首页 > 最新文献

Columbia Law School最新文献

英文 中文
Shaping Reforms and Business Models for the OTC Derivatives Market: Quo Vadis? 场外衍生品市场改革与商业模式的塑造:现状如何?
Pub Date : 2010-04-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1593131
Diego. Valiante
Now that the worst of the financial storm is over, regulators are setting new strategies to deal with the systemic importance of the €427 trillion ($604 trillion) over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives market. This paper explores the three major sources of disruptive effects in OTC derivatives: liquidity, counterparty risk and legal uncertainty. These risks affect the value chain of a typical derivative transaction and weaken the economic and legal rationale behind their widespread use. On the policy side, commitments have been made at G-20 level to draft uniform rules on a global scale “to build a safer financial system”. This paper finds, however, that in practice, the EU and US proposals lay out divergent roads to meet common objectives and the author warns that such divergences may encourage regulatory and supervisory arbitrage. Policy options currently under discussion may need further revision. For instance, access to network clearing infrastructures, such as CCPs, can only be made available to a restricted group of eligible derivative products. Mechanisms of adverse selection and moral hazard, then, may at any time affect the efficient functioning of these crucial infrastructures for financial markets.
如今,金融风暴最糟糕的时期已经过去,监管机构正在制定新的策略,以应对价值427万亿欧元(604万亿美元)的场外衍生品市场的系统重要性。本文探讨了场外衍生品破坏性效应的三个主要来源:流动性、交易对手风险和法律不确定性。这些风险影响了典型衍生品交易的价值链,并削弱了其广泛使用背后的经济和法律依据。在政策方面,20国集团已承诺在全球范围内起草统一规则,“建立一个更安全的金融体系”。然而,本文发现,在实践中,欧盟和美国的提案为实现共同目标制定了不同的道路,作者警告说,这种分歧可能会鼓励监管和监管套利。目前正在讨论的政策方案可能需要进一步修订。例如,使用网络清算基础设施,例如ccp,只能提供给一组有限的合格衍生产品。因此,逆向选择和道德风险机制随时可能影响这些金融市场关键基础设施的有效运作。
{"title":"Shaping Reforms and Business Models for the OTC Derivatives Market: Quo Vadis?","authors":"Diego. Valiante","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1593131","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1593131","url":null,"abstract":"Now that the worst of the financial storm is over, regulators are setting new strategies to deal with the systemic importance of the €427 trillion ($604 trillion) over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives market. This paper explores the three major sources of disruptive effects in OTC derivatives: liquidity, counterparty risk and legal uncertainty. These risks affect the value chain of a typical derivative transaction and weaken the economic and legal rationale behind their widespread use. On the policy side, commitments have been made at G-20 level to draft uniform rules on a global scale “to build a safer financial system”. This paper finds, however, that in practice, the EU and US proposals lay out divergent roads to meet common objectives and the author warns that such divergences may encourage regulatory and supervisory arbitrage. Policy options currently under discussion may need further revision. For instance, access to network clearing infrastructures, such as CCPs, can only be made available to a restricted group of eligible derivative products. Mechanisms of adverse selection and moral hazard, then, may at any time affect the efficient functioning of these crucial infrastructures for financial markets.","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"1 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2010-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"88604281","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 14
Is the Bankruptcy Code an Adequate Mechanism for Resolving the Distress of Systemically Important Institutions? 破产法是解决系统重要性机构困境的适当机制吗?
Pub Date : 2009-12-30 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1529802
E. Morrison
Lehman’s bankruptcy has triggered calls for new approaches to rescuing systemically important institutions. This essay assesses and confirms the need for a new approach. It identifies the inadequacies of the Bankruptcy Code and advocates an approach modeled on the current regime governing commercial banks. That regime includes both close monitoring when a bank is healthy and aggressive intervention when it is distressed. The two tasks—monitoring and intervention—are closely tied, ensuring that intervention occurs only when there is a well-established need for it. The same approach should be applied to all systemically important institutions. President Obama and the Congress are now considering such an approach, though it is unclear whether it will establish a sufficiently close connection between the power to intervene and the duty to monitor. The proposed legislation is unwise if it gives the government power to seize an institution regardless of whether it was previously subject to monitoring and other regulations.
