首页 > 最新文献

University of Southern California Legal Studies Research Paper Series最新文献

英文 中文
Post-Grant Adjudication of Drug Patents: Agency and/or Court 药物专利授予后的裁决:机构和/或法院
Pub Date : 2021-08-05 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3865804
A. Rai, Saurabh Vishnubhakat, Jorge Lemus, Erik N. Hovenkamp
The America Invents Act of 2011 (“AIA”) created a robust administrative system—the Patent Trial and Appeal Board (“PTAB”)—for challenging the validity of granted patents. Congress determined that administrative correction of errors made in initial patent grants could be cheaper and more scientifically accurate than district court litigation over patent validity. In terms of private economic value per patent, few areas of technology can match the biopharmaceutical industry. Particularly for small molecule drugs, a billion-dollar drug monopoly may be protected from competition by a relatively small number of patents. Accordingly, the social cost of invalid patents—and, by extension, the potential benefit of PTAB review—is particularly acute in the biopharmaceutical industry. Conversely, to the extent that PTAB is overly assertive and improperly targets high-quality patents, the decrease in innovation incentives may be quite problematic. To investigate the issue empirically, our paper uses several novel datasets (made publicly available via the posting of this article) to study the respective roles of the PTAB and the district courts. Our empirical findings indicate that the PTAB’s role in adjudicating small molecule patents has been quite modest, substantially more modest than its role for other types of patents. Moreover, we do not find any evidence that the PTAB targets categories of small molecule patents that are generally considered high quality. To the contrary, the PTAB does not appear to differentially target even categories of small molecule patents that are generally considered to exhibit lower quality. We also find no evidence that the PTAB is targeting small molecule patents held by small entities. We conclude by discussing paths policymakers could take if they were interested in a more active role for the PTAB in policing the validity of small molecule drug patents.
2011年美国发明法案(“AIA”)创建了一个强大的管理系统——专利审判和上诉委员会(“PTAB”)——来挑战已授予专利的有效性。国会认为,对最初专利授予中出现的错误进行行政纠正,可能比在地方法院就专利有效性提起诉讼更便宜,也更科学准确。就每项专利的私人经济价值而言,很少有技术领域可以与生物制药行业相媲美。特别是对于小分子药物,数十亿美元的药品垄断可以通过相对较少的专利保护免受竞争。因此,无效专利的社会成本,以及PTAB审查的潜在利益,在生物制药行业尤为突出。相反,在某种程度上,PTAB过于自信,不恰当地针对高质量专利,创新激励的减少可能是相当有问题的。为了从经验上调查这个问题,我们的论文使用了几个新的数据集(通过本文的发布公开提供)来研究PTAB和地方法院各自的角色。我们的实证研究结果表明,PTAB在裁决小分子专利方面的作用相当温和,比其他类型的专利的作用要温和得多。此外,我们没有发现任何证据表明PTAB针对通常被认为是高质量的小分子专利类别。相反,PTAB似乎没有区别地针对甚至是通常被认为表现出较低质量的小分子专利类别。我们也没有发现证据表明PTAB针对小实体持有的小分子专利。最后,我们讨论了政策制定者如果对PTAB在监督小分子药物专利有效性方面发挥更积极的作用感兴趣,可以采取的途径。
{"title":"Post-Grant Adjudication of Drug Patents: Agency and/or Court","authors":"A. Rai, Saurabh Vishnubhakat, Jorge Lemus, Erik N. Hovenkamp","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3865804","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3865804","url":null,"abstract":"The America Invents Act of 2011 (“AIA”) created a robust administrative system—the Patent Trial and Appeal Board (“PTAB”)—for challenging the validity of granted patents. Congress determined that administrative correction of errors made in initial patent grants could be cheaper and more scientifically accurate than district court litigation over patent validity. In terms of private economic value per patent, few areas of technology can match the biopharmaceutical industry. Particularly for small molecule drugs, a billion-dollar drug monopoly may be protected from competition by a relatively small number of patents. Accordingly, the social cost of invalid patents—and, by extension, the potential benefit of PTAB review—is particularly acute in the biopharmaceutical industry. Conversely, to the extent that PTAB is overly assertive and improperly targets high-quality patents, the decrease in innovation incentives may be quite problematic. To investigate the issue empirically, our paper uses several novel datasets (made publicly available via the posting of this article) to study the respective roles of the PTAB and the district courts. Our empirical findings indicate that the PTAB’s role in adjudicating small molecule patents has been quite modest, substantially more modest than its role for other types of patents. Moreover, we do not find any evidence that the PTAB targets categories of small molecule patents that are generally considered high quality. To the contrary, the PTAB does not appear to differentially target even categories of small molecule patents that are generally considered to exhibit lower quality. We also find no evidence that the PTAB is targeting small molecule patents held by small entities. We conclude by discussing paths policymakers could take if they were interested in a more active role for the PTAB in policing the validity of small molecule drug patents.","PeriodicalId":415853,"journal":{"name":"University of Southern California Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"56 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-08-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116397600","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Death of the Income Tax (or, the Rise of America's Universal Wage Tax) 所得税的消亡(或美国普遍工资税的兴起)
Pub Date : 2019-04-08 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.3242314
Edward J. McCaffery
Recent proposals from Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez (D NY) to raise the top marginal tax rates under the income tax, and from Senator Elizabeth Warren (D Mass), to add a stand-alone wealth tax to the existing mix of taxes, are promising beginnings. They have burst forth from a veritable desert of progressive tax alternatives in the public political discussion. But both sets of ideas suffer from an allegiance to the status quo; both operate within the existing paradigm of nominally attempting to tax “income” and “wealth” – wealth transfers, in the case of the status quo, wealth itself, in the case of Warren’s proposal. This Article examines that status quo to show that the “income” tax is dead, replaced by a universal wage tax in which payroll taxes add on to a wage/income tax to highly, and inescapably, burden labor while wealth is left off the hook of taxation altogether. This Article traces the century-long movement of our tax system from an income tax to a wage tax, culminating, to date, in President Trump’s Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017. Liberals and progressives must change the way they think about tax in order to get non-taxpaying billionaires, such as the President and his son-in-law, to pay anything at all.
