首页 > 最新文献

Quantitative Marketing and Economics最新文献

英文 中文
Apparent algorithmic discrimination and real-time algorithmic learning in digital search advertising 数字搜索广告中的显性算法辨别和实时算法学习
Pub Date : 2024-07-25 DOI: 10.1007/s11129-024-09286-z
Anja Lambrecht, Catherine Tucker

Digital algorithms try to display content that engages consumers. To do this, algorithms need to overcome a ‘cold-start problem’ by swiftly learning whether content engages users. This requires feedback from users. The algorithm targets segments of users. However, if there are fewer individuals in a targeted segment of users, simply because this group is rarer in the population, this could lead to uneven outcomes for minority relative to majority groups. This is because individuals in a minority segment are proportionately more likely to be test subjects for experimental content that may ultimately be rejected by the platform. We explore in the context of ads that are displayed following searches on Google whether this is indeed the case. Previous research has documented that searches for names associated in a US context with Black people on search engines were more likely to return ads that highlighted the need for a criminal background check than was the case for searches for white people. We implement search advertising campaigns that target ads to searches for Black and white names. Our ads are indeed more likely to be displayed following a search for a Black name, even though the likelihood of clicking was similar. Since Black names are less common, the algorithm learns about the quality of the underlying ad more slowly. As a result, an ad is more likely to persist for searches next to Black names than next to white names. Proportionally more Black name searches are likely to have a low-quality ad shown next to them, even though eventually the ad will be rejected. A second study where ads are placed following searches for terms related to religious discrimination confirms this empirical pattern. Our results suggest that as a practical matter, real-time algorithmic learning can lead minority segments to be more likely to see content that will ultimately be rejected by the algorithm.

数字算法试图展示能吸引消费者的内容。为此,算法需要克服 "冷启动问题",迅速了解内容是否能吸引用户。这需要用户的反馈。算法以细分用户为目标。但是,如果目标用户群体中的个体数量较少,仅仅因为该群体在人口中较为稀少,这可能会导致少数群体与多数群体的结果不均衡。这是因为少数群体中的个人更有可能成为实验内容的测试对象,而这些内容最终可能会被平台拒绝。我们以谷歌搜索后显示的广告为背景,来探讨这种情况是否属实。以前的研究表明,在美国的搜索引擎上搜索与黑人相关的名字时,比搜索白人时更有可能返回强调需要进行犯罪背景调查的广告。我们实施了针对黑人和白人姓名搜索的搜索广告活动。尽管点击的可能性相似,但我们的广告确实更有可能在搜索黑人姓名后显示出来。由于黑人姓名不太常见,因此算法对基础广告质量的了解更慢。因此,与白人姓名相比,黑人姓名旁边的搜索广告更有可能持续出现。更多的黑人姓名搜索可能会在旁边显示低质量的广告,即使广告最终会被拒绝。第二项研究证实了这一经验模式,即在与宗教歧视相关的搜索词后投放广告。我们的研究结果表明,在实践中,实时算法学习会导致少数群体更有可能看到最终会被算法拒绝的内容。
{"title":"Apparent algorithmic discrimination and real-time algorithmic learning in digital search advertising","authors":"Anja Lambrecht, Catherine Tucker","doi":"10.1007/s11129-024-09286-z","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-024-09286-z","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Digital algorithms try to display content that engages consumers. To do this, algorithms need to overcome a ‘cold-start problem’ by swiftly learning whether content engages users. This requires feedback from users. The algorithm targets segments of users. However, if there are fewer individuals in a targeted segment of users, simply because this group is rarer in the population, this could lead to uneven outcomes for minority relative to majority groups. This is because individuals in a minority segment are proportionately more likely to be test subjects for experimental content that may ultimately be rejected by the platform. We explore in the context of ads that are displayed following searches on Google whether this is indeed the case. Previous research has documented that searches for names associated in a US context with Black people on search engines were more likely to return ads that highlighted the need for a criminal background check than was the case for searches for white people. We implement search advertising campaigns that target ads to searches for Black and white names. Our ads are indeed more likely to be displayed following a search for a Black name, even though the likelihood of clicking was similar. Since Black names are less common, the algorithm learns about the quality of the underlying ad more slowly. As a result, an ad is more likely to persist for searches next to Black names than next to white names. Proportionally more Black name searches are likely to have a low-quality ad shown next to them, even though eventually the ad will be rejected. A second study where ads are placed following searches for terms related to religious discrimination confirms this empirical pattern. Our results suggest that as a practical matter, real-time algorithmic learning can lead minority segments to be more likely to see content that will ultimately be rejected by the algorithm.</p>","PeriodicalId":501397,"journal":{"name":"Quantitative Marketing and Economics","volume":"24 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2024-07-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141781799","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Complementarities between algorithmic and human decision-making: The case of antibiotic prescribing 算法决策与人工决策之间的互补性:抗生素处方案例
Pub Date : 2024-07-05 DOI: 10.1007/s11129-024-09284-1
Michael Allan Ribers, Hannes Ullrich

