Pub Date : 2024-09-05DOI: 10.1007/s00712-024-00883-w
John S. Heywood, Zerong Wang, Guangliang Ye
We uniquely model an upstream mixed duopoly engaging in either uniform pricing or spatial price discrimination when facing a continuum of downstream firms. Uniform pricing generates higher welfare with a fully public firm. Uniform pricing generates greater optimal partial privatization except when the cost disadvantage of the public firm is large and downstream cost convexity is large. Similarly, welfare under optimal partial privatization is larger under uniform pricing except when the cost disadvantage of the public firm is relatively large and downstream cost convexity is large. Thus, the implications of the pricing scheme depend critically on the upstream and downstream cost structure and the ownership structure.
{"title":"A mixed duopoly input market: uniform pricing versus spatial price discrimination","authors":"John S. Heywood, Zerong Wang, Guangliang Ye","doi":"10.1007/s00712-024-00883-w","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-024-00883-w","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We uniquely model an upstream mixed duopoly engaging in either uniform pricing or spatial price discrimination when facing a continuum of downstream firms. Uniform pricing generates higher welfare with a fully public firm. Uniform pricing generates greater optimal partial privatization except when the cost disadvantage of the public firm is large and downstream cost convexity is large. Similarly, welfare under optimal partial privatization is larger under uniform pricing except when the cost disadvantage of the public firm is relatively large and downstream cost convexity is large. Thus, the implications of the pricing scheme depend critically on the upstream and downstream cost structure and the ownership structure.</p>","PeriodicalId":47523,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics","volume":"155 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2024-09-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"142177579","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
Pub Date : 2024-09-04DOI: 10.1007/s00712-024-00882-x
Miguel Ángel Ropero García
We study a class of signaling games in which one of the signals induces the receiver to take an action that provides the sender with the highest utility. This class of games has multiple pooling equilibria, but the equilibrium in which all senders′ types choose the signal that induces the receiver to take that action is more plausible than others. Although all the equilibria in pure strategies are divine in our class of games when the single-crossing condition is not satisfied, only the plausible equilibrium is a neologism-proof equilibrium. Therefore, we have identified a general class of signaling games in which the neologism-proof equilibrium is useful to select the most plausible equilibrium, whereas all the pooling equilibria survive divinity and other less restrictive refinements. We apply our model to an educational signaling game with two features. First, the highest level of education allows a worker to access a more productive segment of the labor market. Second, the educational system is non-selective and consequently, the cost of education does not change with the worker′s ability. As expected, there is overeducation in equilibrium because all worker′s types choose the highest level of education.
{"title":"Signaling games with a highly effective signal","authors":"Miguel Ángel Ropero García","doi":"10.1007/s00712-024-00882-x","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-024-00882-x","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We study a class of signaling games in which one of the signals induces the receiver to take an action that provides the sender with the highest utility. This class of games has multiple pooling equilibria, but the equilibrium in which all senders<i>′</i> types choose the signal that induces the receiver to take that action is more plausible than others. Although all the equilibria in pure strategies are divine in our class of games when the single-crossing condition is not satisfied, only the plausible equilibrium is a neologism-proof equilibrium. Therefore, we have identified a general class of signaling games in which the neologism-proof equilibrium is useful to select the most plausible equilibrium, whereas all the pooling equilibria survive divinity and other less restrictive refinements. We apply our model to an educational signaling game with two features. First, the highest level of education allows a worker to access a more productive segment of the labor market. Second, the educational system is non-selective and consequently, the cost of education does not change with the worker<i>′</i>s ability. As expected, there is overeducation in equilibrium because all worker<i>′</i>s types choose the highest level of education.</p>","PeriodicalId":47523,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics","volume":"107 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2024-09-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"142177580","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
Pub Date : 2024-07-18DOI: 10.1007/s00712-024-00880-z
Giannis Karagiannis
Briec et al. (2003) Aggregation of directional distance functions and industrial efficiency. J Econ 79:237–261) showed that industrial and structural efficiency are identical in the context of cost aggregation if all firms use the same technology, a single output is produced and constant returns to scale prevail. In this note it is shown that the same is also true if the technology is additive, which is equivalently referred to as independence in production or input non-jointness.