纽约州民主党议员亚历山大·奥卡西奥-科尔特斯(Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez)最近提议提高所得税的最高边际税率,马萨诸塞州民主党参议员伊丽莎白·沃伦(Elizabeth Warren)提议在现有的税种组合中增加一项独立的财富税,这些都是有希望的开端。在公开的政治讨论中,累进税的替代方案确实是一片荒漠,而这些方案正是从中迸发出来的。但这两种观点都受制于对现状的忠诚;两者都在现有的模式下运作,名义上试图对“收入”和“财富”征税——在现状下是财富转移,在沃伦的提议中是财富本身。本文考察了这一现状,以表明“收入”税已死,取而代之的是普遍的工资税,其中工资税加上工资/所得税,给劳动力带来了沉重的负担,而财富则完全摆脱了税收的束缚。本文追溯了我们的税收制度从所得税到工资税长达一个世纪的变迁,到目前为止,在特朗普总统的2017年减税和就业法案中达到了顶峰。自由主义者和进步主义者必须改变他们对税收的看法,以便让不纳税的亿万富翁,如总统和他的女婿,支付任何费用。
{"title":"The Death of the Income Tax (or, the Rise of America's Universal Wage Tax)","authors":"Edward J. McCaffery","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.3242314","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3242314","url":null,"abstract":"Recent proposals from Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez (D NY) to raise the top marginal tax rates under the income tax, and from Senator Elizabeth Warren (D Mass), to add a stand-alone wealth tax to the existing mix of taxes, are promising beginnings. They have burst forth from a veritable desert of progressive tax alternatives in the public political discussion. But both sets of ideas suffer from an allegiance to the status quo; both operate within the existing paradigm of nominally attempting to tax “income” and “wealth” – wealth transfers, in the case of the status quo, wealth itself, in the case of Warren’s proposal. This Article examines that status quo to show that the “income” tax is dead, replaced by a universal wage tax in which payroll taxes add on to a wage/income tax to highly, and inescapably, burden labor while wealth is left off the hook of taxation altogether. This Article traces the century-long movement of our tax system from an income tax to a wage tax, culminating, to date, in President Trump’s Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017. Liberals and progressives must change the way they think about tax in order to get non-taxpaying billionaires, such as the President and his son-in-law, to pay anything at all.","PeriodicalId":415853,"journal":{"name":"University of Southern California Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"29 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2019-04-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130750380","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
'The State of Intellectual Freedom in America' (Written Testimony Before the United States House of Representatives Committee on the Judiciary Subcommittee on the Constitution and Civil Justice) “美国的知识自由状况”(在美国众议院司法委员会宪法和民事司法小组委员会上的书面证词)
Pub Date : 2018-11-09 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.3256465
M. Simkovic
Disagreement between knowledgeable scientific experts and median political views often do not suggest political bias on the part of scientists, but rather an effort by think tanks, media organizations, interest groups and politicians to inappropriately politicize scientific issues. For example, the causes and consequences of Climate Change are scientific issues. The likely economic harm from such changes, and the costs of preventing or mitigating them, are also scientific issues. So are the adverse health consequences from air and water pollution or the health effects of smoking. So is the question of whether tax cuts can generate enough economic growth to reduce the Debt-to-GDP ratio. While scientific questions can have political and policy implications, scientific inquiry should not be politicized. The best evidence should be analyzed with the best methods, and the implications and degree of uncertainty honestly conveyed to policymakers and the public. But according to scientific experts, many scientific issues have been inappropriately politicized when scientific evidence threatened private sector profits or government budgets. These issues include the causes and effects of climate change, the health risks of pollution, and the dangers of tobacco use. According to a Pew survey, nearly 80 percent of scientists believe that previous administrations suppressed government scientists’ findings for political reasons. Many scientists worry that suppression of scientific findings for political reasons is becoming more common. Note that the Pew sample consists overwhelmingly of natural or “hard” scientists in fields such as medical sciences, chemistry, physics and geosciences. Pew’s sample included those who work in private industry as well as those who work in government and universities. Recently, there have been systematic efforts by some members of Congress to weaken the role of science in informing agency rule-making and increase the role of political actors. Some politicians have also sought to prevent government agencies from collecting basic data about demographics, the environment, health and safety, and the economy, even if de-identified to protect individual privacy. Today, threats to academic freedom can come from powerful donors, political leaders, and outside pressure groups who sometimes seek to subtly (or not so subtly) influence ostensibly neutral and unbiased academic research to further their own business interests or other political preferences. The best way to protect universities from undue influence may be to secure and expand revenue sources that are indifferent to or cannot sway the conclusions of academic research. This is analogous to the approach we take to try to protect the independence of members of the federal judiciary or the Federal Reserve.