Artificial Intelligence has the potential to improve human decisions in complex environments, but its effectiveness can remain limited if humans hold context-specific private information. Using the empirical example of antibiotic prescribing for urinary tract infections, we show that full automation of prescribing fails to improve on physician decisions. Instead, optimally delegating a share of decisions to physicians, where they possess private diagnostic information, effectively utilizes the complementarity between algorithmic and human decisions. Combining physician and algorithmic decisions can achieve a reduction in inefficient overprescribing of antibiotics by 20.3 percent.

人工智能有可能改善人类在复杂环境中的决策,但如果人类掌握了特定情境下的私人信息,人工智能的有效性就会受到限制。通过尿路感染抗生素处方的实证例子,我们发现处方的完全自动化并不能改善医生的决策。相反,在医生掌握私人诊断信息的情况下,将一部分决策权最佳地委托给医生,可以有效地利用算法决策与人工决策之间的互补性。将医生决策与算法决策相结合,可将抗生素的低效过量处方减少 20.3%。
{"title":"Complementarities between algorithmic and human decision-making: The case of antibiotic prescribing","authors":"Michael Allan Ribers, Hannes Ullrich","doi":"10.1007/s11129-024-09284-1","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-024-09284-1","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Artificial Intelligence has the potential to improve human decisions in complex environments, but its effectiveness can remain limited if humans hold context-specific private information. Using the empirical example of antibiotic prescribing for urinary tract infections, we show that full automation of prescribing fails to improve on physician decisions. Instead, optimally delegating a share of decisions to physicians, where they possess private diagnostic information, effectively utilizes the complementarity between algorithmic and human decisions. Combining physician and algorithmic decisions can achieve a reduction in inefficient overprescribing of antibiotics by 20.3 percent.</p>","PeriodicalId":501397,"journal":{"name":"Quantitative Marketing and Economics","volume":"20 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2024-07-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141550497","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Watching intensity and media franchise engagement 观看强度和媒体特许经营参与度
Pub Date : 2024-06-25 DOI: 10.1007/s11129-024-09283-2
Mina Ameri, Elisabeth Honka, Ying Xie

The rapid adoption of online streaming and over-the-top services has fundamentally changed at-home entertainment media consumption and given rise to new behaviors which are often characterized by a high intensity of watching (e.g., binge-watching). In this paper, we investigate how the watching intensity affects consumers’ engagement with media franchises in two areas: personal and interactive engagement. The former involves consumers’ adoption and consumption of franchise extensions and the latter concerns consumers’ content generation related to a focal media product they watched. Using individual-level data from an online anime (Japanese cartoons) platform, we find inverse U-shaped effects of watching intensity with the largest effects around three to five hours of watching per day on personal engagement and two to four hours a day on interactive engagement. The positive effects of watching intensity are larger for sequels than other types of franchise extensions. For interactive engagement, our results show that conditional on rating submission, higher watching intensity is associated with higher valence of anime ratings, the most prevalent form of UGC on the platform. We interpret this result as evidence that watching intensity can induce liking.