雷曼兄弟的破产引发了人们对采取新方法拯救具有系统重要性的机构的呼声。本文评估并确认了一种新方法的必要性。它指出了《破产法》的不足之处,并主张采用一种以现行商业银行管理制度为蓝本的方法。这一机制既包括银行健康时的密切监控,也包括银行陷入困境时的积极干预。监测和干预这两项任务紧密相连,确保只有在明确需要干预的情况下才进行干预。同样的方法应适用于所有具有系统重要性的机构。奥巴马总统和国会目前正在考虑这样一种方法,尽管目前尚不清楚它是否会在干预的权力和监督的责任之间建立足够紧密的联系。如果这项立法提案赋予政府接管一家机构的权力,而不管这家机构之前是否受到监管和其他规定的约束,那么它就是不明智的。
{"title":"Is the Bankruptcy Code an Adequate Mechanism for Resolving the Distress of Systemically Important Institutions?","authors":"E. Morrison","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1529802","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1529802","url":null,"abstract":"Lehman’s bankruptcy has triggered calls for new approaches to rescuing systemically important institutions. This essay assesses and confirms the need for a new approach. It identifies the inadequacies of the Bankruptcy Code and advocates an approach modeled on the current regime governing commercial banks. That regime includes both close monitoring when a bank is healthy and aggressive intervention when it is distressed. The two tasks—monitoring and intervention—are closely tied, ensuring that intervention occurs only when there is a well-established need for it. The same approach should be applied to all systemically important institutions. President Obama and the Congress are now considering such an approach, though it is unclear whether it will establish a sufficiently close connection between the power to intervene and the duty to monitor. The proposed legislation is unwise if it gives the government power to seize an institution regardless of whether it was previously subject to monitoring and other regulations.","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"7 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-12-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86167561","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11
Solving Global Financial Imbalances: A Plan for a World Financial Authority 解决全球金融失衡:建立世界金融管理局的计划
Pub Date : 2009-11-16 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1507286
Carlos Mauricio Mirandola
This paper will propose a plan to reform international finance – the World Financial Authority (WFA) Plan. Under such a plan, the IMF and other existing international financial institutions would be reformed and coordinated around a newly created WFA. The WFA would have two core functions. First, managing the international liquidity, which implies reducing externalities arising from domestic monetary policies adopted by its members, and dealing with global liquidity problems involving financial activities of transnational private banks. Second, helping countries to make their domestic monetary policies more effective, regaining traction and preventing contagion. A central instrument to this end is the creation of the World Financial Unit (WFU), an international currency unit conceived as a synthetic security backed by reserves composed of currencies surrendered to the WFA by member countries. The WFA is being thought as a device to support the financial globalization, as well as helping governments to maintain their power to manage the domestic macroeconomic conditions, contain externalities, align incentives, and allow for more responsible policies.
本文将提出一项改革国际金融的计划——世界金融管理局计划。根据这一计划,国际货币基金组织和其他现有的国际金融机构将围绕新成立的世界金融机构进行改革和协调。WFA将有两个核心职能。第一,管理国际流动性,这意味着减少其成员国采取的国内货币政策所产生的外部性,并处理涉及跨国私人银行金融活动的全球流动性问题。第二,帮助各国提高国内货币政策的有效性,重新获得牵引力,防止危机蔓延。实现这一目标的一项核心手段是创建世界金融单位(WFU),这是一种国际货币单位,被设想为一种合成证券,由成员国向世界金融组织交出的货币组成的储备作为担保。世界金融论坛被认为是一个支持金融全球化的工具,同时也有助于政府保持其管理国内宏观经济状况的权力,遏制外部性,协调激励措施,并允许更负责任的政策。
{"title":"Solving Global Financial Imbalances: A Plan for a World Financial Authority","authors":"Carlos Mauricio Mirandola","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1507286","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1507286","url":null,"abstract":"This paper will propose a plan to reform international finance – the World Financial Authority (WFA) Plan. Under such a plan, the IMF and other existing international financial institutions would be reformed and coordinated around a newly created WFA. The WFA would have two core functions. First, managing the international liquidity, which implies reducing externalities arising from domestic monetary policies adopted by its members, and dealing with global liquidity problems involving financial activities of transnational private banks. Second, helping countries to make their domestic monetary policies more effective, regaining traction and preventing contagion. A central instrument to this end is the creation of the World Financial Unit (WFU), an international currency unit conceived as a synthetic security backed by reserves composed of currencies surrendered to the WFA by member countries. The WFA is being thought as a device to support the financial globalization, as well as helping governments to maintain their power to manage the domestic macroeconomic conditions, contain externalities, align incentives, and allow for more responsible policies.","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"28 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-11-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"79384383","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
A Proposed Petroleum Fuel Price Stabilization Plan 石油燃料价格稳定计划建议
Pub Date : 2009-05-05 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1399706
T. Merrill, David M. Schizer