知识渊博的科学专家和中间政治观点之间的分歧往往并不表明科学家有政治偏见,而是智库、媒体组织、利益集团和政治家试图将科学问题不恰当地政治化。例如,气候变化的原因和后果是科学问题。这些变化可能造成的经济损害,以及预防或减轻这些损害的成本,也是科学问题。空气和水污染或吸烟对健康的不良影响也是如此。减税能否产生足够的经济增长以降低债务与gdp之比的问题也是如此。虽然科学问题可能具有政治和政策含义,但科学探究不应政治化。最好的证据应该用最好的方法进行分析,不确定性的影响和程度应该诚实地传达给决策者和公众。但据科学专家称,当科学证据威胁到私营部门的利润或政府预算时,许多科学问题被不恰当地政治化了。这些问题包括气候变化的原因和影响、污染的健康风险以及烟草使用的危害。根据皮尤的一项调查,近80%的科学家认为,前几届政府出于政治原因压制了政府科学家的发现。许多科学家担心,出于政治原因对科学发现的压制正变得越来越普遍。请注意,皮尤研究中心的样本绝大多数由医学、化学、物理和地球科学等领域的自然或“硬”科学家组成。皮尤的样本包括在私营企业工作的人,也包括在政府和大学工作的人。最近,一些国会议员一直在系统性地努力削弱科学在为机构制定规则提供信息方面的作用,并增加政治行为者的作用。一些政治家还试图阻止政府机构收集有关人口统计、环境、健康和安全以及经济的基本数据,即使是为了保护个人隐私而去标识化的数据。今天,对学术自由的威胁可能来自强大的捐助者、政治领袖和外部压力集团,他们有时试图巧妙地(或不那么巧妙地)影响表面上中立和无偏见的学术研究,以促进自己的商业利益或其他政治偏好。保护大学不受不当影响的最好办法可能是确保和扩大与学术研究结论无关或不能影响其结论的收入来源。这类似于我们试图保护联邦司法机构或美联储成员独立性的做法。
{"title":"'The State of Intellectual Freedom in America' (Written Testimony Before the United States House of Representatives Committee on the Judiciary Subcommittee on the Constitution and Civil Justice)","authors":"M. Simkovic","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.3256465","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3256465","url":null,"abstract":"Disagreement between knowledgeable scientific experts and median political views often do not suggest political bias on the part of scientists, but rather an effort by think tanks, media organizations, interest groups and politicians to inappropriately politicize scientific issues. \u0000For example, the causes and consequences of Climate Change are scientific issues. The likely economic harm from such changes, and the costs of preventing or mitigating them, are also scientific issues. So are the adverse health consequences from air and water pollution or the health effects of smoking. So is the question of whether tax cuts can generate enough economic growth to reduce the Debt-to-GDP ratio. \u0000While scientific questions can have political and policy implications, scientific inquiry should not be politicized. The best evidence should be analyzed with the best methods, and the implications and degree of uncertainty honestly conveyed to policymakers and the public. \u0000But according to scientific experts, many scientific issues have been inappropriately politicized when scientific evidence threatened private sector profits or government budgets. These issues include the causes and effects of climate change, the health risks of pollution, and the dangers of tobacco use. \u0000According to a Pew survey, nearly 80 percent of scientists believe that previous administrations suppressed government scientists’ findings for political reasons. Many scientists worry that suppression of scientific findings for political reasons is becoming more common. \u0000Note that the Pew sample consists overwhelmingly of natural or “hard” scientists in fields such as medical sciences, chemistry, physics and geosciences. Pew’s sample included those who work in private industry as well as those who work in government and universities. \u0000Recently, there have been systematic efforts by some members of Congress to weaken the role of science in informing agency rule-making and increase the role of political actors. Some politicians have also sought to prevent government agencies from collecting basic data about demographics, the environment, health and safety, and the economy, even if de-identified to protect individual privacy. \u0000Today, threats to academic freedom can come from powerful donors, political leaders, and outside pressure groups who sometimes seek to subtly (or not so subtly) influence ostensibly neutral and unbiased academic research to further their own business interests or other political preferences. \u0000The best way to protect universities from undue influence may be to secure and expand revenue sources that are indifferent to or cannot sway the conclusions of academic research. This is analogous to the approach we take to try to protect the independence of members of the federal judiciary or the Federal Reserve.","PeriodicalId":415853,"journal":{"name":"University of Southern California Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"71 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-11-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126811276","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
From Eternity to Here: Divine Accommodation and the Lost Language of Law 从永恒到此地:神圣的迁就与失落的法律语言
Pub Date : 2018-09-25 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.3255018
N. Stolzenberg
This paper asserts that the discourse of religious accommodation has stopped making sense, and that the reason it has stopped making sense is because our terminology (including such terms as "religion," "accommodation," and "secularism") is inherited from tradition of political theological discourse that has been forgotten: the theology of divine accommodation. The paper reconstructs the content of that tradition of political theology in broad strokes, arguing that the birthplace of secularism and the birthplace of liberalism both lie here and that, once we recognize that, a number of doctrinal and conceptual puzzles can be solved, including how to define religion, whether to characterize secular humanism as a religion, and whether to accept the broad (virtually boundless) conception of a right to religious accommodation now being promoted by religious conservatives. The answers proposed are that (a) religion, from the standpoint of this tradition of political theology, refers to beliefs about the content and source of the moral law, and is not contingent on continued belief in a deity; (b) secular humanism is a religion in this sense, and is indeed the religion promoted by accommodationist political theology; (c) the broad conception of a right to religious accommodation must be rejected for the same reasons that the "religion" of secular humanism must be accepted. The paper further argues, as a matter of political theory/history of political thought, that locating the origins of liberalism and secularism in the tradition of divine accommodation reveals conservative political theology and liberal political theory to be one and the same. Finally, it underscores the centrality of law to the humanist tradition and the centrality of humanism to law.