在线流媒体和超媒体服务的迅速普及从根本上改变了家庭娱乐媒体消费,并催生了以高强度观看(如狂欢式观看)为特征的新行为。在本文中,我们将从个人参与和互动参与两个方面研究观看强度如何影响消费者对媒体特许经营的参与。前者涉及消费者对特许经营延伸产品的采用和消费,后者涉及消费者与他们观看的重点媒体产品相关的内容生成。通过使用一个在线动漫(日本动画片)平台的个人层面数据,我们发现观看强度会产生反 U 型效应,每天观看三到五个小时对个人参与的影响最大,每天观看两到四个小时对互动参与的影响最大。与其他类型的特许经营扩展相比,续集的观看强度所产生的正效应更大。在互动参与方面,我们的结果显示,在提交评分的条件下,观看强度越高,动漫评分的价值越高,而动漫评分是平台上最普遍的 UGC 形式。我们将这一结果解释为观看强度可以诱发喜欢的证据。
{"title":"Watching intensity and media franchise engagement","authors":"Mina Ameri, Elisabeth Honka, Ying Xie","doi":"10.1007/s11129-024-09283-2","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-024-09283-2","url":null,"abstract":"<p>The rapid adoption of online streaming and over-the-top services has fundamentally changed at-home entertainment media consumption and given rise to new behaviors which are often characterized by a high intensity of watching (e.g., binge-watching). In this paper, we investigate how the watching intensity affects consumers’ engagement with media franchises in two areas: personal and interactive engagement. The former involves consumers’ adoption and consumption of franchise extensions and the latter concerns consumers’ content generation related to a focal media product they watched. Using individual-level data from an online anime (Japanese cartoons) platform, we find inverse U-shaped effects of watching intensity with the largest effects around three to five hours of watching per day on personal engagement and two to four hours a day on interactive engagement. The positive effects of watching intensity are larger for sequels than other types of franchise extensions. For interactive engagement, our results show that conditional on rating submission, higher watching intensity is associated with higher valence of anime ratings, the most prevalent form of UGC on the platform. We interpret this result as evidence that watching intensity can induce liking.</p>","PeriodicalId":501397,"journal":{"name":"Quantitative Marketing and Economics","volume":"28 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2024-06-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141506404","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Testing a theory of strategic multi-product choice 检验战略性多产品选择理论
Pub Date : 2024-06-18 DOI: 10.1007/s11129-024-09280-5
Edward J. Fox, Hristina Pulgar, John H. Semple

This paper tests a theory of strategic multi-product choice (SMPC) using empirical evidence from a large-scale choice experiment, two smaller longitudinal choice experiments, and multi-market panel data. Multi-product choice involves two stages. In the first stage, the consumer chooses a set of substitutable products, where “set” refers to both the variety of alternatives and the quantities of each. In the second stage, the set is consumed. Assuming consumers are strategic, their consumption decisions will consider both the utility of whichever product is selected for consumption and the expected utility (i.e., value) of the set that remains. SMPC therefore requires a dynamic model. We test two such dynamic models in this paper. These models are derived from a basic random utility framework with a stochastic error term for the utility of each product alternative at the moment of consumption. Despite maintaining state variables for the quantity of every alternative, these SMPC dynamic models offer both a value function and optimal consumption policy in closed form. These structures allow us to test for strategic consumption in the second stage and for optimality of the choice sets selected in the first stage. Data from the large-scale choice experiment and the smaller longitudinal choice experiments support strategic consumer decision-making, consistent with SMPC theory. SMPC theory further predicts that the amount of variety consumers select will be higher for lower consumption rates and lower for higher consumption rates. Evidence from panel data of yogurt purchases supports this prediction. While we find that consumption choices are consistent with SMPC theory, they are not consistent with alternative explanations such as variety seeking or diversification bias. Viewed in its entirety, the empirical evidence presented in this paper confirms that both the choice set selected and the way it is consumed are consistent with dynamic models of future preference uncertainty.