The high level of petroleum consumption in the United States contributes to environmental harms, burdens national security, and increases urban sprawl and traffic congestion. In response, the Obama administration has proposed targeted subsidies and regulatory mandates. We do not believe this will be an effective strategy because Congress has no comparative advantage in picking technological winners and losers. Among serious policy analysts, there is consensus that the best approach is to increase prices through a gas tax. The problem, however, is intense and widespread public opposition to this approach. We propose an alternative that offers many important benefits of a gas tax but is more politically palatable, and also will not reduce aggregate consumer demand: a revenue-neutral petroleum fuel price stabilization plan (the “PFPS”). The essential idea is to set a floor under the price of gasoline. If the market price falls below this threshold, then consumers would pay an additional levy on petroleum fuels to make up the difference. For example, suppose the PFSP sets a floor of $3.50 per gallon. If the price would otherwise fall to $3.00, the PFPS contribution would raise the price by 50 cents. But if the market price rises to $3.75, the levy would be zero. Our goal is not to collect revenue, but to influence behavior. Accordingly, we propose that any revenues collected be fully refunded to consumers pro rata. While consumers as a group would experience no net decline in purchasing power, individuals would, of course, be affected: those who consume less than the average amount of gasoline would enjoy a net benefit, while those who consume more would incur a net cost. Thus, the PFPS would create a systematic long-term incentive to reduce petroleum fuel consumption with a neutral fiscal impact. Our proposal would signal to consumers, auto manufacturers, and investors in alternative energy technology that petroleum fuel prices will not decline below the floor price in the future. Armed with this information, consumers, manufacturers and energy investors would commit to making fundamental changes in their behavior and their investments in new technology – without need of targeted government subsidies – because they would know that their investments would not be undermined by a future collapse in petroleum prices. Such assurances are crucial, as recent events have shown. Without a stabilization program, the wild fluctuation in oil prices in 2008 will leave investors and consumers all the more wary of investing in energy efficiency. Our proposal also has significant political advantages. The fact that it is refundable means that those who consume the average amount of petroleum or less will make net profit from the program, and thus will become a constituency for it. Moreover, if the floor on gas prices is set below the level of gas prices when the program is enacted – something that is easy to do when prices are high – then voters could take comfort
在美国,高水平的石油消费对环境造成了危害,给国家安全带来了负担,并加剧了城市扩张和交通拥堵。作为回应,奥巴马政府提出了有针对性的补贴和监管要求。我们不相信这将是一个有效的战略,因为国会在挑选技术赢家和输家方面没有比较优势。严肃的政策分析人士一致认为,最好的办法是通过征收汽油税来提高价格。然而,问题是公众强烈而广泛地反对这种做法。我们提出了一个替代方案,它提供了汽油税的许多重要好处,但在政治上更容易接受,也不会减少总消费需求:收入中性的石油燃料价格稳定计划(“PFPS”)。最基本的想法是为汽油价格设定一个下限。如果市场价格低于这个门槛,那么消费者将支付额外的石油燃料税来弥补差额。例如,假设PFSP设定了每加仑3.50美元的下限。如果价格降至3美元,PFPS的贡献将使价格提高50美分。但如果市场价格涨到3.75美元,征税将为零。我们的目标不是收钱,而是影响行为。因此,我们建议将所征收的任何税收按比例全额退还给消费者。虽然消费者作为一个群体不会经历购买力的净下降,但个人当然会受到影响:那些消费低于平均汽油量的人将享受净收益,而那些消费更多的人将招致净成本。因此,PFPS将创造一个系统性的长期激励,以减少石油燃料的消耗,同时对财政产生中性影响。我们的提议将向消费者、汽车制造商和替代能源技术的投资者发出信号,即石油燃料的价格在未来不会跌至最低价格以下。有了这些信息,消费者、制造商和能源投资者将承诺从根本上改变他们的行为和对新技术的投资——不需要政府的定向补贴——因为他们知道,他们的投资不会因未来石油价格暴跌而受到损害。正如最近的事件所显示的那样,这样的保证至关重要。如果没有稳定计划,2008年油价的剧烈波动将使投资者和消费者在投资能源效率方面更加谨慎。我们的建议也有显著的政治优势。可退还的事实意味着,那些消耗平均量或更少的石油的人将从该计划中获得净利润,从而成为该计划的支持者。此外,如果在该计划实施时,将天然气价格的下限设定在天然气价格的水平以下——在价格高企的时候,这很容易做到——那么选民就可以放心,只要油价不下跌,他们就不必在该计划下支付任何费用。当然,如果价格下限设定在较低水平,该计划的影响就会较小。如果在天然气价格较低的时候采用该计划,并且将最低限价保持在低于市场价格的水平,则很可能出现这种情况。作为回应,我们的建议可能会有一系列的调整。
{"title":"A Proposed Petroleum Fuel Price Stabilization Plan","authors":"T. Merrill, David M. Schizer","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1399706","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1399706","url":null,"abstract":"The high level of petroleum consumption in the United States contributes to environmental harms, burdens national security, and increases urban sprawl and traffic congestion. In response, the Obama administration has proposed targeted subsidies and regulatory mandates. We do not believe this will be an effective strategy because Congress has no comparative advantage in picking technological winners and losers. Among serious policy analysts, there is consensus that the best approach is to increase prices through a gas tax. The problem, however, is intense and widespread public opposition to this approach. We propose an alternative that offers many important benefits of a gas tax but is more politically palatable, and also will not reduce aggregate consumer demand: a revenue-neutral petroleum fuel price stabilization plan (the “PFPS”). The essential idea is to set a floor under the price of gasoline. If the market price falls below this threshold, then consumers would pay an additional levy on petroleum fuels to make up the difference. For example, suppose the PFSP sets a floor of $3.50 per gallon. If the price would otherwise fall to $3.00, the PFPS contribution would raise the price by 50 cents. But if the market price rises to $3.75, the levy would be zero. Our goal is not to collect revenue, but to influence behavior. Accordingly, we propose that any revenues collected be fully refunded to consumers pro rata. While consumers as a group would experience no net decline in purchasing