本文断言,宗教调和的话语已经失去了意义,而它失去意义的原因是因为我们的术语(包括“宗教”、“调和”和“世俗主义”等术语)是从已经被遗忘的政治神学话语传统中继承下来的:神性调和的神学。本文从广义上重构了政治神学传统的内容,认为世俗主义的发源地和自由主义的发源地都在这里,一旦我们认识到这一点,许多教义和概念上的难题就可以解决,包括如何定义宗教,是否将世俗人文主义定性为一种宗教,以及是否接受目前由宗教保守派倡导的广泛的(实际上是无限的)宗教和解权的概念。提出的答案是:(a)从政治神学传统的立场来看,宗教指的是关于道德律的内容和来源的信仰,而不是取决于对神的持续信仰;(b)世俗人文主义在这个意义上是一种宗教,确实是由迁就主义政治神学推动的宗教;(c)由于必须接受世俗人道主义“宗教”的同样理由,必须拒绝宗教通便权的广泛概念。本文进一步认为,作为政治理论/政治思想史的一个问题,将自由主义和世俗主义的起源定位于神圣调和的传统,揭示了保守的政治神学和自由主义的政治理论是一体的。最后,强调了法律对人文主义传统的中心性和人文主义对法律的中心性。
{"title":"From Eternity to Here: Divine Accommodation and the Lost Language of Law","authors":"N. Stolzenberg","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.3255018","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3255018","url":null,"abstract":"This paper asserts that the discourse of religious accommodation has stopped making sense, and that the reason it has stopped making sense is because our terminology (including such terms as \"religion,\" \"accommodation,\" and \"secularism\") is inherited from tradition of political theological discourse that has been forgotten: the theology of divine accommodation. The paper reconstructs the content of that tradition of political theology in broad strokes, arguing that the birthplace of secularism and the birthplace of liberalism both lie here and that, once we recognize that, a number of doctrinal and conceptual puzzles can be solved, including how to define religion, whether to characterize secular humanism as a religion, and whether to accept the broad (virtually boundless) conception of a right to religious accommodation now being promoted by religious conservatives. The answers proposed are that (a) religion, from the standpoint of this tradition of political theology, refers to beliefs about the content and source of the moral law, and is not contingent on continued belief in a deity; (b) secular humanism is a religion in this sense, and is indeed the religion promoted by accommodationist political theology; (c) the broad conception of a right to religious accommodation must be rejected for the same reasons that the \"religion\" of secular humanism must be accepted. The paper further argues, as a matter of political theory/history of political thought, that locating the origins of liberalism and secularism in the tradition of divine accommodation reveals conservative political theology and liberal political theory to be one and the same. Finally, it underscores the centrality of law to the humanist tradition and the centrality of humanism to law.","PeriodicalId":415853,"journal":{"name":"University of Southern California Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"5 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2018-09-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128843632","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Taxing Wealth Seriously 认真征收财富税
Pub Date : 2016-11-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2738848
Edward J. McCaffery
The social and political problems of wealth inequality in America are severe and getting worse. A surprise is that the U.S. tax system, as is, is a significant cause of these problems, not a cure for them. The tax-law doctrines that allow those who already have financial wealth to live, luxuriously and tax-free, or to pass on their wealth tax-free to heirs, are simple. The applicable legal doctrines have been in place for nearly a century under the income tax, the primary social tool for addressing matters of economic inequality. The analytic pathways to reform are easy to see once the law is properly understood. Yet our political systems show no serious interest in taxing wealth seriously. We are letting capital off the hook, and ratcheting up taxes on labor, at precisely a time when deep-seated and long-running economic forces suggest that this is precisely the wrong thing to do. It is time -- past time -- for a change. This Article canvasses a century of tax policy in the United States to show that we have never been serious about taxing wealth seriously, and to lay out pathways towards reform.