本文利用大规模选择实验、两个较小的纵向选择实验以及多市场面板数据中的经验证据,检验了战略性多产品选择(SMPC)理论。多产品选择包括两个阶段。在第一阶段,消费者选择一组可替代产品,这里的 "一组 "指的是替代品的种类和数量。在第二阶段,这组产品被消费。假定消费者是有策略的,那么他们的消费决策既要考虑被选中消费的产品的效用,也要考虑剩下的这套产品的预期效用(即价值)。因此,SMPC 需要一个动态模型。我们在本文中测试了两个这样的动态模型。这些模型是从一个基本的随机效用框架中推导出来的,在消费时,每个备选产品的效用都有一个随机误差项。尽管保持了每种替代品数量的状态变量,但这些 SMPC 动态模型以封闭形式提供了价值函数和最优消费政策。这些结构使我们能够检验第二阶段的战略消费和第一阶段所选选择集的最优性。来自大规模选择实验和较小规模纵向选择实验的数据支持战略性消费决策,这与 SMPC 理论是一致的。SMPC 理论进一步预测,消费者选择的品种数量在消费率较低时较高,在消费率较高时较低。购买酸奶的面板数据支持这一预测。虽然我们发现消费选择与 SMPC 理论一致,但与其他解释(如品种寻求或多样化偏差)并不一致。从整体上看,本文提供的经验证据证实,所选择的选择集和消费方式都符合未来偏好不确定性的动态模型。
{"title":"Testing a theory of strategic multi-product choice","authors":"Edward J. Fox, Hristina Pulgar, John H. Semple","doi":"10.1007/s11129-024-09280-5","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-024-09280-5","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper tests a theory of strategic multi-product choice (<i>SMPC</i>) using empirical evidence from a large-scale choice experiment, two smaller longitudinal choice experiments, and multi-market panel data. Multi-product choice involves two stages. In the first stage, the consumer chooses a set of substitutable products, where “set” refers to both the variety of alternatives and the quantities of each. In the second stage, the set is consumed. Assuming consumers are strategic, their consumption decisions will consider both the utility of whichever product is selected for consumption and the expected utility (i.e., value) of the set that remains. <i>SMPC</i> therefore requires a dynamic model. We test two such dynamic models in this paper. These models are derived from a basic random utility framework with a stochastic error term for the utility of each product alternative at the moment of consumption. Despite maintaining state variables for the quantity of every alternative, these <i>SMPC</i> dynamic models offer both a value function and optimal consumption policy in closed form. These structures allow us to test for strategic consumption in the second stage and for optimality of the choice sets selected in the first stage. Data from the large-scale choice experiment and the smaller longitudinal choice experiments support strategic consumer decision-making, consistent with <i>SMPC</i> theory. <i>SMPC</i> theory further predicts that the amount of variety consumers select will be higher for lower consumption rates and lower for higher consumption rates. Evidence from panel data of yogurt purchases supports this prediction. While we find that consumption choices are consistent with <i>SMPC</i> theory, they are not consistent with alternative explanations such as variety seeking or diversification bias. Viewed in its entirety, the empirical evidence presented in this paper confirms that both the choice set selected and the way it is consumed are consistent with dynamic models of future preference uncertainty.</p>","PeriodicalId":501397,"journal":{"name":"Quantitative Marketing and Economics","volume":"60 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2024-06-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141506405","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Simulated maximum likelihood estimation of the sequential search model 顺序搜索模型的模拟最大似然估计
Pub Date : 2024-05-29 DOI: 10.1007/s11129-024-09281-4
Jae Hyen Chung, Pradeep Chintagunta, Sanjog Misra

We propose a new approach to simulate the likelihood of the sequential search model. By allowing search costs to be heterogeneous across consumers and products, we directly compute the joint probability of the search and purchase decisions when consumers are searching for the idiosyncratic preference shocks in their utility functions. Under the assumptions of Weitzman’s sequential search algorithm, the proposed procedure recursively makes random draws for each quantity that requires numerical integration while enforcing the conditions stipulated by the algorithm. In an extensive simulation study, we compare the proposed method with existing likelihood simulators that have recently been used to estimate the sequential search model. The proposed method attributes the uncertainty in the search order to the consumer-product-level distribution of search costs and the uncertainty in the purchase decision to the distribution of match values across consumers and products. This results in more precise estimation and an improvement in prediction accuracy. We also show that the proposed method allows for different assumptions on the search cost distribution and that it recovers consumers’ relative preferences even if the utility function and/or the search cost distribution is mis-specified. We then apply our approach to online search data from Expedia for field-data validation. From a substantive perspective, we find that search costs and “position” effects affect products in the lower part of the product listing page more than they do those in the upper part of the page.