Briec et al. (2003) Aggregation of direction distance functions and industrial efficiency.J Econ 79:237-261)的研究表明,如果所有企业使用相同的技术,生产单一产品,并且规模收益不变,那么在成本聚集的情况下,产业效率和结构效率是相同的。本说明指出,如果技术具有可加性,即生产的独立性或投入的非联合性,则两者也是相同的。
{"title":"Aggregation of directional distance functions and industrial efficiency: a note","authors":"Giannis Karagiannis","doi":"10.1007/s00712-024-00880-z","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-024-00880-z","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Briec et al. (2003) Aggregation of directional distance functions and industrial efficiency. J Econ 79:237–261) showed that industrial and structural efficiency are identical in the context of cost aggregation if all firms use the same technology, a single output is produced and constant returns to scale prevail. In this note it is shown that the same is also true if the technology is additive, which is equivalently referred to as independence in production or input non-jointness.</p>","PeriodicalId":47523,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics","volume":"35 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2024-07-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141744812","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
Pub Date : 2024-07-06DOI: 10.1007/s00712-024-00877-8
Jiancai Pi, Yuhan Luo
We develop general equilibrium models that incorporate an agricultural equipment sector to explore the impact of climate change on skilled-unskilled wage inequality in a small open economy, with a specific focus on the role of the domestic capital market. In the model with the agricultural equipment sector using skilled labor as input, we illustrate that climate change decreases both skilled and unskilled wages. However, its effect on wage inequality varies depending on the discrepancy of the capital intensity between the urban skilled and unskilled sectors. Moreover, if the demand for capital in the agricultural equipment sector significantly influences the capital market, this sector will not only act as a buffer, but also trigger a reversal change of wage inequality. To enhance the robustness of our findings, we extend the model to include considerations of public goods provision and taxation.
{"title":"Climate change and wage inequality","authors":"Jiancai Pi, Yuhan Luo","doi":"10.1007/s00712-024-00877-8","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-024-00877-8","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We develop general equilibrium models that incorporate an agricultural equipment sector to explore the impact of climate change on skilled-unskilled wage inequality in a small open economy, with a specific focus on the role of the domestic capital market. In the model with the agricultural equipment sector using skilled labor as input, we illustrate that climate change decreases both skilled and unskilled wages. However, its effect on wage inequality varies depending on the discrepancy of the capital intensity between the urban skilled and unskilled sectors. Moreover, if the demand for capital in the agricultural equipment sector significantly influences the capital market, this sector will not only act as a buffer, but also trigger a reversal change of wage inequality. To enhance the robustness of our findings, we extend the model to include considerations of public goods provision and taxation.</p>","PeriodicalId":47523,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics","volume":"8 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2024-07-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141566347","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
Pub Date : 2024-07-03DOI: 10.1007/s00712-024-00879-6
Chuyuan Zhang, Sang-Ho Lee
This study constructs a vertical structure model where domestic upstream and downstream firms compete with a vertically integrated foreign firm (VIFF), and examines firms’ supply decisions under domestic firms’ separation and integration. We find that the VIFF would switch its supply schedule in both markets, depending on separation and integration, which also shapes different supply decisions of the integrated domestic firm. We demonstrate that industry supply under separation might be socially beneficial if VIFF supplies the final goods, while that under integration decreases welfare unless the number of downstream firm ex-post integration is intermediate. We also examine strategic choices between separation and integration, showing that strategic integration can eliminate these welfare-distortion effects, caused by the VIFF’s switch in its supply decisions, while strategic separation might decrease welfare. Our findings highlight the possible anti-competitiveness of vertical integration when the strategic reactions between the supply shift by the VIFF and domestic integration are relevant.
{"title":"Supply shift by a vertically integrated foreign firm under domestic integration","authors":"Chuyuan Zhang, Sang-Ho Lee","doi":"10.1007/s00712-024-00879-6","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-024-00879-6","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This study constructs a vertical structure model where domestic upstream and downstream firms compete with a vertically integrated foreign firm (VIFF), and examines firms’ supply decisions under domestic firms’ separation and integration. We find that the VIFF would switch its supply schedule in both markets, depending on separation and integration, which also shapes different supply decisions of the integrated domestic firm. We demonstrate that industry supply under separation might be socially beneficial if VIFF supplies the final goods, while that under integration decreases welfare unless the number of downstream firm ex-post integration is intermediate. We also examine strategic choices between separation and integration, showing that strategic integration can eliminate these welfare-distortion effects, caused by the VIFF’s switch in its supply decisions, while strategic separation might decrease welfare. Our findings highlight the possible anti-competitiveness of vertical integration when the strategic reactions between the supply shift by the VIFF and domestic integration are relevant.</p>","PeriodicalId":47523,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics","volume":"43 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2024-07-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141525515","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
Pub Date : 2024-06-03DOI: 10.1007/s00712-024-00875-w
Toshiki Tamai
This paper examines intergenerational welfare effects of public investment financed by factor income taxes in a perpetual-youth overlapping generations model. With elastic labor supply, our analysis shows that long-run employment increases as the tax rate on capital income increases. The positive long-run effect of capital income taxation on employment weakens the negative growth effect of tax distortion. In contrast, the long-run employment might decrease as the tax rate on labor income increases. Hence, the negative long-run effect of labor income taxation on employment strengthens the negative growth effect due to the tax distortion. Finally, this paper reveals that older people with more financial wealth suffer more significant welfare loss from the increased tax on each capital and labor income than younger people if the increased tax impedes economic growth. Furthermore, the increased tax harms the younger generations more than the older generations at the aggregate level because they have a larger population than the older people. However, the negative welfare effects of labor income taxation are stronger than those of capital income taxation because of the negative effect of labor income taxation on employment, which leads to a lower equilibrium growth rate.