power, individuals would, of course, be affected: those who consume less than the average amount of gasoline would enjoy a net benefit, while those who consume more would incur a net cost. Thus, the PFPS would create a systematic long-term incentive to reduce petroleum fuel consumption with a neutral fiscal impact. Our proposal would signal to consumers, auto manufacturers, and investors in alternative energy technology that petroleum fuel prices will not decline below the floor price in the future. Armed with this information, consumers, manufacturers and energy investors would commit to making fundamental changes in their behavior and their investments in new technology – without need of targeted government subsidies – because they would know that their investments would not be undermined by a future collapse in petroleum prices. Such assurances are crucial, as recent events have shown. Without a stabilization program, the wild fluctuation in oil prices in 2008 will leave investors and consumers all the more wary of investing in energy efficiency. Our proposal also has significant political advantages. The fact that it is refundable means that those who consume the average amount of petroleum or less will make net profit from the program, and thus will become a constituency for it. Moreover, if the floor on gas prices is set below the level of gas prices when the program is enacted – something that is easy to do when prices are high – then voters could take comfort ","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"32 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-05-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"82537639","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Impossible Desire: Parents Involved and Limits to the Victim's Perspective 不可能的欲望:父母的参与和受害者视角的限制
Pub Date : 2009-04-09 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1375647
A. Timmer
This paper explores the scholarship on the most recent Supreme Court school segregation case; Parents Involved. Many articles have appeared critiquing the majority of the Robert's Court's stance on the meaning of racial discrimination. This note does not give another version of that critique, but rather examines the fierce reactions the case engendered in legal scholars. It is, so to say, a critique of the critiques. I recast the debate about Parents Involved in terms of the victim's and the perpetrator perspective, a model borrowed from Alan Freeman. I argue that the critics of Parents Involved plead that the Supreme Court take up the victim's perspective. But would the affront felt by critics of the Robert's Court's opinion in this case be eliminated if the Court had adopted the victim's rather than the perpetrator's perspective? I argue that it would not. To the extent that what underlies the objection to the majority opinion in Parents Involved is a sense that the Court has done a form of violence to the idea of racial justice in this country, the turn to the victim perspective will not eliminate that violence. It would merely enact an alternative form of violence. In addition, things are more complicated because something larger than law is at stake in Parents Involved. At stake is a trauma and law cannot heal that. I conclude that the solution that the critics of Parents Involved have put forward is incapable of delivering the desired healing of old wounds.
本文探讨了最近最高法院学校种族隔离案的学术研究;父母参与进来。出现了许多文章,批评罗伯特法院对种族歧视含义的大多数立场。本文并没有给出这种批评的另一个版本,而是考察了该案件在法律学者中引起的激烈反应。可以说,这是对批评者的批评。我借用了艾伦·弗里曼(Alan Freeman)的一个模型,从受害者和加害者的角度,重新讨论了关于父母参与的争论。我认为,批评“父母参与其中”的人请求最高法院站在受害者的角度。但是,如果法院采纳了受害者而不是犯罪者的观点,对罗伯特法院在本案中的意见持批评态度的人所感到的侮辱是否就可以消除?我认为不会。在某种程度上,反对“父母参与案”多数意见的根本原因是法院对这个国家的种族正义理念施加了某种形式的暴力,转向受害者的观点并不能消除这种暴力。它只会实施另一种形式的暴力。此外,事情变得更加复杂,因为在“父母参与”中,有比法律更大的东西处于危险之中。危在旦夕的是一种创伤,法律无法治愈它。我的结论是,《父母参与》一书的批评者提出的解决方案无法治愈旧伤。
{"title":"Impossible Desire: Parents Involved and Limits to the Victim's Perspective","authors":"A. Timmer","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1375647","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1375647","url":null,"abstract":"This paper explores the scholarship on the most recent Supreme Court school segregation case; Parents Involved. Many articles have appeared critiquing the majority of the Robert's Court's stance on the meaning of racial discrimination. This note does not give another version of that critique, but rather examines the fierce reactions the case engendered in legal scholars. It is, so to say, a critique of the critiques. I recast the debate about Parents Involved in terms of the victim's and the perpetrator perspective, a model borrowed from Alan Freeman. I argue that the critics of Parents Involved plead that the Supreme Court take up the victim's perspective. But would the affront felt by critics of the Robert's Court's opinion in this case be eliminated if the Court had adopted the victim's rather than the perpetrator's perspective? I argue that it would not. To the extent that what underlies the objection to the majority opinion in Parents Involved is a sense that the Court has done a form of violence to the idea of racial justice in this country, the turn to the victim perspective will not eliminate that violence. It would merely enact an alternative form of violence. In addition, things are more complicated because something larger than law is at stake in Parents Involved. At stake is a trauma and law cannot heal that. I conclude that the solution that the critics of Parents Involved have put forward is incapable of delivering the desired healing of old wounds.","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"15 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-04-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"87909903","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Global Network Finance: Organizational Hedging in Times of Uncertainty 全球网络金融:不确定时代的组织对冲