我们提出了一种模拟顺序搜索模型可能性的新方法。通过允许搜索成本在不同消费者和产品之间是异质的,我们直接计算了当消费者搜索其效用函数中的特异偏好冲击时,搜索和购买决策的联合概率。在魏茨曼顺序搜索算法的假设条件下,所提出的程序会递归地对每个需要数值积分的数量进行随机抽取,同时执行算法规定的条件。在广泛的模拟研究中,我们将所提出的方法与最近用于估计顺序搜索模型的现有似然模拟器进行了比较。所提出的方法将搜索顺序的不确定性归因于消费者-产品层面的搜索成本分布,将购买决策的不确定性归因于消费者和产品之间匹配值的分布。这使得估算更加精确,预测准确率也有所提高。我们还表明,所提出的方法允许对搜索成本分布进行不同的假设,而且即使效用函数和/或搜索成本分布被错误地指定,它也能恢复消费者的相对偏好。然后,我们将我们的方法应用于 Expedia 的在线搜索数据,进行实地数据验证。从实质角度来看,我们发现搜索成本和 "位置 "效应对产品列表页面下部产品的影响大于对页面上部产品的影响。
{"title":"Simulated maximum likelihood estimation of the sequential search model","authors":"Jae Hyen Chung, Pradeep Chintagunta, Sanjog Misra","doi":"10.1007/s11129-024-09281-4","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-024-09281-4","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We propose a new approach to simulate the likelihood of the sequential search model. By allowing search costs to be heterogeneous across consumers and products, we directly compute the joint probability of the search and purchase decisions when consumers are searching for the idiosyncratic preference shocks in their utility functions. Under the assumptions of Weitzman’s sequential search algorithm, the proposed procedure recursively makes random draws for each quantity that requires numerical integration while enforcing the conditions stipulated by the algorithm. In an extensive simulation study, we compare the proposed method with existing likelihood simulators that have recently been used to estimate the sequential search model. The proposed method attributes the uncertainty in the search order to the consumer-product-level distribution of search costs and the uncertainty in the purchase decision to the distribution of match values across consumers and products. This results in more precise estimation and an improvement in prediction accuracy. We also show that the proposed method allows for different assumptions on the search cost distribution and that it recovers consumers’ relative preferences even if the utility function and/or the search cost distribution is mis-specified. We then apply our approach to online search data from Expedia for field-data validation. From a substantive perspective, we find that search costs and “position” effects affect products in the lower part of the product listing page more than they do those in the upper part of the page.</p>","PeriodicalId":501397,"journal":{"name":"Quantitative Marketing and Economics","volume":"18 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2024-05-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141169704","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Investigating complementarities in subscription software usage using advertising experiments 利用广告实验调查订阅软件使用的互补性
Pub Date : 2024-05-20 DOI: 10.1007/s11129-024-09282-3
Jon Zeller, Sridhar Narayanan
{"title":"Investigating complementarities in subscription software usage using advertising experiments","authors":"Jon Zeller, Sridhar Narayanan","doi":"10.1007/s11129-024-09282-3","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-024-09282-3","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":501397,"journal":{"name":"Quantitative Marketing and Economics","volume":"91 21","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2024-05-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141122954","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Heterogeneous treatment effects and optimal targeting policy evaluation 异质性治疗效果和最佳目标政策评估
Pub Date : 2024-04-05 DOI: 10.1007/s11129-023-09278-5
Günter J. Hitsch, Sanjog Misra, Walter W. Zhang

We present a general framework to target customers using optimal targeting policies, and we document the profit differences from alternative estimates of the optimal targeting policies. Two foundations of the framework are conditional average treatment effects (CATEs) and off-policy evaluation using data with randomized targeting. This policy evaluation approach allows us to evaluate an arbitrary number of different targeting policies using only one randomized data set and thus provides large cost advantages over conducting a corresponding number of field experiments. We use different CATE estimation methods to construct and compare alternative targeting policies. Our particular focus is on the distinction between indirect and direct methods. The indirect methods predict the CATEs using a conditional expectation function estimated on outcome levels, whereas the direct methods specifically predict the treatment effects of targeting. We introduce a new direct estimation method called treatment effect projection (TEP). The TEP is a non-parametric CATE estimator that we regularize using a transformed outcome loss which, in expectation, is identical to a loss that we could construct if the individual treatment effects were observed. The empirical application is to a catalog mailing with a high-dimensional set of customer features. We document the profits of the estimated policies using data from two campaigns conducted one year apart, which allows us to assess the transportability of the predictions to a campaign implemented one year after collecting the training data. All estimates of the optimal targeting policies yield larger profits than uniform policies that target none or all customers. Further, there are significant profit differences across the methods, with the direct estimation methods yielding substantially larger economic value than the indirect methods.