{"title":"Public investment, factor income taxation, and intergenerational welfare distribution in an overlapping generations model","authors":"Toshiki Tamai","doi":"10.1007/s00712-024-00875-w","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-024-00875-w","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper examines intergenerational welfare effects of public investment financed by factor income taxes in a perpetual-youth overlapping generations model. With elastic labor supply, our analysis shows that long-run employment increases as the tax rate on capital income increases. The positive long-run effect of capital income taxation on employment weakens the negative growth effect of tax distortion. In contrast, the long-run employment might decrease as the tax rate on labor income increases. Hence, the negative long-run effect of labor income taxation on employment strengthens the negative growth effect due to the tax distortion. Finally, this paper reveals that older people with more financial wealth suffer more significant welfare loss from the increased tax on each capital and labor income than younger people if the increased tax impedes economic growth. Furthermore, the increased tax harms the younger generations more than the older generations at the aggregate level because they have a larger population than the older people. However, the negative welfare effects of labor income taxation are stronger than those of capital income taxation because of the negative effect of labor income taxation on employment, which leads to a lower equilibrium growth rate.</p>","PeriodicalId":47523,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics","volume":"53 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2024-06-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141258261","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
This paper sets up a three-stage game (technology licensing, emission tax, and output) in which one foreign firm owns both process technology and environmental technology. We compare three types of licensing strategies, process technology, environmental technology, and package licensing, showing that the licensor’s preference on licensing strategy depends on the level of marginal environmental damage. Specifically, if the environmental damage caused by the production of the home firm is large, the package licensing deal is preferred by the foreign firm; otherwise process licensing is preferred. It is also found that the social welfare may be lower after licensing.
{"title":"Environmental policy, licensing strategy, and social welfare","authors":"Yen-Ju Lin, Yan-Shu Lin, Tsung-Han Chou, Pei-Cyuan Shih","doi":"10.1007/s00712-024-00873-y","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-024-00873-y","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper sets up a three-stage game (technology licensing, emission tax, and output) in which one foreign firm owns both process technology and environmental technology. We compare three types of licensing strategies, process technology, environmental technology, and package licensing, showing that the licensor’s preference on licensing strategy depends on the level of marginal environmental damage. Specifically, if the environmental damage caused by the production of the home firm is large, the package licensing deal is preferred by the foreign firm; otherwise process licensing is preferred. It is also found that the social welfare may be lower after licensing.</p>","PeriodicalId":47523,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics","volume":"60 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2024-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141196002","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
Pub Date : 2024-05-19DOI: 10.1007/s00712-024-00871-0
Xingtang Wang, Leonard F. S. Wang, Huizhong Liu
We construct a vertical product differentiation duopoly model incorporating managerial delegation and cross-ownership. By exploring the interplay of these factors, we find a U-shaped relationship between endogenous managerial delegation coefficients and cross-ownership. The difference in managerial delegation coefficients between the two firms decreases as the cross-ownership proportion increases. In an ownership structure involving cross-ownership of firms producing different quality products, managerial delegation improves firms’ profits while reducing consumer surplus and social welfare in a vertical product differentiation market. Moreover, cross-ownership intensifies the positive impact of managerial delegation on joint profits and the negative effects on consumer surplus and social welfare. Consequently, regulating cross-ownership among firms in vertically differentiated product markets is an important policy issue for competition law.
