risk-averse employees in order to compensate them for extra bank risk is a force that reduces this effect. Optimal contracts use relative performance and are implementable as a wage with bonuses tied to individual and firm performance. The connection between pay for performance and bank risk depends on correlation of returns. If employee returns are uncorrelated, the form of pay is irrelevant for risk. If returns are perfectly correlated, a low wage can indicate risk. Connections to compensation regulation and characteristics of organizations are discussed.
本文采用存款保险和有限责任银行的多主体道德风险模型,分析了银行员工(CEO以下)薪酬与银行风险之间的关系。有存款保险的有限责任是一种扭曲努力的力量。然而,增加对风险厌恶的员工的薪酬,以补偿他们承担额外的银行风险,这是一种削弱这种影响的力量。最优契约使用相对绩效,并可作为工资和奖金与个人和公司绩效挂钩的形式来实施。绩效薪酬与银行风险之间的联系取决于回报的相关性。如果员工回报不相关,那么薪酬形式就与风险无关。如果回报率是完全相关的,低工资可能意味着风险。讨论了薪酬监管与组织特征之间的联系。
{"title":"Banker Compensation, Relative Performance, and Bank Risk","authors":"Arantxa Jarque, E. Prescott","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3485742","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3485742","url":null,"abstract":"A multi-agent, moral-hazard model of a bank operating under deposit insurance and limited liability is used to analyze the connection between compensation of bank employees (below CEO) and bank risk. Limited liability with deposit insurance is a force that distorts effort down. However, the need to increase compensation to risk-averse employees in order to compensate them for extra bank risk is a force that reduces this effect. Optimal contracts use relative performance and are implementable as a wage with bonuses tied to individual and firm performance. The connection between pay for performance and bank risk depends on correlation of returns. If employee returns are uncorrelated, the form of pay is irrelevant for risk. If returns are perfectly correlated, a low wage can indicate risk. Connections to compensation regulation and characteristics of organizations are discussed.","PeriodicalId":281936,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Microeconomics: Decision-Making under Risk & Uncertainty (Topic)","volume":"75 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-11-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116347079","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Coarse, Efficient Decision-Making 粗糙、高效的决策
Pub Date : 2019-11-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2494600
Michael Mandler
To minimize the cost of making decisions, an agent should use criteria to sort alternatives and each criterion should sort coarsely. To decide on a movie, for example, an agent could use one criterion that orders movies by genre categories, another by director categories, and so on, with a small number of categories in each case. The agent then needs to aggregate the criterion orderings, possibly by a weighted vote, to arrive at choices. As criteria become coarser (each criterion has fewer categories) decision-making costs fall, even though an agent must then use more criteria. The most efficient option is consequently to select the binary criteria with two categories each. This result holds even when the marginal cost of using additional categories diminishes to 0. The extensive use of coarse criteria in practice may therefore be a result of optimization rather than cognitive limitations. Binary criteria also generate choice functions that maximize rational preferences: decision-making efficiency implies rational choice.
为了使决策成本最小化,代理应该使用标准对备选方案进行排序,并且每个标准都应该进行粗略排序。例如,为了决定一部电影,代理可以使用一个标准按类型类别来订购电影,另一个标准按导演类别来订购电影,以此类推,每种情况下都有少量的类别。然后,代理需要聚合标准排序,可能是通过加权投票来得出选择。随着标准变得更粗糙(每个标准的类别更少),决策成本下降,即使代理必须使用更多的标准。因此,最有效的选择是选择二元标准,每个标准有两个类别。即使使用额外类别的边际成本减少到0,这个结果也成立。因此,在实践中广泛使用粗标准可能是优化而不是认知限制的结果。二元标准也产生了最大化理性偏好的选择函数:决策效率意味着理性选择。
{"title":"Coarse, Efficient Decision-Making","authors":"Michael Mandler","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2494600","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2494600","url":null,"abstract":"\u0000 To minimize the cost of making decisions, an agent should use criteria to sort alternatives and each criterion should sort coarsely. To decide on a movie, for example, an agent could use one criterion that orders movies by genre categories, another by director categories, and so on, with a small number of categories in each case. The agent then needs to aggregate the criterion orderings, possibly by a weighted vote, to arrive at choices. As criteria become coarser (each criterion has fewer categories) decision-making costs fall, even though an agent must then use more criteria. The most efficient option is consequently to select the binary criteria with two categories each. This result holds even when the marginal cost of using additional categories diminishes to 0. The extensive use of coarse criteria in practice may therefore be a result of optimization rather than cognitive limitations. Binary criteria also generate choice functions that maximize rational preferences: decision-making efficiency implies rational choice.","PeriodicalId":281936,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Microeconomics: Decision-Making under Risk & Uncertainty (Topic)","volume":"46 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125386874","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Inefficiency-Manipulability Tradeoff in the Parallel Mechanism 并行机构的无效率-可操控性权衡
Pub Date : 2019-10-23 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3387000
Jerry Anunrojwong
Most school choice and other matching mechanisms are based on deferred acceptance (DA) for its incentive properties. However, non-strategyproof mechanisms can dominate DA in welfare because manipulation in preference rankings can reflect the intensities of underlying cardinal preferences. In this work, we use the parallel mechanism of Chen and Kesten, which interpolates between Boston mechanism and DA, to quantify this tradeoff. While it is previously known that mechanisms that are closer to Boston mechanism are more manipulable, we show that they are also more efficient in student welfare if school priorities are weak. Our theoretical results show the inefficiency-manipulability tradeoff in the worst case, while our simulation results show the same tradeoff in the typical case.
大多数学校选择和其他匹配机制是基于延迟接受(DA)的激励性质。然而,非策略证明机制可以主导福利方面的数据分析,因为对偏好排名的操纵可以反映潜在基本偏好的强度。在这项工作中,我们使用Chen和Kesten的平行机制,它在波士顿机制和数据分析之间进行插值,以量化这种权衡。虽然以前已知的机制更接近波士顿机制更易操纵,但我们表明,如果学校优先级较弱,它们在学生福利方面也更有效。我们的理论结果显示了在最坏情况下的低效率与可操控性的权衡,而我们的模拟结果显示了在典型情况下的相同权衡。
{"title":"Inefficiency-Manipulability Tradeoff in the Parallel Mechanism","authors":"Jerry Anunrojwong","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3387000","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3387000","url":null,"abstract":"Most school choice and other matching mechanisms are based on deferred acceptance (DA) for its incentive properties. However, non-strategyproof mechanisms can dominate DA in welfare because manipulation in preference rankings can reflect the intensities of underlying cardinal preferences. In this work, we use the parallel mechanism of Chen and Kesten, which interpolates between Boston mechanism and DA, to quantify this tradeoff. While it is previously known that mechanisms that are closer to Boston mechanism are more manipulable, we show that they are also more efficient in student welfare if school priorities are weak. Our theoretical results show the inefficiency-manipulability tradeoff in the worst case, while our simulation results show the same tradeoff in the typical case.","PeriodicalId":281936,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Other Microeconomics: Decision-Making under Risk & Uncertainty (Topic)","volume":"92 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-10-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"132215963","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
ERN: Other Microeconomics: Decision-Making under Risk & Uncertainty (Topic)
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1