我们提出了一个使用最优目标定位政策定位客户的总体框架,并记录了最优目标定位政策的其他估计值所产生的利润差异。该框架的两个基础是条件平均处理效果(CATE)和使用随机定位数据进行非政策评估。这种政策评估方法使我们只需使用一个随机数据集就能评估任意数量的不同目标定位政策,因此与进行相应数量的实地实验相比,具有很大的成本优势。我们使用不同的 CATE 估算方法来构建和比较备选目标定位政策。我们特别关注间接方法和直接方法之间的区别。间接方法使用对结果水平估计的条件期望函数来预测 CATE,而直接方法则专门预测目标定位的治疗效果。我们引入了一种新的直接估算方法,称为治疗效果预测法(TEP)。TEP 是一种非参数 CATE 估计器,我们使用转换后的结果损失对其进行正则化,该结果损失在期望值上与我们在观察个体治疗效果的情况下构建的损失相同。实证应用于具有高维客户特征集的目录邮件。我们使用相隔一年的两次营销活动的数据记录了估计政策的收益,这使我们能够评估预测结果在收集训练数据一年后的营销活动中的可移植性。与不以任何客户为目标或以所有客户为目标的统一政策相比,最优目标定位政策的所有估计值都能产生更大的利润。此外,不同方法的利润差异也很大,直接估算法产生的经济价值远远大于间接估算法。
{"title":"Heterogeneous treatment effects and optimal targeting policy evaluation","authors":"Günter J. Hitsch, Sanjog Misra, Walter W. Zhang","doi":"10.1007/s11129-023-09278-5","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-023-09278-5","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We present a general framework to target customers using optimal targeting policies, and we document the profit differences from alternative estimates of the optimal targeting policies. Two foundations of the framework are conditional average treatment effects (CATEs) and off-policy evaluation using data with randomized targeting. This policy evaluation approach allows us to evaluate an arbitrary number of different targeting policies using only one randomized data set and thus provides large cost advantages over conducting a corresponding number of field experiments. We use different CATE estimation methods to construct and compare alternative targeting policies. Our particular focus is on the distinction between indirect and direct methods. The indirect methods predict the CATEs using a conditional expectation function estimated on outcome levels, whereas the direct methods specifically predict the treatment effects of targeting. We introduce a new direct estimation method called treatment effect projection (TEP). The TEP is a non-parametric CATE estimator that we regularize using a transformed outcome loss which, in expectation, is identical to a loss that we could construct if the individual treatment effects were observed. The empirical application is to a catalog mailing with a high-dimensional set of customer features. We document the profits of the estimated policies using data from two campaigns conducted one year apart, which allows us to assess the transportability of the predictions to a campaign implemented one year after collecting the training data. All estimates of the optimal targeting policies yield larger profits than uniform policies that target none or all customers. Further, there are significant profit differences across the methods, with the direct estimation methods yielding substantially larger economic value than the indirect methods.</p>","PeriodicalId":501397,"journal":{"name":"Quantitative Marketing and Economics","volume":"20 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2024-04-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140603166","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Transitory shocks, limited attention, and a firm’s decision to exit 短暂冲击、有限关注和企业退出决定
Pub Date : 2024-03-07 DOI: 10.1007/s11129-024-09279-y
Avi Goldfarb, Mo Xiao

This paper investigates the incidence of limited attention in a high-stakes business setting: a bar owner may be unable to purge transitory shocks from noisy profit signals when deciding whether to exit. Combining a 24-year monthly panel on the alcohol revenues from every bar in Texas with weather data, we find suggestive evidence that inexperienced, distantly located owners may overreact to the transitory component of revenue relative to the persistent component. This apparent asymmetric response is muted under higher revenue fluctuations. We formulate and estimate a structural model to endogenize attention allocation by owners with different thinking cost. Under the assumptions of the model, we find that 3.9% bars make incorrect exit decisions due to limited attention. As exits are irreversible, permanent decisions, small mistakes at the margin interpreting profit signals can lead to large welfare losses for entrepreneurs.