Pub Date : 2008-10-14 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1284606
Katharina Pistor
The global financial crisis that began in 2007 revealed a fundamental weakness in the global financial system: Extensive financial interdependence of financial relations unmatched by a governance regime of similar reach. As multinational banks sought to fortify their capital base in the wake of the unfolding crisis, Sovereign wealth Funds (SWFs) and the banks’ home governments have become mutual stakeholders in some of the largest financial intermediaries with global reach. From the multitude of individual transactions has emerged a network of equity ties that spans the globe. These ties bridge institutional practices and governance regimes that previously operated largely independently of each other. They have the potential of fostering the emergence of a new governance regime for the global financial market place that deviates from earlier prognoses that globalization entails convergence on a single governance model. Instead, the newly created ties that jointly add up to a global financial network enable institutionally and organizationally diverse players to contribute their own perspectives as joint stakeholders in selected financial intermediaries, and indirectly, in the global financial system. This is likely to have important implications for the behavior of these actors in the future and the emergence of new governance solutions for the global market place. The paper discusses two recent cases of collaborative re-capitalization events to illustrate how this regime is evolving in practice.
始于2007年的全球金融危机暴露了全球金融体系的一个根本弱点:金融关系之间存在着广泛的金融相互依赖,规模类似的治理机制无法与之匹敌。随着跨国银行在危机爆发后寻求巩固其资本基础,主权财富基金(swf)和银行所在国政府已成为一些具有全球影响力的最大金融中介机构的共同利益相关者。从大量的个人交易中,形成了一个遍布全球的股权联系网络。这些联系连接了以前在很大程度上彼此独立运作的机构实践和治理制度。它们有可能促进全球金融市场出现一种新的治理制度,这种制度偏离了早期的预测,即全球化需要向单一治理模式趋同。相反,新建立的联系共同构成了一个全球金融网络,使制度和组织上多样化的参与者能够在选定的金融中介机构中作为共同利益相关者贡献自己的观点,并间接地在全球金融体系中贡献自己的观点。这可能会对这些参与者未来的行为以及全球市场新治理解决方案的出现产生重要影响。本文讨论了最近的两个合作再资本化事件的案例,以说明这种制度在实践中是如何演变的。
{"title":"Global Network Finance: Organizational Hedging in Times of Uncertainty","authors":"Katharina Pistor","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1284606","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1284606","url":null,"abstract":"The global financial crisis that began in 2007 revealed a fundamental weakness in the global financial system: Extensive financial interdependence of financial relations unmatched by a governance regime of similar reach. As multinational banks sought to fortify their capital base in the wake of the unfolding crisis, Sovereign wealth Funds (SWFs) and the banks’ home governments have become mutual stakeholders in some of the largest financial intermediaries with global reach. From the multitude of individual transactions has emerged a network of equity ties that spans the globe. These ties bridge institutional practices and governance regimes that previously operated largely independently of each other. They have the potential of fostering the emergence of a new governance regime for the global financial market place that deviates from earlier prognoses that globalization entails convergence on a single governance model. Instead, the newly created ties that jointly add up to a global financial network enable institutionally and organizationally diverse players to contribute their own perspectives as joint stakeholders in selected financial intermediaries, and indirectly, in the global financial system. This is likely to have important implications for the behavior of these actors in the future and the emergence of new governance solutions for the global market place. The paper discusses two recent cases of collaborative re-capitalization events to illustrate how this regime is evolving in practice.","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"46 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-10-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"76807896","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Vote Fraud in the Eye of the Beholder: The Role of Public Opinion in the Challenge to Voter Identification Requirements 旁观者眼中的投票欺诈:公众舆论在对选民身份要求的挑战中的作用
Pub Date : 2008-02-21 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1099056
S. Ansolabehere, N. Persily
In the current debate over the constitutionality of voter identification laws, both the Supreme Court and defenders of such laws have justified them, in part, as counteracting a widespread fear of voter fraud that leads citizens to disengage from the democracy. Because actual evidence of voter impersonation fraud is rare and difficult to come by if fraud is successful, reliance on public opinion as to the prevalence of fraud threatens to allow courts to evade the difficult task of balancing the actual constitutional risks involved. In this short Article we employ a unique survey to evaluate the causes and effects of public opinion regarding voter fraud. We find that perceptions of fraud have no relationship to an individual's likelihood of turning out to vote. We also find that voters who were subject to stricter identification requirements believe fraud is just as widespread as do voters subject to less restrictive identification requirements.