美国财富不平等的社会和政治问题很严重,而且还在恶化。令人惊讶的是,美国现行的税收制度是造成这些问题的重要原因,而不是解决这些问题的良方。税法理论允许那些已经拥有金融财富的人过上奢侈的免税生活,或者免税地将财富传给继承人,这很简单。所得税是解决经济不平等问题的主要社会工具,适用于所得税的法律理论已经存在了近一个世纪。一旦法律被正确理解,改革的分析途径就很容易看到。然而,我们的政治制度对对财富认真征税并没有表现出真正的兴趣。我们让资本摆脱困境,并逐步提高对劳动力的税收,而正是在这个时候,根深蒂固的、长期存在的经济力量表明,这样做恰恰是错误的。现在是改变的时候了——过去的时候了。本文详细分析了美国一个世纪以来的税收政策,以表明我们从未认真对待过对财富征税,并为改革开辟了道路。
{"title":"Taxing Wealth Seriously","authors":"Edward J. McCaffery","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2738848","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2738848","url":null,"abstract":"The social and political problems of wealth inequality in America are severe and getting worse. A surprise is that the U.S. tax system, as is, is a significant cause of these problems, not a cure for them. The tax-law doctrines that allow those who already have financial wealth to live, luxuriously and tax-free, or to pass on their wealth tax-free to heirs, are simple. The applicable legal doctrines have been in place for nearly a century under the income tax, the primary social tool for addressing matters of economic inequality. The analytic pathways to reform are easy to see once the law is properly understood. Yet our political systems show no serious interest in taxing wealth seriously. We are letting capital off the hook, and ratcheting up taxes on labor, at precisely a time when deep-seated and long-running economic forces suggest that this is precisely the wrong thing to do. It is time -- past time -- for a change. This Article canvasses a century of tax policy in the United States to show that we have never been serious about taxing wealth seriously, and to lay out pathways towards reform.","PeriodicalId":415853,"journal":{"name":"University of Southern California Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"31 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123722668","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Is Rule of Law an Equilibrium Without Private Ordering? 法治是没有私人秩序的均衡吗?
Pub Date : 2016-07-11 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2785017
Gillian K. Hadfield, Barry R. Weingast
Almost all theorizing about law begins with government. In a series of papers we challenge this orthodoxy. Our “what-is-law” approach places private enforcement at the center of a theory of law. The critical public component that distinguishes legal from social order is not public enforcement but rather a public, common knowledge, and stewarded normative classification institution that designates what is and what is not acceptable conduct in a community. Law emerges, we argue, to better coordinate and incentivize decentralized collective punishment (that is, private ordering: sanctions imposed by individuals not in an official capacity.) Our work to date shows that the social order produced by a centralized classification institution supported exclusively by decentralized enforcement is characterized by several normatively attractive features. We call these features legal attributes. They include features routinely understood in the legal philosophical literature as characteristic of the rule of law: generality, published, clear, prospective, and stable. Importantly, the legal attributes we identify do not arise from normative claims about law. Rather, they arise from our positive analysis sustaining an equilibrium based on centralized classification when enforcement requires the voluntary participation of ordinary citizens. These legal attributes are necessary to secure coordination and incentive compatibility in a regime of fully decentralized enforcement. Without them, the effort to sustain an equilibrium based on centralized classification fails. A regime characterized by rule of law is only an equilibrium, we argue, when enforcement of public classifications includes an important component of private enforcement. Without the discipline imposed by the need to incentivize and coordinate private enforcers, a government cannot succeed in sustaining law.
几乎所有关于法律的理论都是从政府开始的。在一系列的论文中,我们对这种正统观念提出了挑战。我们的“法律是什么”方法将私人执法置于法律理论的中心。区分法律与社会秩序的关键公共要素不是公共执法,而是一种公共的、共同的知识和管理的规范性分类制度,它指定了一个社区中什么是可接受的,什么是不可接受的行为。我们认为,法律的出现是为了更好地协调和激励分散的集体惩罚(即私人命令:由非官方身份的个人实施的制裁)。迄今为止,我们的工作表明,由中央集权的分类制度所产生的社会秩序,完全由分散的执法所支持,具有几个规范上有吸引力的特征。我们称这些特征为法律属性。它们包括在法律哲学文献中通常被理解为法治特征的特征:普遍性、公开性、清晰性、前瞻性和稳定性。重要的是,我们所认定的法律属性并非源于法律的规范性主张。相反,当执法需要普通公民的自愿参与时,它们源于我们的积极分析,维持了一种基于集中分类的平衡。这些法律属性对于在完全分散执法的制度中确保协调和激励相容是必要的。没有它们,维持基于集中分类的平衡的努力就会失败。我们认为,当公共分类的执行包括私人执行的重要组成部分时,以法治为特征的制度只是一种均衡。如果没有激励和协调私人执法者的需要所强加的纪律,政府就无法成功地维持法律。
{"title":"Is Rule of Law an Equilibrium Without Private Ordering?","authors":"Gillian K. Hadfield, Barry R. Weingast","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2785017","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2785017","url":null,"abstract":"Almost all theorizing about law begins with government. In a series of papers we challenge this orthodoxy. Our “what-is-law” approach places private enforcement at the center of a theory of law. The critical public component that distinguishes legal from social order is not public enforcement but rather a public, common knowledge, and stewarded normative classification institution that designates what is and what is not acceptable conduct in a community. Law emerges, we argue, to better coordinate and incentivize decentralized collective punishment (that is, private ordering: sanctions imposed by individuals not in an official capacity.) Our work to date shows that the social order produced by a centralized classification