本文研究了在高风险商业环境中有限注意力的发生率:酒吧业主在决定是否退出时,可能无法从嘈杂的利润信号中剔除短暂冲击。通过将德克萨斯州每家酒吧 24 年的月度酒类收入面板与天气数据相结合,我们发现了提示性证据,即经验不足、位置较远的酒吧业主可能会对收入的短暂部分做出相对于持续部分的过度反应。在收入波动较大的情况下,这种明显的非对称反应会减弱。我们建立并估算了一个结构模型,以内生不同思维成本的业主的注意力分配。在该模型的假设条件下,我们发现 3.9% 的酒吧由于注意力有限而做出了错误的退出决策。由于退出是不可逆的永久性决策,因此在解读利润信号时的微小失误都可能导致创业者的巨大福利损失。
{"title":"Transitory shocks, limited attention, and a firm’s decision to exit","authors":"Avi Goldfarb, Mo Xiao","doi":"10.1007/s11129-024-09279-y","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-024-09279-y","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper investigates the incidence of limited attention in a high-stakes business setting: a bar owner may be unable to purge transitory shocks from noisy profit signals when deciding whether to exit. Combining a 24-year monthly panel on the alcohol revenues from every bar in Texas with weather data, we find suggestive evidence that inexperienced, distantly located owners may overreact to the transitory component of revenue relative to the persistent component. This apparent asymmetric response is muted under higher revenue fluctuations. We formulate and estimate a structural model to endogenize attention allocation by owners with different thinking cost. Under the assumptions of the model, we find that 3.9% bars make incorrect exit decisions due to limited attention. As exits are irreversible, permanent decisions, small mistakes at the margin interpreting profit signals can lead to large welfare losses for entrepreneurs.</p>","PeriodicalId":501397,"journal":{"name":"Quantitative Marketing and Economics","volume":"19 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2024-03-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140070221","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Better with buy now, pay later?: A competitive analysis 先买后付更好?
Pub Date : 2023-12-15 DOI: 10.1007/s11129-023-09271-y
Preyas S. Desai, Pranav Jindal

In this paper, we study the incentives of vertically differentiated firms to offer Buy Now, Pay Later (BNPL) in a competitive market. BNPL is a relatively new payment mechanism which, at the point of sale, allows consumers to pay for a product in interest-free installments spread out over a few weeks/months. For a monopolist, offering BNPL is essentially about expanding the market by offering financing to the consumers who cannot afford its product. Therefore, a monopolist is always better-off providing BNPL to its consumers. However, in a competitive environment, offering BNPL is a more complex strategic decision because retailers also need to consider strategic reactions from their competitors. We find that in a competitive situation either of the two retailers might refrain from offering BNPL. This is because when one retailer offers BNPL, the other firm not offering BNPL also benefits from competitive spillovers. Although a monopolist’s benefits from offering BNPL increases in its product quality, in a competitive environment, holding all else constant, a low-quality firm might have more to gain from offering BNPL. In addition to asymmetric equilibria, we also find that there is a symmetric equilibrium in which both retailers offer BNPL. In view of public concerns about possible negative impact of BNPL on consumers, we also study how BNPL consumers’ ignoring the cost of using BNPL can adversely affect them. We find that underestimation of these costs lowers consumers’ welfare, and this reduction in welfare stems from three different sources - (i) higher product prices, (ii) excessive purchase, and (ii) excessive upgrades to the higher quality product.