在当前关于选民身份法是否符合宪法的辩论中,最高法院和这些法律的捍卫者都认为,这些法律在一定程度上是合理的,因为它们抵消了对选民欺诈的普遍恐惧,这种恐惧会导致公民脱离民主。由于选民冒充欺诈的实际证据很少,而且如果欺诈成功,也很难获得,因此,对欺诈普遍程度的判断依赖于公众舆论,可能会使法院逃避平衡所涉及的实际宪法风险的艰巨任务。在这篇简短的文章中,我们采用一项独特的调查来评估公众舆论对选民欺诈的原因和影响。我们发现,对欺诈的认知与个人投票的可能性没有关系。我们还发现,受到更严格身份要求约束的选民认为,欺诈行为与受到较少严格身份要求约束的选民一样普遍。
{"title":"Vote Fraud in the Eye of the Beholder: The Role of Public Opinion in the Challenge to Voter Identification Requirements","authors":"S. Ansolabehere, N. Persily","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1099056","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1099056","url":null,"abstract":"In the current debate over the constitutionality of voter identification laws, both the Supreme Court and defenders of such laws have justified them, in part, as counteracting a widespread fear of voter fraud that leads citizens to disengage from the democracy. Because actual evidence of voter impersonation fraud is rare and difficult to come by if fraud is successful, reliance on public opinion as to the prevalence of fraud threatens to allow courts to evade the difficult task of balancing the actual constitutional risks involved. In this short Article we employ a unique survey to evaluate the causes and effects of public opinion regarding voter fraud. We find that perceptions of fraud have no relationship to an individual's likelihood of turning out to vote. We also find that voters who were subject to stricter identification requirements believe fraud is just as widespread as do voters subject to less restrictive identification requirements.","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"67 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-02-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"83582307","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 82
Sovereign Wealth Funds and Corporate Governance: A Minimalist Response to the New Merchantilism 主权财富基金与公司治理:对新商品主义的极简回应
Pub Date : 2008-02-18 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1095023
R. Gilson, C. Milhaupt
Sovereign wealth funds (SWFs) have increased dramatically in size as a result of increased commodity prices and the increase in the foreign currency reserves of Asian trading countries. SWF assets now roughly equal those in hedge and private equity funds combined. This growth, and the shift of SWF investment strategy toward equities and increasingly high profile investments like capital infusions into U.S. financial institutions following the subprime mortgage problem, have generated calls for domestic and international regulation. The U.S. and other western economies already regulate the foreign acquisition of control of domestic corporations. However, acquisitions of significant but non-controlling positions are not regulated. The danger is that new regulation will compromise the beneficial recycling of trade surpluses accomplished by SWF investments. In this paper, we situate the controversy over SWF investments in the increasing global trend toward direct governmental involvement in corporate activity, a phenomenon we label the New Merchantilism. We explain why increased transparency of SWF investment portfolios and strategy, the most commonly advanced policy recommendation, does not respond to the chief concern that SWF investments have engendered. We offer a regulatory minimalist response to fears that SWFs will make portfolio investments for strategic rather than economic reasons. Under our proposal, voting rights of SWF equity investments in U.S. corporations would be suspended but reinstated on sale. Thus, SWFs would buy and sell fully voting rights, thereby assuring that the incentives to make non-strategic investments would be unaffected, while the capacity to exercise influence for strategic motives would be constrained. The paper concludes by assessing the extent to which even a regulatory minimalist response remains both over and under inclusive; however, the limited imprecision does not undermine the effectiveness of the response.