institution supported exclusively by decentralized enforcement is characterized by several normatively attractive features. We call these features legal attributes. They include features routinely understood in the legal philosophical literature as characteristic of the rule of law: generality, published, clear, prospective, and stable. Importantly, the legal attributes we identify do not arise from normative claims about law. Rather, they arise from our positive analysis sustaining an equilibrium based on centralized classification when enforcement requires the voluntary participation of ordinary citizens. These legal attributes are necessary to secure coordination and incentive compatibility in a regime of fully decentralized enforcement. Without them, the effort to sustain an equilibrium based on centralized classification fails. A regime characterized by rule of law is only an equilibrium, we argue, when enforcement of public classifications includes an important component of private enforcement. Without the discipline imposed by the need to incentivize and coordinate private enforcers, a government cannot succeed in sustaining law.","PeriodicalId":415853,"journal":{"name":"University of Southern California Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"84 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2016-07-11","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121709699","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
The Bank-Centered View of the Money Market Part II: Re-Evaluating the Real Bills Approach to Macro-Prudential Regulation 以银行为中心的货币市场观——第二部分:对实物票据宏观审慎监管方法的再评价
Pub Date : 2015-04-07 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2578408
Carolyn Sissoko
This paper argues that an early 20th century central banker, had he been alive at the turn of the 21st century, would have predicted the 2007-08 crisis and its severity. This paper is Part II of a series which contends that early 20th century banking theory is a valuable framework for understanding the relationship between banks, financial markets, and the central bank. This paper builds on Part I which explained that because a social norm supports the circulation of bank deposits as money, deposits are a network good and this makes possible monetary finance, or the expansion of the money supply as a source of funds for banks to lend.This paper first analyses the British model of monetary finance, the structured interaction of banks, the money market, and the central bank that formed its core, and the means by which this structure made possible the origination of safe, privately-issued assets. Then, the analysis turns to the macroeconomic implications of monetary finance: in order to protect the monetary social norm, both financial instability and inflation must be avoided. The real bills principle addressed the former by proscribing monetary finance of long-term assets and the latter by requiring careful monitoring and control of the growth of money market instruments that were not real bills.Thus, the modern integration of money and capital markets is seen through traditional banking theory to be a recipe for financial instability, because it undermines the ability of banks and the money market to be joined together in the production of safe privately-issued assets. This theory indicates that restabilizing the financial system will require structural reform and that only after such reform has been implemented can we expect macro-prudential regulation to succeed.
本文认为,如果一位20世纪初的央行行长活在21世纪之交,他就会预测到2007-08年的危机及其严重程度。本文是系列文章的第二部分,该系列文章认为,20世纪早期的银行理论是理解银行、金融市场和中央银行之间关系的一个有价值的框架。本文建立在第一部分的基础上,第一部分解释了由于社会规范支持银行存款作为货币的流通,存款是一种网络商品,这使得货币金融或货币供应的扩大成为可能,作为银行贷款的资金来源。本文首先分析了英国的货币金融模式,银行、货币市场和构成其核心的中央银行之间的结构性互动,以及这种结构使安全、私人发行资产的起源成为可能的手段。然后,分析转向货币金融的宏观经济含义:为了保护货币社会规范,必须避免金融不稳定和通货膨胀。实物票据原则通过禁止对长期资产进行货币融资来解决前者的问题,而后者则要求仔细监测和控制非实物票据的货币市场工具的增长。因此,通过传统的银行理论,货币和资本市场的现代一体化被视为金融不稳定的一个因素,因为它破坏了银行和货币市场在生产安全的私人发行资产方面联合起来的能力。这一理论表明,重新稳定金融体系需要结构性改革,只有在实施了这种改革之后,我们才能期望宏观审慎监管取得成功。
{"title":"The Bank-Centered View of the Money Market Part II: Re-Evaluating the Real Bills Approach to Macro-Prudential Regulation","authors":"Carolyn Sissoko","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.2578408","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2578408","url":null,"abstract":"This paper argues that an early 20th century central banker, had he been alive at the turn of the 21st century, would have predicted the 2007-08 crisis and its severity. This paper is Part II of a series which contends that early 20th century banking theory is a valuable framework for understanding the relationship between banks, financial markets, and the central bank. This paper builds on Part I which explained that because a social norm supports the circulation of bank deposits as money, deposits are a network good and this makes possible monetary finance, or the expansion of the money supply as a source of funds for banks to lend.This paper first analyses the British model of monetary finance, the structured interaction of banks, the money market, and the central bank that formed its core, and the means by which this structure made possible the origination of safe, privately-issued assets. Then, the analysis turns to the macroeconomic implications of monetary finance: in order to protect the monetary social norm, both financial instability and inflation must be avoided. The real bills principle addressed the former by proscribing monetary finance of long-term assets and the latter by