本文研究了纵向差异化企业在竞争市场中提供 "先买后付"(BNPL)的激励机制。BNPL 是一种相对较新的付款机制,它允许消费者在销售点分几周/月免息分期付款购买产品。对垄断者来说,提供 BNPL 本质上是为了扩大市场,为买不起产品的消费者提供融资。因此,垄断者向消费者提供 BNPL 总是更有利的。然而,在竞争环境中,提供 BNPL 是一项更为复杂的战略决策,因为零售商还需要考虑竞争对手的战略反应。我们发现,在竞争情况下,两家零售商中的任何一家都可能不提供 BNPL。这是因为当一家零售商提供 BNPL 时,另一家不提供 BNPL 的公司也会从竞争溢出效应中获益。虽然垄断企业提供 BNPL 的收益会随着产品质量的提高而增加,但在竞争环境中,在其他条件不变的情况下,低质量企业可能会从提供 BNPL 中获得更多收益。除了非对称均衡外,我们还发现存在一种对称均衡,即两个零售商都提供 BNPL。鉴于公众担心 BNPL 可能对消费者产生负面影响,我们还研究了 BNPL 消费者忽视使用 BNPL 的成本会对他们产生什么不利影响。我们发现,低估这些成本会降低消费者的福利,而福利的降低来自三个不同的方面--(i) 更高的产品价格,(ii) 过度购买,以及 (ii) 过度升级到更高质量的产品。
{"title":"Better with buy now, pay later?: A competitive analysis","authors":"Preyas S. Desai, Pranav Jindal","doi":"10.1007/s11129-023-09271-y","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-023-09271-y","url":null,"abstract":"<p>In this paper, we study the incentives of vertically differentiated firms to offer Buy Now, Pay Later (BNPL) in a competitive market. BNPL is a relatively new payment mechanism which, at the point of sale, allows consumers to pay for a product in interest-free installments spread out over a few weeks/months. For a monopolist, offering BNPL is essentially about expanding the market by offering financing to the consumers who cannot afford its product. Therefore, a monopolist is always better-off providing BNPL to its consumers. However, in a competitive environment, offering BNPL is a more complex strategic decision because retailers also need to consider strategic reactions from their competitors. We find that in a competitive situation either of the two retailers might refrain from offering BNPL. This is because when one retailer offers BNPL, the other firm not offering BNPL also benefits from competitive spillovers. Although a monopolist’s benefits from offering BNPL increases in its product quality, in a competitive environment, holding all else constant, a low-quality firm might have more to gain from offering BNPL. In addition to asymmetric equilibria, we also find that there is a symmetric equilibrium in which both retailers offer BNPL. In view of public concerns about possible negative impact of BNPL on consumers, we also study how BNPL consumers’ ignoring the cost of using BNPL can adversely affect them. We find that underestimation of these costs lowers consumers’ welfare, and this reduction in welfare stems from three different sources - (i) higher product prices, (ii) excessive purchase, and (ii) excessive upgrades to the higher quality product.</p>","PeriodicalId":501397,"journal":{"name":"Quantitative Marketing and Economics","volume":"175 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-12-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"138684800","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The pricing strategies of online grocery retailers 网上杂货零售商的定价策略
Pub Date : 2023-11-28 DOI: 10.1007/s11129-023-09273-w
Diego Aparicio, Zachary Metzman, Roberto Rigobon

This paper documents the differences in pricing strategies between online and offline (brick-and-mortar) channels. We collect price data for identical products from leading online grocery retailers in the United States and complement it with offline data for the same products from scanner data. Our findings reveal a consistent pattern: online retailers exhibit higher price dispersion than their offline counterparts. More specifically, online grocers employ price algorithms that amplify price discrimination in three key dimensions: (1) over time (through frequent price changes), (2) across locations (by charging varying prices based on delivery zipcodes), and (3) across sellers (by setting dispersed prices for identical products across rival retailers).

本文记录了线上和线下(实体)渠道之间定价策略的差异。我们从美国领先的在线杂货零售商那里收集相同产品的价格数据,并从扫描仪数据中补充相同产品的离线数据。我们的发现揭示了一个一致的模式:在线零售商比线下零售商表现出更高的价格差异。更具体地说,在线杂货商使用的价格算法在三个关键方面放大了价格歧视:(1)随着时间的推移(通过频繁的价格变化),(2)跨地点(通过根据送货邮编收取不同的价格),以及(3)跨卖家(通过在竞争对手的零售商之间为相同的产品设定分散的价格)。
{"title":"The pricing strategies of online grocery retailers","authors":"Diego Aparicio, Zachary Metzman, Roberto Rigobon","doi":"10.1007/s11129-023-09273-w","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-023-09273-w","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper documents the differences in pricing strategies between online and offline (brick-and-mortar) channels. We collect price data for identical products from leading online grocery retailers in the United States and complement it with offline data for the same products from scanner data. Our findings reveal a consistent pattern: online retailers exhibit higher price dispersion than their offline counterparts. More specifically, online grocers employ price algorithms that amplify price discrimination in three key dimensions: (1) over time (through frequent price changes), (2) across locations (by charging varying prices based on delivery zipcodes), and (3) across sellers (by setting dispersed prices for identical products across rival retailers).</p>","PeriodicalId":501397,"journal":{"name":"Quantitative Marketing and Economics","volume":"47 10","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-11-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"138521734","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Quantitative Marketing and Economics
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1