由于大宗商品价格上涨和亚洲贸易国家外汇储备增加,主权财富基金(SWFs)的规模急剧扩大。目前,主权财富基金的资产规模大致相当于对冲基金和私人股本基金的总和。这种增长,加上主权财富基金的投资策略转向股票,以及在次贷危机后向美国金融机构注资等越来越引人注目的投资,引发了对国内和国际监管的呼声。美国和其他西方经济体已经对外资收购国内公司的控制权进行了监管。然而,对重要但非控制地位的收购不受监管。危险在于,新法规将损害主权财富基金投资所实现的贸易顺差的有益循环。在本文中,我们将主权财富基金投资的争议置于政府直接参与企业活动的日益增长的全球趋势中,我们将这种现象称为新商品主义。我们解释了为什么提高主权财富基金投资组合和策略的透明度,这是最常见的先进政策建议,并没有回应主权财富基金投资所产生的主要担忧。对于主权财富基金将出于战略而非经济原因进行组合投资的担忧,我们提供了一种监管最小化的回应。根据我们的提议,主权财富基金在美国公司股权投资的投票权将被暂停,但可以恢复出售。因此,主权财富基金将买卖完全投票权,从而确保进行非战略投资的动机不受影响,而出于战略动机施加影响的能力将受到限制。最后,本文评估了即使是监管极简主义的回应,在多大程度上也是包容性过高或过低的;然而,有限的不精确并不会影响应对措施的有效性。
{"title":"Sovereign Wealth Funds and Corporate Governance: A Minimalist Response to the New Merchantilism","authors":"R. Gilson, C. Milhaupt","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1095023","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1095023","url":null,"abstract":"Sovereign wealth funds (SWFs) have increased dramatically in size as a result of increased commodity prices and the increase in the foreign currency reserves of Asian trading countries. SWF assets now roughly equal those in hedge and private equity funds combined. This growth, and the shift of SWF investment strategy toward equities and increasingly high profile investments like capital infusions into U.S. financial institutions following the subprime mortgage problem, have generated calls for domestic and international regulation. The U.S. and other western economies already regulate the foreign acquisition of control of domestic corporations. However, acquisitions of significant but non-controlling positions are not regulated. The danger is that new regulation will compromise the beneficial recycling of trade surpluses accomplished by SWF investments. In this paper, we situate the controversy over SWF investments in the increasing global trend toward direct governmental involvement in corporate activity, a phenomenon we label the New Merchantilism. We explain why increased transparency of SWF investment portfolios and strategy, the most commonly advanced policy recommendation, does not respond to the chief concern that SWF investments have engendered. We offer a regulatory minimalist response to fears that SWFs will make portfolio investments for strategic rather than economic reasons. Under our proposal, voting rights of SWF equity investments in U.S. corporations would be suspended but reinstated on sale. Thus, SWFs would buy and sell fully voting rights, thereby assuring that the incentives to make non-strategic investments would be unaffected, while the capacity to exercise influence for strategic motives would be constrained. The paper concludes by assessing the extent to which even a regulatory minimalist response remains both over and under inclusive; however, the limited imprecision does not undermine the effectiveness of the response.","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"1 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2008-02-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"88118031","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 85
Understanding Convertible Debt Funded Stock Buybacks - Cypress Semiconductor Case Study 了解可转换债券资助的股票回购-赛普拉斯半导体案例研究
Pub Date : 2007-10-04 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1019326
M. Gumport
In 2006-2007, convert funded stock buybacks are popular. Why? Consider Cypress Semiconductor's complex transaction. In March 2007, its stock at $18.89, Cypress sells $600 million of converts, enters a $571 million VWAP (volume weighted average price) stock buyback contract, buys calls and sells warrants. It retires 28.9 million shares. Good profits! Bad deal? Six months post deal with its stock up 51.9% to $28.70, Cypress stands to reap a $180 million benefit at maturity, a $1.18 (4.3%) stock price boon for ongoing shareholders. Still, when it enters the deal, Cypress: - Needs 11.0% stock price appreciation to break even - Is exposed to 100% of any shortfall in its stock price from breakeven - Receives 100% of any stock price increase up to 28.7% above breakeven - Receives just 13.0% of any further stock price advance Simpler, superior structures are available. At 0-5% added cost, a call spread matches upside but cuts risk 83% or more. Other structures give lower cost with equal (or better) upside. Its deal choice (full downside; limited upside) suggests Cypress at execution is sure its stock is going up. Are selling shareholders adequately informed? Is earnings management an attraction? Real economic advantage through tax arbitrage seems blocked, but equity accounting lets deal losses (if incurred) and most fees bypass the income statement. A baseline settlement at current spot has Cypress receive a $180.2 million benefit through in part (40%) cash receipts, in part (60%) a 2.4% share count reduction. The only definite monetary trace in reported income is $27.0 million of tax deductible expense over the deal's life; Cypress can elect to show phantom income, but real tax then cuts the total real economic benefit. Also, stock buyback execution prices are seriously understated, but companies should not value this feature: The complex, syndicated deal itself exacerbates 10b-18 governance concerns, and misleading trade confirmations just put other anomalies in stock volume and pricing in a bad light. This analysis is tentative insofar as it fails to identify economic or governance advantages to explain the popularity of convert funded buybacks. Earnings cosmetics is not satisfying given the deal's poor risk/reward. Is there an overlooked tax advantage? The deal's popularity with banking syndicates is easy to understand, but, for now, we wonder, could the transaction be popular with companies because it is popular?