requiring careful monitoring and control of the growth of money market instruments that were not real bills.Thus, the modern integration of money and capital markets is seen through traditional banking theory to be a recipe for financial instability, because it undermines the ability of banks and the money market to be joined together in the production of safe privately-issued assets. This theory indicates that restabilizing the financial system will require structural reform and that only after such reform has been implemented can we expect macro-prudential regulation to succeed.","PeriodicalId":415853,"journal":{"name":"University of Southern California Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"148 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-04-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123267849","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Scaffolding: Using Formal Contracts to Build Informal Relations in Support of Innovation 脚手架:使用正式契约建立非正式关系以支持创新
Pub Date : 2015-02-25 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1984915
I. Božović, Gillian K. Hadfield
In a study that follows in Macaulay’s (1963) footsteps, we asked businesses what role formal contract law plays in managing their external relationships. We heard similar answers to the ones Macaulay obtained fifty years ago from companies who described important but non-innovation-oriented external relationships. But we also uncovered an important phenomenon: companies that described innovationoriented external relationships reported making extensive use of formal contracts to plan and manage these relationships. They do not, however, generate these formal contracts in order to secure the benefits of a credible threat of formal contract enforcement; instead, like Macaulay’s original respondents, they largely relied on relational tools
在一项追随麦考利(Macaulay, 1963)脚步的研究中,我们询问企业,正式合同法在管理其外部关系方面发挥了什么作用。我们听到的答案与麦考利50年前从一些公司那里得到的答案类似,他们描述了重要但非创新导向的外部关系。但我们也发现了一个重要的现象:那些描述了以创新为导向的外部关系的公司报告称,它们广泛使用正式合同来规划和管理这些关系。然而,他们产生这些正式合同并不是为了确保正式合同执行的可信威胁所带来的好处;相反,就像麦考利最初的受访者一样,他们在很大程度上依赖于关系工具
{"title":"Scaffolding: Using Formal Contracts to Build Informal Relations in Support of Innovation","authors":"I. Božović, Gillian K. Hadfield","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1984915","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1984915","url":null,"abstract":"In a study that follows in Macaulay’s (1963) footsteps, we asked businesses what role formal contract law plays in managing their external relationships. We heard similar answers to the ones Macaulay obtained fifty years ago from companies who described important but non-innovation-oriented external relationships. But we also uncovered an important phenomenon: companies that described innovationoriented external relationships reported making extensive use of formal contracts to plan and manage these relationships. They do not, however, generate these formal contracts in order to secure the benefits of a credible threat of formal contract enforcement; instead, like Macaulay’s original respondents, they largely relied on relational tools","PeriodicalId":415853,"journal":{"name":"University of Southern California Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"17 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2015-02-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121527576","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 57
Virtual Music Scores, Copyright and the Promotion of a Marginalized Technology 虚拟乐谱、版权与边缘技术的推广
Pub Date : 2014-07-28 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.2457442
Charles Cronin
Virtual music scores are produced from highly manipulable instructions about the location and other attributes of digitally rendered musical symbols and sounds. These instructions, compiled in one of the hundreds of codes developed for the graphical representation of music, direct the arrangement of pixels into a sequence of characters of symbolic music notation. They typically also comprise MIDI (Musical Instrument Digital Interface) instructions that enable sound producing machinery to recreate cfonsistently, across audio platforms, an audible rendition of the visual score. Over seventy percent of professional quality music scores are now produced using virtual score technology yet very few of these are distributed in any format other than printed scores. This is regrettable because virtual scores offer musicians remarkable new creative freedoms and efficiencies. They are also, however, more susceptible to unauthorized copying than are hardcopy scores; hence publishers are reluctant to distribute their scores in this format. Publishers of editions of public domain musical works - that comprise most of the Classical music canon - are particularly chary of distribution of virtual scores. This is because their copyright interest in these editions tends to be attenuated, extending only to original information that editors may have added, but not to the considerable “sweat of the brow” they may have invested in producing scores that reflect the original author’s intentions. This article suggests that to ensure a future for music scores publishers of public domain and copyrightable music scores alike might find that the best means to capitalize upon their publications - while also promoting more widespread adoption of virtual score technology - are contractual restrictions and access and copy controls managed by aggregators of virtual music scores.