我们构建了一个包含管理授权和交叉所有权的纵向产品差异化双头垄断模型。通过探讨这些因素的相互作用,我们发现内生的管理授权系数与交叉所有权之间存在 U 型关系。随着交叉持股比例的增加,两家公司之间管理授权系数的差异会减小。在生产不同质量产品的企业交叉持股的所有制结构中,管理授权提高了企业利润,同时减少了纵向产品差异化市场中的消费者剩余和社会福利。此外,交叉所有制加剧了管理授权对联合利润的积极影响,以及对消费者剩余和社会福利的消极影响。因此,对纵向差异化产品市场中企业间的交叉所有权进行监管是竞争法的一个重要政策问题。
{"title":"Cross-ownership and managerial delegation under vertical product differentiation","authors":"Xingtang Wang, Leonard F. S. Wang, Huizhong Liu","doi":"10.1007/s00712-024-00871-0","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-024-00871-0","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We construct a vertical product differentiation duopoly model incorporating managerial delegation and cross-ownership. By exploring the interplay of these factors, we find a U-shaped relationship between endogenous managerial delegation coefficients and cross-ownership. The difference in managerial delegation coefficients between the two firms decreases as the cross-ownership proportion increases. In an ownership structure involving cross-ownership of firms producing different quality products, managerial delegation improves firms’ profits while reducing consumer surplus and social welfare in a vertical product differentiation market. Moreover, cross-ownership intensifies the positive impact of managerial delegation on joint profits and the negative effects on consumer surplus and social welfare. Consequently, regulating cross-ownership among firms in vertically differentiated product markets is an important policy issue for competition law.</p>","PeriodicalId":47523,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics","volume":"46 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2024-05-19","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141062915","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
Pub Date : 2024-05-12DOI: 10.1007/s00712-024-00870-1
Makoto Hirono
We construct an overlapping generations model in which the government chooses the tax rate that determines publicly provided education and healthcare. Education increases human capital accumulation, and healthcare improves life expectancy. Each policy is financed by taxes. Two sectors of government, the public education and public healthcare sectors, uncooperatively determine the tax rates for education and healthcare that maximize the GDP per capita and an adult’s welfare. Our main findings are as follows. First, the optimal tax rates for both branches of government based on per capita GDP maximization are uniquely determined. Second, in the case based on welfare maximization, there are multiple equilibria that can be ranked. The conclusion relies on the strategic complementary relationship between public education and healthcare, and the result is consistent with empirical data.
我们构建了一个世代重叠模型,在该模型中,政府选择的税率决定了公共教育和医疗服务的提供。教育能增加人力资本积累,医疗能提高预期寿命。每项政策都由税收提供资金。政府的两个部门,即公共教育部门和公共医疗部门,以不合作的方式决定教育和医疗的税率,使人均 GDP 和成人福利最大化。我们的主要发现如下。首先,基于人均 GDP 最大化的两个政府部门的最优税率是唯一确定的。其次,在基于福利最大化的情况下,存在可以排序的多重均衡。结论依赖于公共教育和医疗保健之间的战略互补关系,结果与经验数据一致。
{"title":"Population aging, human capital accumulation, and coordination of policies","authors":"Makoto Hirono","doi":"10.1007/s00712-024-00870-1","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-024-00870-1","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We construct an overlapping generations model in which the government chooses the tax rate that determines publicly provided education and healthcare. Education increases human capital accumulation, and healthcare improves life expectancy. Each policy is financed by taxes. Two sectors of government, the public education and public healthcare sectors, uncooperatively determine the tax rates for education and healthcare that maximize the GDP per capita and an adult’s welfare. Our main findings are as follows. First, the optimal tax rates for both branches of government based on per capita GDP maximization are uniquely determined. Second, in the case based on welfare maximization, there are multiple equilibria that can be ranked. The conclusion relies on the strategic complementary relationship between public education and healthcare, and the result is consistent with empirical data.</p>","PeriodicalId":47523,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics","volume":"155 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2024-05-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140928755","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
Pub Date : 2024-05-02DOI: 10.1007/s00712-024-00868-9
Carlos Bethencourt, Fernando Perera-Tallo
This paper proposes a theory about the allocation of human capital along the development process that helps to understand the controversial impact of this variable in growth regressions. We build a model in which human capital is allocated to three activities: production, tax collection (bureaucracy), and public education. At the first stage of development, countries have low effective tax rates because tax collection requires human capital, which is scarce. As countries accumulate human capital throughout the transition, the effective tax rate rises, diverting human capital from production to bureaucracy and public education. Consequently, at this stage, human capital has a weak impact on production, even when the human capital allocation is efficient. Furthermore, disparities in institutional quality may diminish the correlation between human capital and GDP.
{"title":"Public sector and human capital: on the mechanics of economic development","authors":"Carlos Bethencourt, Fernando Perera-Tallo","doi":"10.1007/s00712-024-00868-9","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-024-00868-9","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper proposes a theory about the allocation of human capital along the development process that helps to understand the controversial impact of this variable in growth regressions. We build a model in which human capital is allocated to three activities: production, tax collection (bureaucracy), and public education. At the first stage of development, countries have low effective tax rates because tax collection requires human capital, which is scarce. As countries accumulate human capital throughout the transition, the effective tax rate rises, diverting human capital from production to bureaucracy and public education. Consequently, at this stage, human capital has a weak impact on production, even when the human capital allocation is efficient. Furthermore, disparities in institutional quality may diminish the correlation between human capital and GDP.</p>","PeriodicalId":47523,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economics","volume":"47 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2024-05-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140833081","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}