2006-2007年,转换资金股票回购很受欢迎。为什么?以赛普拉斯半导体的复杂交易为例。2007年3月,其股价为18.89美元,赛普拉斯出售了6亿美元的转股权,签订了5.71亿美元的VWAP(成交量加权平均价格)股票回购合约,买入看涨期权并卖出认股权证。它将回购2890万股股票。好的利润!糟糕的交易吗?交易完成六个月后,赛普拉斯的股价上涨51.9%,至28.70美元,到期时将获得1.8亿美元的收益,对现有股东来说,股价将上涨1.18美元(4.3%)。尽管如此,当赛普拉斯参与交易时,它:-需要11.0%的股价涨幅才能实现盈亏平衡-从盈亏平衡中获得100%的股价损失-在盈亏平衡以上28.7%的任何股价上涨中获得100%的收益-任何进一步的股价上涨仅获得13.0%的收益更简单,更优越的结构。在0-5%的额外成本下,看涨期权价差与上行相匹配,但风险降低了83%或更多。其他结构在同等(或更好)的优势下提供更低的成本。它的交易选择(完全不利;有限的上行空间)表明,赛普拉斯在执行时确信其股票将上涨。出售股票的股东是否得到充分通知?盈余管理有吸引力吗?通过税收套利获得的真正经济优势似乎受到阻碍,但权益会计让交易损失(如果发生)和大多数费用绕过损益表。根据目前的基准结算,赛普拉斯将获得1.802亿美元的收益,其中一部分(40%)是现金收入,另一部分(60%)是股份数量减少2.4%。在报告的收入中,唯一明确的货币痕迹是在交易期间2700万美元的可抵税费用;柏树可以选择显示虚幻收入,但实际税收则削减了总实际经济效益。此外,股票回购执行价格被严重低估,但公司不应重视这一特点:复杂的银团交易本身加剧了对2010 -18年治理问题的担忧,误导性的交易确认只会使股票数量和定价的其他异常情况受到不利影响。这种分析是试探性的,因为它未能确定经济或治理优势来解释转换融资回购的流行。考虑到这笔交易的低风险/回报,盈利化妆品并不令人满意。是否存在被忽视的税收优势?这笔交易受到银团的欢迎是很容易理解的,但是,就目前而言,我们想知道,这笔交易受到公司欢迎是因为它受欢迎吗?
{"title":"Understanding Convertible Debt Funded Stock Buybacks - Cypress Semiconductor Case Study","authors":"M. Gumport","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1019326","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1019326","url":null,"abstract":"In 2006-2007, convert funded stock buybacks are popular. Why? Consider Cypress Semiconductor's complex transaction. In March 2007, its stock at $18.89, Cypress sells $600 million of converts, enters a $571 million VWAP (volume weighted average price) stock buyback contract, buys calls and sells warrants. It retires 28.9 million shares. Good profits! Bad deal? Six months post deal with its stock up 51.9% to $28.70, Cypress stands to reap a $180 million benefit at maturity, a $1.18 (4.3%) stock price boon for ongoing shareholders. Still, when it enters the deal, Cypress: - Needs 11.0% stock price appreciation to break even - Is exposed to 100% of any shortfall in its stock price from breakeven - Receives 100% of any stock price increase up to 28.7% above breakeven - Receives just 13.0% of any further stock price advance Simpler, superior structures are available. At 0-5% added cost, a call spread matches upside but cuts risk 83% or more. Other structures give lower cost with equal (or better) upside. Its deal choice (full downside; limited upside) suggests Cypress at execution is sure its stock is going up. Are selling shareholders adequately informed? Is earnings management an attraction? Real economic advantage through tax arbitrage seems blocked, but equity accounting lets deal losses (if incurred) and most fees bypass the income statement. A baseline settlement at current spot has Cypress receive a $180.2 million benefit through in part (40%) cash receipts, in part (60%) a 2.4% share count reduction. The only definite monetary trace in reported income is $27.0 million of tax deductible expense over the deal's life; Cypress can elect to show phantom income, but real tax then cuts the total real economic benefit. Also, stock buyback execution prices are seriously understated, but companies should not value this feature: The complex, syndicated deal itself exacerbates 10b-18 governance concerns, and misleading trade confirmations just put other anomalies in stock volume and pricing in a bad light. This analysis is tentative insofar as it fails to identify economic or governance advantages to explain the popularity of convert funded buybacks. Earnings cosmetics is not satisfying given the deal's poor risk/reward. Is there an overlooked tax advantage? The deal's popularity with banking syndicates is easy to understand, but, for now, we wonder, could the transaction be popular with companies because it is popular?","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"26 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2007-10-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"85118839","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Reasons for Reasons 原因的原因
Pub Date : 2007-09-08 DOI: 10.1007/978-90-481-9588-6_7
Mathilde Cohen
{"title":"Reasons for Reasons","authors":"Mathilde Cohen","doi":"10.1007/978-90-481-9588-6_7","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/978-90-481-9588-6_7","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":10506,"journal":{"name":"Columbia Law School","volume":"31 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2007-09-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"85339837","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
期刊
Columbia Law School
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1