虚拟乐谱是由高度可操作的指令产生的,这些指令是关于数字渲染音乐符号和声音的位置和其他属性的。这些指令是在为音乐的图形表示而开发的数百种代码中的一种代码中编写的,它将像素的排列引导成符号音乐符号的字符序列。它们通常还包含MIDI(乐器数字接口)指令,使声音产生机器能够跨音频平台一致地重新创建视觉乐谱的声音再现。目前,超过70%的专业乐谱是使用虚拟乐谱技术制作的,但其中很少以印刷乐谱以外的任何格式分发。这是令人遗憾的,因为虚拟乐谱为音乐家提供了非凡的新的创作自由和效率。然而,它们也比纸质分数更容易被未经授权的复制;因此,发行商不愿以这种格式分发他们的分数。公共领域音乐作品(包括大多数古典音乐经典)的出版商对虚拟乐谱的发行尤其谨慎。这是因为他们在这些版本中的版权利益趋于减弱,只延伸到编辑可能添加的原始信息,而不是他们可能在制作反映原作者意图的分数上投入的大量“汗水”。这篇文章建议,为了确保乐谱的未来,公共领域和受版权保护的乐谱的出版商可能会发现,利用他们的出版物的最好方法——同时也促进虚拟乐谱技术的更广泛采用——是由虚拟乐谱聚合器管理的合同限制、访问和复制控制。
{"title":"Virtual Music Scores, Copyright and the Promotion of a Marginalized Technology","authors":"Charles Cronin","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.2457442","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.2457442","url":null,"abstract":"Virtual music scores are produced from highly manipulable instructions about the location and other attributes of digitally rendered musical symbols and sounds. These instructions, compiled in one of the hundreds of codes developed for the graphical representation of music, direct the arrangement of pixels into a sequence of characters of symbolic music notation. They typically also comprise MIDI (Musical Instrument Digital Interface) instructions that enable sound producing machinery to recreate cfonsistently, across audio platforms, an audible rendition of the visual score. Over seventy percent of professional quality music scores are now produced using virtual score technology yet very few of these are distributed in any format other than printed scores. This is regrettable because virtual scores offer musicians remarkable new creative freedoms and efficiencies. They are also, however, more susceptible to unauthorized copying than are hardcopy scores; hence publishers are reluctant to distribute their scores in this format. Publishers of editions of public domain musical works - that comprise most of the Classical music canon - are particularly chary of distribution of virtual scores. This is because their copyright interest in these editions tends to be attenuated, extending only to original information that editors may have added, but not to the considerable “sweat of the brow” they may have invested in producing scores that reflect the original author’s intentions. This article suggests that to ensure a future for music scores publishers of public domain and copyrightable music scores alike might find that the best means to capitalize upon their publications - while also promoting more widespread adoption of virtual score technology - are contractual restrictions and access and copy controls managed by aggregators of virtual music scores.","PeriodicalId":415853,"journal":{"name":"University of Southern California Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"55 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2014-07-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"132176144","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Measuring Agency Attributes with Attitudes Across Time: A Method and Examples Using Large-Scale Federal Surveys 用态度衡量机构属性:一种使用大规模联邦调查的方法和例子
Pub Date : 2013-06-17 DOI: 10.1093/JOPART/MUT040
Anthony M. Bertelli, D. Mason, J. Connolly, David A. Gastwirth
Public management researchers are interested in many characteristics of organizations that cannot be directly captured, making aggregated attitudes from surveys an attractive proxy. Yet difficulties in measuring meaningful attributes over time and across organizations have frequently limited statistical designs to a single organization or time. We offer a method for creating such statistical measures across agencies and time using item response theory. Focusing our attention on U.S. federal administrative agencies, we marshal a variety of questions from surveys commissioned by the Office of Personnel Management and Merit Systems Protection Board and employ statistical models to measure three important attributes — autonomy, job satisfaction, and intrinsic motivation — for 71 agencies between 1998-2010. Our study provides a wealth of data for quantitative public management research designs as well as an adaptable framework for measuring a wide range of concepts.
公共管理研究人员对不能直接捕获的组织的许多特征感兴趣,这使得从调查中收集的态度成为一个有吸引力的代理。然而,随着时间的推移和跨组织测量有意义的属性的困难往往限制了对单个组织或时间的统计设计。我们提供了一种方法来创建这样的统计措施跨机构和时间使用项目反应理论。将我们的注意力集中在美国联邦行政机构上,我们从人事管理办公室和绩效制度保护委员会委托的调查中收集了各种问题,并采用统计模型来衡量1998年至2010年间71个机构的三个重要属性——自主性、工作满意度和内在动机。我们的研究为定量公共管理研究设计提供了丰富的数据,也为测量广泛的概念提供了一个适应性的框架。
{"title":"Measuring Agency Attributes with Attitudes Across Time: A Method and Examples Using Large-Scale Federal Surveys","authors":"Anthony M. Bertelli, D. Mason, J. Connolly, David A. Gastwirth","doi":"10.1093/JOPART/MUT040","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JOPART/MUT040","url":null,"abstract":"Public management researchers are interested in many characteristics of organizations that cannot be directly captured, making aggregated attitudes from surveys an attractive proxy. Yet difficulties in measuring meaningful attributes over time and across organizations have frequently limited statistical designs to a single organization or time. We offer a method for creating such statistical measures across agencies and time using item response theory. Focusing our attention on U.S. federal administrative agencies, we marshal a variety of questions from surveys commissioned by the Office of Personnel Management and Merit Systems Protection Board and employ statistical models to measure three important attributes — autonomy, job satisfaction, and intrinsic motivation — for 71 agencies between 1998-2010. Our study provides a wealth of data for quantitative public management research designs as well as an adaptable framework for measuring a wide range of concepts.","PeriodicalId":415853,"journal":{"name":"University of Southern California Legal Studies Research Paper Series","volume":"51 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2013-06-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130115340","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 22
期刊
University of Southern California Legal Studies Research Paper Series
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1